Financing Risk & Reinsurance

Similar documents
Advanced Risk Management

Finance: Risk Management

Economic and Financial Perspectives on the Demand for Reinsurance

If the market is perfect, hedging would have no value. Actually, in real world,

Economic and Financial Perspectives on the Demand for Reinsurance

INTERNAL VERSUS EXTERNAL CAPITAL MARKETS IN THE INSURANCE INDUSTRY: THE ROLE OF REINSURANCE. Lawrence S. Powell

RISK MANAGEMENT AND CORPORATE VALUE

600 Solved MCQs of MGT201 BY

Corporate Risk Management: Costs and Benefits

MERTON & PEROLD FOR DUMMIES

Corporate Demand for Insurance: Empirical Evidence from Germany

The Determinants of Foreign Currency Hedging by UK Non- Financial Firms

Question # 4 of 15 ( Start time: 07:07:31 PM )

WHY DO RISK NEUTRAL FIRMS HEDGE?

RISK MANAGEMENT AND VALUE CREATION

MGT201 Financial Management Solved MCQs A Lot of Solved MCQS in on file

MGT201 Financial Management Solved MCQs

Demand for Reinsurance: Evidence from Australian Insurers

Risk Based Capital and Capital Allocation in Insurance

CHAPTER 17: CAPITAL STRUCTURE: TRADEOFFS AND THEORY

Solved MCQs MGT201. (Group is not responsible for any solved content)

MGT Financial Management Mega Quiz file solved by Muhammad Afaaq

How Much do Firms Hedge with Derivatives?

The homework assignment reviews the major capital structure issues. The homework assures that you read the textbook chapter; it is not testing you.

JACOBS LEVY CONCEPTS FOR PROFITABLE EQUITY INVESTING

Chapter 13 Capital Structure and Distribution Policy

Citation for published version (APA): Oosterhof, C. M. (2006). Essays on corporate risk management and optimal hedging s.n.

FINALTERM EXAMINATION Fall 2009 MGT201- Financial Management (Session - 4)

How to review an ORSA

Volume Author/Editor: Kenneth Singleton, editor. Volume URL:

Economics 430 Handout on Rational Expectations: Part I. Review of Statistics: Notation and Definitions

Feedback Effect and Capital Structure

The Value of Catastrophe Securitization Bobby Bierley, Jim Hilliard and Rob Hoyt

PowerPoint. to accompany. Chapter 11. Systematic Risk and the Equity Risk Premium

P1.T1. Foundations of Risk Management Zvi Bodie, Alex Kane, and Alan J. Marcus, Investments, 10th Edition Bionic Turtle FRM Study Notes

Reinsurance Section News

The Effects of Responsible Investment: Financial Returns, Risk, Reduction and Impact

Cash Holdings from a Risk Management Perspective

Catastrophe Reinsurance Pricing

Does Hedging Increase Firm Value?

Portfolio Management

Why Do Non-Financial Firms Select One Type of Derivatives Over Others?

Does Portfolio Theory Work During Financial Crises?

THEORY & PRACTICE FOR FUND MANAGERS. SPRING 2011 Volume 20 Number 1 RISK. special section PARITY. The Voices of Influence iijournals.

Corporate Finance Finance Ch t ap er 1: I t nves t men D i ec sions Albert Banal-Estanol

Rationales for Corporate Risk Management - A Critical Literature Review

The Value of Investing in ERM

HOW TO DIVERSIFY THE TAX-SHELTERED EQUITY FUND

Risk and Return. Nicole Höhling, Introduction. Definitions. Types of risk and beta

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary

Risk Concentrations Principles

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission.

Risk Management Determinants Affecting Firms' Values in the Gold Mining Industry: New Empirical Results

ALLAMA IQBAL OPEN UNIVERSITY, ISLAMABAD (Department of Business Administration) FINANCIAL MANAGEMENT (191) CHECKLIST SEMESTER: AUTUMN, 2013

On the Risk Capital Framework of Financial Institutions

SOLVENCY, CAPITAL ALLOCATION, AND FAIR RATE OF RETURN IN INSURANCE

Allocate Capital and Measure Performances in a Financial Institution

Quarterly Investment Outlook 1 st Quarter 2016 December 2015

FINANCE BASIC FOR MANAGERS SUMMER 2015 FINAL EXAM

Strategy, Pricing and Value. Gary G Venter Columbia University and Gary Venter, LLC

Master Thesis Finance Foreign Currency Exposure, Financial Hedging Instruments and Firm Value

The Strategic Motives for Corporate Risk Management

Monetary Economics Cost of Capital. Gerald P. Dwyer Fall 2015

EG, Ch. 12: International Diversification

Some Puzzles. Stock Splits

The Real Benefits of Active Management

Managing and Identifying Risk

CHAPTER 14 BOND PORTFOLIOS

Hedging and Firm Value in the European Airline Industry

TECHNICAL BRIEF PAY FOR PERFORMANCE STRATEGIES FOR WESTERN STATES

Financial Services is dominated by ILFC, International Lease Financing Corporation, which is the largest aircraft financing company in the world.

THE UNIVERSITY OF NEW SOUTH WALES SCHOOL OF BANKING AND FINANCE

PAPER F3 FINANCIAL STRATEGY. Acorn Chapters

The hedge fund sector has grown at a rapid pace over the last several years. There are a record number of hedge funds,

Question # 1 of 15 ( Start time: 01:53:35 PM ) Total Marks: 1

Value from Hedging Risk with Reinsurance

CONTENTS. Preface... xi

Organizational Structure and Risk Taking: Evidence from the Life Insurance Industry in Japan

Guide to Financial Management Course Number: 6431

Hedge Portfolios, the No Arbitrage Condition & Arbitrage Pricing Theory

OPTIMAL RISKY PORTFOLIOS- ASSET ALLOCATIONS. BKM Ch 7

The Use of Foreign Currency Derivatives and Firm Value In U.S.

RESEARCH STATEMENT. Heather Tookes, May My research lies at the intersection of capital markets and corporate finance.

INSURANCE. Life Insurance. as an. Asset Class

Fiduciary Insights. IMPLEMENTING LIABILITY- DRIVEN INVESTING: Not a Day at the Beach

The Role of Derivatives in corporate risk management. Introduction: Basics of Derivatives:

Random Variables and Applications OPRE 6301

As interest rates go up, the present value of a stream of fixed cash flows.

Irrational markets, rational fiduciaries

The Effect of Life Settlement Portfolio Size on Longevity Risk

DETERMINANTS OF CORPORATE HEDGING PRACTICES USED BY COMPANIES LISTED IN NAIROBI SECURITY EXCHANGE

Ross School of Business at the University of Michigan Independent Study Project Report

International Financial Markets Prices and Policies. Why Measure and Manage Financial Exposure?

Chapter 18 Interest rates / Transaction Costs Corporate Income Taxes (Cash Flow Effects) Example - Summary for Firm U Summary for Firm L

Risk Management Determinants Affecting Firms' Values in the Gold Mining Industry: New Empirical Results

Arbitrage and Asset Pricing

Derivatives and Corporate Risk Management: Participation and Volume Decisions in the Insurance Industry

Concepts in Best Practice: Transfer Pricing Customer Accounts

How do Croatian Companies make Corporate Risk Management Decisions: Evidence from the Field

Dr. Syed Tahir Hijazi 1[1]

Transcription:

JOHN A. MAJOR, GARY G. VENTER 1 Guy Carpenter & Co., Inc. Two World Trade Center New York, NY 10048 (212) 323-1605 john.major@guycarp.com Financing Risk & Reinsurance WHY TRANSFER RISK? Ever since Modigliani and Miller (1958), finance theorists have grappled with the question of why firms engage in various forms of risk transfer, including insurance and hedging with financial derivatives. This article summarizes recent findings on that question and draws attention to certain consequences for risk transfer professionals. The Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) approach to valuing a firm states that systematic risk covariance between the fortunes of a firm and the rest of the market as measured by beta and only systematic risk, requires compensation in a competitive investment environment. Random shocks to earnings or cash flow, as long as they are uncorrelated with stock market movements, are of no consequence to an investor whose portfolio is well diversified. Consequently, any actions taken by the firm to reduce the volatility of earnings or cash flow (with no improvement in the 1 John Major, ASA, is a member of the board of contributors of FR&R. Gary Venter, FCAS, is a Managing Director of Guy Carpenter & Co., Inc.

Major and Venter: Why Transfer Risk? Page 2 expected levels of earnings) will not result in a change in investors demands for return on investment. So why bother? Finance theorists have hypothesized a number of reasons that firms might rationally hedge their risks to earnings or cash flow. Other researchers have examined the behavior of large numbers of firms to see if the data support the theories. Several conclusions have emerged. Most of the theories revolve around market imperfections that make the logic of CAPM not (fully) applicable. These include the corporate income tax, costs incurred in going bankrupt, financing costs, incomplete diversification, and other features of an imperfect world. That the corporate income tax constitutes a market imperfection should come as no surprise. One theory here is that after-tax earnings are a nonlinear function of gross earnings. Therefore, reducing volatility in earnings takes advantage of a convexity effect in boosting expected net results. Unfortunately, Graham and Rogers (1999), in studying corporate hedging of interest rate and currency risk, found that the convexity effect was too small to influence hedging. Instead, they found that reducing volatility increased debt capacity, and therefore the value of tax advantages associated with debt. If going bankrupt brings additional expenses (legal fees, business interruption, etc.) then reducing the probability of ruin

Major and Venter: Why Transfer Risk? Page 3 decreases the expected cost. A more interesting line of inquiry is to consider whose shoulders the burden of bankruptcy falls upon. Bondholders, after all, do not view the firm in the same way that shareholders do. They demand a premium for the risk that they will not be repaid that is greater than the expected value of the shortfall. In Froot et. al. (1993), reduction in volatility is seen as decreasing the cost of external financing. However, bondholders do get first call on residual assets, before shareholders. It may be rational for shareholders to consider that too large a portion of an increase in earnings actually benefits the bondholders more than the shareholders. This can lead to a situation where the firm does not take sufficient advantage of its own growth and investment opportunities. This is the so-called underinvestment problem. Insurers cannot use debt directly to increase surplus, because the assets and liabilities would increase by the same amount, thus leaving surplus unchanged. A holding company, however, can use debt to increase the surplus of an insurance subsidiary. The holding company assets and liabilities increase by the same amount, but the insurer only gets the asset. An insurer with surplus infusions financed by debt can help reduce borrowing costs for its parent by engaging in an appropriate amount of risk transfer. Beyond equity and debt investors, there are other stakeholders that value certainty. Suppliers are often looking for long term

Major and Venter: Why Transfer Risk? Page 4 customers, and may offer less favorable terms if the buyer's financial condition appears vulnerable. Employees (who are, after all, not fully diversified in terms of their sources of wages) also could be expected to require higher pay in compensation for the possibility that the firm could go out of business due to an unhedged risk. In the specific case of insurance companies, and, by extension, any business with long-term customer relations, another class of interested parties must be considered: the customers (insureds). Mayers and Smith (1990) highlight the fact that probability of bankruptcy is an integral element of product quality. These stakeholder premiums can be significant drains on earnings. Garven and Lamm-Tennant (1997) include an explicit term for this, the default cost function, in their theoretical model of the value of an insurance firm. The risk of insurer bankruptcy is the key concern of rating agencies. The market relies upon them to quantify risk; both the bond rating and the claims paying rating look to stability as an issue. Clearly, higher bond ratings increase expected earnings by reducing debt costs. Similarly, one should be able to detect a price advantage from the claims paying rating. Reinsurance is a factor that rating agencies consider. Some insurers say they would not buy reinsurance if it were not for Best's ratings. The protection only achieves value when it becomes recognized in the marketplace, e.g., through a better rating and

Major and Venter: Why Transfer Risk? Page 5 improved prices and access to markets. Ratings agencies are the key mechanism by which policyholders and other stakeholders can assess the riskiness of the firm as one element of product quality. Insurance is also seen as more than a risk-transfer mechanism; it provides real services, e.g., in loss control or benefits and claims administration. Reinsurance similarly provides real services to an insurer expanding into a geographical area or line of business with which it has little experience or expertise. Also, as a confirmation of financial theory expectations, Mayers and Smith find that the less diversified the owners of an insurance company (e.g., Lloyd s companies versus widely-held stock companies), the more likely the company is to reinsure. Reinsurance in particular, and substitute risk transfer mechanisms in general, can be alternative forms of financing by allowing an insurer to write as if it had more surplus. If the servicing costs of debt exceed the loading elements of the reinsurance, risk transfer can increase the overall profitability. For mutual companies without access to either debt or equity markets, reinsurance can become the only viable financing arrangement. Mayers and Smith found that mutual companies do indeed buy more reinsurance than similarly situated stock companies. Hoyt and Khang (1999) also study the corporate insurance purchase decision. They find evidence that tax effects, as outlined in Mayers and Smith (1982) are important. Specifically,

Major and Venter: Why Transfer Risk? Page 6 insurance provides a faster adjustment of the depreciable basis of replacement property than does self-insurance. It also allows the firm to protect other tax benefits (investment tax credits, loss carry-forwards, etc.) Insuring depreciated assets can be profitable after tax. If the premium is a deductible expense, after tax it could be less than expected losses. At the same time if the recovery of a loss is not taxable income, after tax the expected recovery then exceeds the premium, with no offsetting book loss as the lost asset was depreciated. Hoyt and Khang found that insurance purchases increased significantly with increases in the ratio of cumulative depreciation to the historical cost of fixed assets. Minton and Schrand (1998) dig deeper into the nature of volatility and find a distinction between reducing the volatility of earnings and that of cash flow. Cash flow volatility is found to be associated with decreased levels of discretionary investment (the underinvestment problem ) and increased costs of external financing. Bond rating agencies and analysts appear to attend to cash flow volatility and not earnings volatility. On the other hand, stock analysts attend to earnings volatility. Finally, they find that a risk management strategy is only effective if it is expected to provide benefits extending into the future; one-shot fixes are of little help. A related problem is that of distinguishing a fluctuation from a trend. If earnings go down one quarter, is that a sign of a problem or just a one-time blip?

Major and Venter: Why Transfer Risk? Page 7 Accounting and regulatory issues provide another dimension of motivation for risk transfer. Statutory accounting for insurance companies requires proportional earning of policy expenses, such as commissions, even if these are paid up front. Thus an insurer receives a fraction of the premium at inception but books a reserve of 100%. This surplus strain creates additional financing needs. Another area of regulatory intervention is capital requirements. While arguably an appropriate province of regulation, there is no agreed upon objective method for the determination of necessary capital for an insurer. Erring on the conservative side, regulators are likely to increase the need for risk transfer beyond the levels dictated by financial theory. What are the implications of this for those of us engaged in the business of risk transfer? First, reducing earnings or cash flow volatility, or pushing back the probability of ruin, are generally not of value in and of themselves. They usually acquire value only through specific mechanisms that allow the client to reduce expenses, increase earnings, or engage in profitable activities that would otherwise not be possible. How well diversified are the owners? If not very well, then perhaps they do value stability per se. But even so, one should attend to those value-enhancing mechanisms. What is the tax situation of the client? Is there a convexity effect? Are there tax advantages that aren t being adequately

Major and Venter: Why Transfer Risk? Page 8 utilized? What is their inventory of depreciable assets? Examine the balance sheet. Is the client taking sufficient advantage of debt? What is the cost of external financing and can it be lowered? Consider the various stakeholders: customers, suppliers, and employees. How does the client s situation compare with successful peers? Is the client paying a premium in terms of higher costs or lower revenues because of an inferior risk position? This analysis starts (but shouldn t end) with ratings concerns. Are there real services advantages to be gained? An insurance solution may look expensive from a risk-financing viewpoint, but it may provide operational value in terms of services that are not being offered by an alternative. These need to be priced out accordingly. Are there accounting and regulatory issues that stand in the way of positive net present value projects? The intricacies involved here often dominate the analysis. So-called regulatory arbitrage between insurance and other sectors of the economy can result in substantial value to the firm undreamed of in finance theory. The possibilities for risk management in general and risk transfer in particular have grown dramatically in recent decades. In addition to insurance and reinsurance, there has been a growth in the use of financial derivatives as well as a convergence and blending with insurance derivatives ( securitization ) and

Major and Venter: Why Transfer Risk? Page 9 financial insurance ( insuratization ). These tools are being used in a more integrated fashion as firms look to enterprise risk management to foster a whole-firm, strategic approach. Finance theory and empirical research reveal that the goal of risk management for the firm is neither as monolithic nor as obvious as it might appear. There are numerous specific mechanisms by which risk reduction manifests itself in increased firm value, and these mechanisms translate into opportunities for the profitable application of risk transfer tools. But in order to take advantage of these opportunities, we must attend to the details. References: Froot, K. A., D. S. Scharfstein and J. C. Stein (1993) Risk management: coordinating corporate investment and financial policies, Journal of Finance 48, 1629-1658. Garven, J. R., and J. Lamm-Tennant (1997) The demand for reinsurance: theory and empirical tests, 5 th International Conference on Insurance Solvency and Finance; to appear in Journal of Business. Graham, J. R. and D. A. Rogers (1999) Is corporate hedging consistent with value maximization? An empirical analysis, Duke University.

Major and Venter: Why Transfer Risk? Page 10 Hoyt, R. E. and H. Khang (1999) On the demand for corporate property insurance, (being revised for resubmission to the Journal of Risk and Insurance). Mayers, D. and C. W. Smith (1982) On the corporate demand for insurance, Journal of Business 55, 281-296. Mayers, D. and C. W. Smith (1990) On the corporate demand for insurance: evidence from the reinsurance market, Journal of Business 63, 19-40. Minton, B. A. and C. Schrand (1998) Does cash flow volatility affect firm value: its impact on discretionary investment and the costs of debt and equity financing, Journal of Financial Economics 54, 432-460. Modigliani, F. and M. H. Miller (1958) The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment, American Economic Review 48, 261-297. -End-