REAL OPTIONS ANALYSIS HANDOUTS

Similar documents
FINANCIAL OPTION ANALYSIS HANDOUTS

CAPITAL INVESTMENT ANALYSIS HANDOUTS

CAPITAL INVESTMENT ANALYSIS HANDOUTS

Option Valuation with Binomial Lattices corrected version Prepared by Lara Greden, Teaching Assistant ESD.71

1. In this exercise, we can easily employ the equations (13.66) (13.70), (13.79) (13.80) and

FINANCIAL OPTION ANALYSIS HANDOUTS

B8.3 Week 2 summary 2018

Binomial model: numerical algorithm

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO. Faculty of Mathematics and Natural Sciences

Put-Call Parity. Put-Call Parity. P = S + V p V c. P = S + max{e S, 0} max{s E, 0} P = S + E S = E P = S S + E = E P = E. S + V p V c = (1/(1+r) t )E

Chapter 14 Exotic Options: I

Real Options and Game Theory in Incomplete Markets

Fixed Income and Risk Management

MS-E2114 Investment Science Lecture 10: Options pricing in binomial lattices

The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing

Chapter 22: Real Options

The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing

Homework Assignments

SYSM 6304: Risk and Decision Analysis Lecture 6: Pricing and Hedging Financial Derivatives

Lattice Model of System Evolution. Outline

Introduction to Real Options

Motivating example: MCI

Page 1. Real Options for Engineering Systems. Financial Options. Leverage. Session 4: Valuation of financial options

BUSM 411: Derivatives and Fixed Income

Notes: This is a closed book and closed notes exam. The maximal score on this exam is 100 points. Time: 75 minutes

MS-E2114 Investment Science Exercise 10/2016, Solutions

Pricing Options with Binomial Trees

MATH 425: BINOMIAL TREES

non linear Payoffs Markus K. Brunnermeier

Chapter 22: Real Options

Chapter 24 Interest Rate Models

MAFS525 Computational Methods for Pricing Structured Products. Topic 1 Lattice tree methods

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Binomial Option Pricing

Fixed-Income Analysis. Assignment 7

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015

Lattice Model of System Evolution. Outline

Term Structure Lattice Models

Conoco s Value and IPO: Real Options Analysis 1

IAPM June 2012 Second Semester Solutions

B6302 B7302 Sample Placement Exam Answer Sheet (answers are indicated in bold)

Model Calibration and Hedging

B6302 Sample Placement Exam Academic Year

Review of Derivatives I. Matti Suominen, Aalto

Arbitrage Enforced Valuation of Financial Options. Outline

Hedging and Pricing in the Binomial Model

Final Exam. Please answer all four questions. Each question carries 25% of the total grade.

Name: MULTIPLE CHOICE. 1 (5) a b c d e. 2 (5) a b c d e TRUE/FALSE 1 (2) TRUE FALSE. 3 (5) a b c d e 2 (2) TRUE FALSE.

Futures and Forward Markets

Real Options. Katharina Lewellen Finance Theory II April 28, 2003

Combining Real Options and game theory in incomplete markets.

Multi-Period Binomial Option Pricing - Outline

Chapter 9 - Mechanics of Options Markets

Value of Flexibility in Managing R&D Projects Revisited

AFM 271 Practice Problem Set #2 Spring 2005 Suggested Solutions

Economic Risk and Decision Analysis for Oil and Gas Industry CE School of Engineering and Technology Asian Institute of Technology

15 American. Option Pricing. Answers to Questions and Problems

Aalto. Derivatives LECTURE 5. Professor: Matti SUOMINEN. 17 Pages

Econ 174 Financial Insurance Fall 2000 Allan Timmermann. Final Exam. Please answer all four questions. Each question carries 25% of the total grade.

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

******************************* The multi-period binomial model generalizes the single-period binomial model we considered in Section 2.

Binomial Trees. Liuren Wu. Options Markets. Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College. Liuren Wu (Baruch ) Binomial Trees Options Markets 1 / 22

Problem Set. Solutions to the problems appear at the end of this document.

Real Option Valuation. Entrepreneurial Finance (15.431) - Spring Antoinette Schoar

Arbitrage-Free Pricing of XVA for American Options in Discrete Time

Chapter 9. Risk Analysis and Real Options

Arbitrage-Free Pricing of XVA for Options in Discrete Time

CHAPTER 12 APPENDIX Valuing Some More Real Options

Option Valuation (Lattice)

Martingale Pricing Applied to Dynamic Portfolio Optimization and Real Options

Real Options. Bernt Arne Ødegaard. 23 November 2017

FNCE 302, Investments H Guy Williams, 2008

Forwards, Swaps, Futures and Options

Resource Allocation and Decision Analysis (ECON 8010) Spring 2014 Foundations of Decision Analysis

Introduction to Binomial Trees. Chapter 12

Advanced Numerical Methods

Option Pricing Models. c 2013 Prof. Yuh-Dauh Lyuu, National Taiwan University Page 205

Options Markets: Introduction

M339W/M389W Financial Mathematics for Actuarial Applications University of Texas at Austin In-Term Exam I Instructor: Milica Čudina

CHAPTER 17 OPTIONS AND CORPORATE FINANCE

MAFS Computational Methods for Pricing Structured Products

OPTIONS. Options: Definitions. Definitions (Cont) Price of Call at Maturity and Payoff. Payoff from Holding Stock and Riskfree Bond

TIM 50 Fall 2011 Notes on Cash Flows and Rate of Return

CHAPTER 22. Real Options. Chapter Synopsis

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

Trinomial Tree. Set up a trinomial approximation to the geometric Brownian motion ds/s = r dt + σ dw. a

Topics in Corporate Finance. Chapter 2: Valuing Real Assets. Albert Banal-Estanol

M339W/389W Financial Mathematics for Actuarial Applications University of Texas at Austin Sample In-Term Exam I Instructor: Milica Čudina

Global Financial Management

B. Combinations. 1. Synthetic Call (Put-Call Parity). 2. Writing a Covered Call. 3. Straddle, Strangle. 4. Spreads (Bull, Bear, Butterfly).

MTH6154 Financial Mathematics I Interest Rates and Present Value Analysis

Handout 4: Deterministic Systems and the Shortest Path Problem

Risk-neutral Binomial Option Valuation

Option pricing models

6. Numerical methods for option pricing

4: Single Cash Flows and Equivalence

Structural Models of Credit Risk and Some Applications

Options in Corporate Finance

S u =$55. S u =S (1+u) S=$50. S d =$48.5. S d =S (1+d) C u = $5 = Max{55-50,0} $1.06. C u = Max{Su-X,0} (1+r) (1+r) $1.06. C d = $0 = Max{48.

MATH 4512 Fundamentals of Mathematical Finance

Transcription:

REAL OPTIONS ANALYSIS HANDOUTS 1

2

REAL OPTIONS ANALYSIS MOTIVATING EXAMPLE Conventional NPV Analysis A manufacturer is considering a new product line. The cost of plant and equipment is estimated at $700M. The product line will be viable for a period of 20 years. There are three equally likely market outcomes: High, Expected and Failure. High : Product line takes off and is a big success. Expected after-tax cash flow given plant capacity is $200M. Expected : Product line generates an after-tax cash flow of $100M, as expected. Failure : Product line generates no income. The company estimates that the expected after-tax cash flow to be $100M per year for the next 20 years. A 15% cost of capital is used for projects with this type of risk. Should the company invest in the new product line? Real Options Analysis Upon further review, management recognizes it has some options available. If the market outcome is high, it can retrofit the facility to create additional capacity at a cost of $500M, and this will generate an additional $150M in after-tax cash flow. The company can also liquidate its investment in plant and equipment for $150M. Given the available options, should the company invest in the new product line? Additional Information: The share price of a mutual fund that invests in stocks in similar companies is $50. The CFO s assessment of how the fund s share price will correlate with the product line market outcome is: Market outcome for new product line High Expected Failure Fund s share price 100 (100% return) 40 (-20% return) 30 (-40% return) The risk-free rate is 3%. 3

4

REAL OPTION ANALYSIS EXAMPLE 1 A company is considering investing in a project. The present value (PV) of future discounted expected cash flows is either 3000 if the market goes up or 500 if the market goes down next year. The objective probability the market will go up is 20%. The appropriate risk-adjusted rate of return (cost of capital) is 25%. The initial capital investment required at time 0 is 1200. The risk-free rate is 10% per year. a. Determine the PV of the project at time 0. b. Determine the NPV of the project at time 0. c. Should the company invest in this project? d. Upon closer inspection the CFO realizes the company actually has some flexibility in managing this project. Specifically, if the market goes down, the company can abandon the project, and liquidate its original capital investment (at time 0) for 75% of its value. If, however, the market should go up, the company can expand operations. With expansion the PV (as seen at the end of next year) will be twice the original PV forecast. To expand the company will have to make an additional capital expenditure of 800. The CFO wants to know if the company should now proceed with the project with the added flexibilities, and asks for you advice. Use the original project without flexibility as the traded underlying security. 5

REAL OPTION ANALYSIS EXAMPLE 2 A company is considering investing in a project. The present value (PV) of future discounted expected cash flows is either 8000 if the market goes up or 3000 if the market goes down next year. The objective probability the market will go up is 30%. The appropriate risk-adjusted rate of return (cost of capital) is 25%. The initial capital investment required at time 0 is 4000. The risk-free rate is 5% per year. a. Determine the PV of the project without flexibility at time 0. b. Determine the NPV of the project without flexibility at time 0. c. Should the company invest in this project without flexibility? d. Suppose the company has some flexibility in managing this project. Specifically, if the market goes down, the company can abandon the project, and liquidate its original capital investment (at time 0) for 50% of its original value. The company can also expand operations next year. With expansion the PV (as seen at the end of next year) will be 50% larger than the original PV forecast. To expand the company will have to make an additional capital expenditure of 1000. Using the original project without flexibility as the traded underlying security, determine the ROA value of this project with flexibility. e. What is the cost of capital that will yield the correct value if the objective probabilities are used? 6

REAL OPTION ANALYSIS EXAMPLE 3 A company is considering investing in a project. The present value (PV) of future discounted expected cash flows is either 10,000 if the market goes up or 5,000 if the market goes down next year. The objective probability the market will go up is 60%. The appropriate risk-adjusted rate of return (cost of capital) is 25%. The initial capital investment required at time 0 is 8,000. The risk-free rate is 10% per year. a. Determine the PV of the project at time 0. b. Determine the NPV of the project at time 0. c. Should the company invest in this project? d. The company has some flexibility in managing this project. Specifically, if the market goes down, the company can abandon the project, and liquidate its original capital investment (at time 0) for 50% of its original value. The company can also expand operations next year. With expansion the PV (as seen at the end of next year) will be twice the original PV. To expand the company will have to make an additional capital expenditure of 4,000. Determine the ROA value of this project with flexibility. Use the original project without flexibility as the traded underlying security. e. What is the cost of capital that will yield the correct value if the objective probabilities are used? 7

8

A DELAY OPTION EXAMPLE The real-estate price for a one-unit condominium, P, is currently $100 thousand. Next year the price will, with equal probability, rise to either $150 thousand, if the market moves favorably, or decline to $90 thousand, if the market moves unfavorably. The construction cost (both now and next year) for a 6-unit building is $80 thousand per unit, and $90 thousand for a 9-unit building. Construction is instantaneous, and rent covers operating expenses, so no free cash flow is generated now or next year. The risk-free rate is 10%. Questions: 1. Should the company invest in this real estate construction project? 2. What is the value of this real estate construction project? 3. Let S t denote the price of a non-dividend paying stock. The price process of S follows a binomial lattice with U = 1.5 and D = 0.90. S 0 = 100 and R = 1.1. Let C(T, K) denote a European call option on S with a maturity of T years and strike price of K. a. Determine the time 0 price of C(1, 80). b. Determine the time 0 price of C(1, 110). c. Determine the cost of the portfolio of 6C(1, 80) +3C(1, 110). d. Compare the answers to questions 2 and 3(c). e. Let V 1 (P 1 ) denote the final payoffs of this real estate construction project. Write a formula for V 1 (P 1 ). Here, we consider the general case P 1 0. f. Graphically depict the function V 1 ( ). (Label the x-axis P 1 and the y-axis V 1 (P 1 ).) g. Use (f) to explain (d). 4. What is the value of this real estate construction project if the delay option last for two years? 9

10

A REDEVELOPMENT OPTION EXAMPLE A real estate developer has the opportunity to redevelop a parcel of land over the next 5 years. Here is the relevant information: The project is valued today at 12.5 million. The project s (yearly) value follows a binomial lattice with U = 1.5 and D = 2/3. The project pays no dividends. The cost to develop the land today is 10 million. The development cost increases 10% each year. At the beginning of each year it costs 0.5 million to maintain the land if it is not developed for the upcoming year. If the land is developed, then there is no maintenance cost. During any year the developer may abandon the project and receive 1.2 million. The objective probability of the market going up is 70%. The risk-free rate is 10%. The real estate developer sees this redevelopment project as a great opportunity. In fact, she is ready to develop the land today, as she has calculated its NPV at 2.5 million. She asks your consulting company for advice on what to do. 11

12

REDEVELOPMENT OPTION SOLUTION 0 1 2 3 4 5 12.50 18.75 28.13 42.19 63.28 94.92 8.33 12.50 18.75 28.13 42.19 5.56 8.33 12.50 18.75 3.70 5.56 8.33 Project Value Event Tree Without Options 2.47 3.70 1.65 Capital Investment 10.00 11.00 12.10 13.31 14.64 16.11 Maintenance Cost 0.50 0.50 0.50 0.50 0.50 0 1 2 3 4 5 4.12 8.41 16.03 4 28.88 2 48.64 1 78.81 1.47 3.06 5 6.43 13.49 26.08 1.20 1.20 3 1.27 2.64 1.20 1.20 1.20 Project NPV Event Tree With Options 1.20 1.20 1.20 The numbers in bold signify the development project should be undertaken. Since the developer could begin development today for an NPV of 2.5 million, and since the value of the development when the delay option exists is 4.12 million, the developer would be willing to pay up to 1.62 million to acquire these options. q = (R D)/(U D) = (1.1 2/3)/(1.5 2/3) = 0.52. 1 78.81 = 94.92 16.11. 2 48.64 = max{ Develop: 63.28 14.64, Continue: [0.52(78.81) + 0.48(26.08)]/1.1 0.50, Abandon: 1.20}. 3 1.27 = max{ Develop: 12.50 14.64, Continue: [0.52(2.64) + 0.48(1.20)]/1.1 0.50, Abandon: 1.20}. 4 28.88 = max{ Develop: 42.19 13.31, Continue: [0.52(48.64) + 0.48(13.49)]/1.1 0.50, Abandon: 1.20}. 5 6.43 = max{ Develop: 18.75 13.31, Continue: [0.52(13.49) + 0.48(1.27)]/1.1 0.50, Abandon: 1.20}. 13

14

A GROWTH OPTION EXAMPLE A biotech project involves a pioneer venture stage to first prove the new technology in order to establish its viability for future commercial development of spin-off products. The pioneer venture involves high initial costs and insufficient projected cash inflows. If the technology proves successful, subsequent product commercialization can be many times the size of the pioneer venture. Consider the following data for a particular biotech project. The pioneer venture requires an initial investment outlay of I 0 = $100 million, and expected cash inflows over two years of C 1 = $54 million and C 2 = $36 million. The follow-on product commercialization stage will become available at the end of year two, and its expected cash flows are 10 times the size of the pioneer venture. That is, I 2 = $1,000 million, and the expected cash inflows over the subsequent two years are C 3 = $540 million and C 4 = $360 million. The cost of capital is 20% and the risk-free rate is 2.5%. (All rates are compounded annually.) Questions: 1. Should the company invest in the pioneer venture? 2. Should the company invest in the follow-on product commercialization stage? 3. Should the company invest in this biotech project? 15

16

A TREE FARM EXAMPLE You are considering an investment in a tree farm. Here are the relevant data: Trees grow each year by the following factors: Year 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Growth 1.6 1.5 1.4 1.3 1.2 1.15 1.1 1.02 1.01 Thus, if the initial number of trees is X, then at the end of one year there would be 1.6X trees, at the end of 2 years there would be 2.4X, etc. The price of lumber follows a binomial lattice with U = 1.20 and D = 0.90. The risk-free rate is 10%. It costs $2 million each year, payable at the beginning of the year, to lease the forest land. The initial value of the trees is $5 million (assuming they were harvested immediately). You can cut down the trees at the beginning of any year, collect the proceeds and not have to pay rent after that. What is the real options value of this investment opportunity? 17

18

A GOLD MINE EXAMPLE A company has the option to acquire a ten-year lease to extract gold from a gold mine. The lease should be acquired if its cost is less than the value of the lease. Here are the relevant data: The mine capacity is 50,000 ounces. When the begin-of-year mine inventory is I, the cost to mine Q ounces for the upcoming year is 500*Q 2 /I. Production occurs instantaneously. Profits each year accrue at the beginning of the year. The price of gold follows a binomial lattice with parameters U = 1.25 and D = 0.80. The risk-free rate is 2.5%. Determine the real options value of the gold mine lease. 19

20

Real Options Analysis In these notes we show how to apply Real Options Analysis (ROA). We will develop the ideas by examining five classic Real Options problems. We will also illustrate the potential pitfalls of applying Decision Tree Analysis (DTA), a close companion of ROA. 1 The Delay Option 1.1 Background information Relevant information pertaining to a project under consideration is as follows: 1. In year 1, the project s present value (of discounted expected subsequent future) cash flow will be 1500 if the market goes up next year and will be 666. 6 if the market goes down next year. The project s present value cash flow in year 2 will be as follows: if the market goes up two consecutive years, then it will be 2250; if the market goes up and then down or down and then up, then it will be 1000; if the market goes down two consecutive years, then it will be 444. 4. 2. The project pays no dividends. 3. The probability of the market going up each year is 0.70. 4. The project s initial investment I 0 (at time 0) is 1050. 5. It is possible to delay the project one year. To do so will cost the company 175 today, and the required investment next year will increase by 10%. 6. In year 1 the company can spend an additional 25 (at time 1) to delay the project one more year. The required investment will increase by another 10%. 7. There is a tradable (non-dividend) security S whose current price is 100. Its price process follows a binomial lattice with U = 1.5 and D = U 1 = 0. 6. 8. The risk-free rate is 5%. 1.2 Analysis of the project without the delay option The first step is to determine the project s value today. The project s payoffs P are perfectly correlated with the tradable security, i.e., P = 10S. Thus, the market value of P today must be 1000. This is the present value of the project. 21

The project s initial investment I 0 (at time 0) is 1050. The project s Net Present Value (NP V ) is given by NP V = P V I 0 = 1000 1050 = 50 < 0. (1) Since the NPV is negative, the project without the delay option should be rejected. 1.3 Analysis of the one year delay option Consider the project with the one year delay option. Its value next year is determined, as follows. If the market goes up, the company should make the investment, and its value is 1500 (1.1)(1050) = 345; (2) if, however, the market goes down, then its value is zero since the company would not make the investment. What is the value today for such a risky payoff? We examine two approaches. DTA analysis Let s first examine how traditional DT A would analyze this opportunity. The project s cost of capital is 25% since 0.7(1500) + 0.3(666. 6) = 1000. (3) 1.25 Accordingly, using DT A the NPV would be determined as follows: (0.7)(345) + (0.3)(0) NP V = 175 = 18.2 > 0. (4) 1.25 Since the NPV is positive, traditional DTA says the project with the one year delay option should be undertaken and implemented next year only if the market goes up. ROA analysis The use of DT A is not correct given the present setup. Let s use Real Options Analysis (ROA) to see why. The risk-neutral probability of the market going up is 0.46, since 0.46(150) + 0.54(66. 6) = 100. (5) 22

Therefore, the correct value of the project today is computed as 0.46(345) + 0.54(0) 175 = 23.86 < 0, (6) and so the correct NP V says the delay option and the project should be rejected. Since How can we verify/explain this? The P V of the project is 151.14 since 151.14 175 = 23.86. (7) P S = 345 0 = 4.14, (8) 150 66. 6 the replicating portfolio of S and the money market M is (4.14S, 262.86M), (9) which, not surprisingly, costs 151.14 to purchase. This portfolio s value next year will either be 345 if the market goes up or 0 if the market goes down, which exactly matches the value of the project with the delay option. If someone insists the correct PV is 193.2 (193.2 = 18.2 + 175), then, in principle, you sell this person a similar project for 193.2 and buy the replicating portfolio for 151.14. The replicating portfolio will fully hedge your position and you will make 193.2 151.14 = 42.06 today, risk-free. Remark. Using DT A can work, but only if the cost of capital is properly adjusted. The expected value of next year s project value using the objective probabilities is (0.7)(345) = 241.5. Consequently, if one uses a cost of capital of 59.79%, then the P V will be 151.14, as required. As we have remarked in class, it is often difficult to arrive at correct values for the cost of capital at each project state since the project s risk characteristics typically change over the life of the project. Recall there is another way to arrive at the cost of capital of 59.79%. The replicating portfolio weights are w S = 4.14(100)/151.14 = 2.739 (10) w M = 262.86/151.14 = 1.739, (11) respectively. Since r S = 25% and r M = 5%, the replicating portfolio s expected return is 2.739(25) 1.739(5) = 59.79. (12) 23

Table 1: Project value event tree without flexibility t = 0 t = 1 t = 2 1000 1500.00 2250.00 666.66 1000.00 444.44 Sensitivity analysis Let ρ denote the premium cost today to delay the project, and let 100γ% denote the percentage increase in the required investment. As a function of ρ and γ, it is possible to determine the acceptance region for the project. In what follows we assume that γ > 0 and (1 + θ)(1050) < 1500. As a function of ρ and γ, the project s correct NP V is 0.46[1500 (1 + γ)1050] ρ, (13) which must be positive if the project with the delay option is to be accepted. The acceptance region is therefore {(γ, ρ) : 197.14 460γ + ρ}. (14) 1.4 Analysis of the two year delay option Project value event tree without flexibility Table 1 records the Project value event tree without flexibility, which we take as our underlying tradable security or the twin security. Project value event tree with flexibility The project with flexibility may be viewed as a collection of options on the underlying security. Table 2 records the Project NPV event tree with flexibility according to ROA. Here is how these numbers were obtained. The project will not be undertaken next year if the market goes down. We need to assess the correct project value (with the delay options) if the market goes up. If the project is not delayed one more year, then the project s value is 345, as before. However, the company does 24

Table 2: Project NPV event tree with flexibility (* = delay) t = 0 t = 1 t = 2 *2.04 *404.11 979.50 0.00 0.00 0.00 have the option to delay one more year, and this option must be considered at this point in time. If the company chooses to delay one more year, the discounted expected project value using the risk-neutral probability is 0.46[1.5(1500) (1.1) 2 (1050)] = 429.11. (15) After subtracting the cost of 25 the value in this state is 404.11. Since 404.11 > 345 it is optimal to delay the project 1 more year should the market go up next year. We conclude that the project s value next year is thus 404.11 if the market goes up and 0 if the market goes down. The correct NP V for this project (with the delay options) is therefore equal to 0.46(404.11) 175 = 2.04 > 0, (16) and so the project with the two year delay option should be accepted. 25

2 Option to Contract Operations 2.1 Background information A company is considering investing two projects. Relevant information is as follows: 1. Each project requires an initial investment of 80 million. 2. Each project has a present value without flexibility of 100 million. 3. Each project pays no dividends. 4. The annual volatility for the present value of project 1 is 40% (i.e. σ = 0.40) whereas the annual volatility for the present value of project 2 is 20%. 5. The appropriate cost of capital for each project is 12%. 6. The company has only 80 million to spend on new investment, so only one project may be selected. 7. With each project it is possible to contract operations by 40% at any time during the next two years. If operations are contracted, the salvage value (cash received) for project 1 is 33 million and 42 million for project 2. 8. The risk-free rate is 5%. 2.2 Analysis of the projects without the option to contract Tables 3 and 4 record the respective project value event trees without flexibility. For project 1 the value for U = e σ( t)1/2 = e 0.40(1)1/2 = 1.4918 (and so D = 1/U = 0.6703) and for project 2 the value for U = e σ( t)1/2 = e 0.20(1)1/2 = 1.2214 (and so D = 1/U = 0.8187). With an initial investment of 80 million, each project has an NPV of 20 million, which is positive. Therefore, the company should invest in one of the projects. For subsequent reference the value event tree for each project has 6 nodes, which we shall label, respectively, as {0, u, d, uu, ud = du, dd}. 26

Table 3: Project 1 value event tree without flexibility t = 0 t = 1 t = 2 100 149.18 222.55 67.03 100.00 44.93 Table 4: Project 2 value event tree without flexibility t = 0 t = 1 t = 2 100 122.14 149.18 81.87 100.00 67.03 2.3 DTA Analysis DTA uses the objective probabilities and the cost of capital for the project without flexibility. Let p i denote the probability for the up state for project i, i = 1, 2. Since the cost of capital for each project is 12%, it follows that 149.18p 1 + 67.03(1 p 1 ) 1.12 122.14p 2 + 81.87(1 p 2 ) 1.12 = 100 = p 1 = 0.547, (17) = 100 = p 2 = 0.748. (18) Analysis of project 1 Table 5 records the NPV event tree with flexibility using DTA. Here is how these numbers were obtained. Table 5: Project 1 NPV event tree with flexibility using DTA (* = contract) t = 0 t = 1 t = 2 22.47 149.18 222.55 *73.22 100.00 *59.96 27

Table 6: Project 2 NPV event tree with flexibility using DTA (* = contract) t = 0 t = 1 t = 2 22.36 122.58 149.18 *91.09 *102.00 *82.22 We must work backwards through the value event tree. Assume the company has reached year 2 and has not yet exercised its option to contract. It does not pay to contract in states uu and ud, and so their respective values remain the same at 222.55 and 100, respectively. In state dd it does pay to contact since and so the value here is 59.96. 0.6(44.93) + 33 = 59.96 > 44.93, (19) Now let s move back to year 1, and suppose the company has not yet exercised its option to contract. In state u it would not pay to contract. Now consider state d. If the company chooses to contract now, then the value would be 0.6(67.03) + 33 = 73.22. (20) The company can, however, choose not to contract, and then the value would be 0.547(100) + 0.453(59.96) 1.12 = 73.09. (21) The best choice at state d is therefore to contract, and the associated value is 73.22. Now let s move back to year 0. Its value is 0.547(149.18) + 0.453(73.22) 1.12 which gives an NP V of 102.47 80 = 22.47. = 102.47, (22) According to DT A the option to contract is worth 2.47. Moreover, according to DT A the option to contract should be exercised in year 1 if state d occurs. Analysis of project 2 Table 6 records the NPV event tree with flexibility using DTA. Here is how these numbers are obtained. 28

We must work backwards through the value event tree. Assume the company has reached year 2 and has not yet exercised its option to contract. It does not pay to contract in state uu, and so its value remains the same at 149.18. In state ud it does pay to contact since 0.6(100) + 42 = 102 > 100, (23) and so the value in state ud is 102. In state dd it also pays to contact since and so the value in state dd is 82.22. 0.6(67.03) + 42 = 82.22 > 67.03, (24) Now let s move back to year 1, and suppose the company has not yet exercised its option to contract. In state u it would not pay to contract. Its (new) P V is 0.748(149.18) + 0.252(102) = 122.58. (25) 1.12 Now consider state d. If the company chose to contract now, then the value would be 0.6(81.87) + 42 = 91.09. (26) The company can, however, choose not to contract, and then the value would be 0.748(102) + 0.252(82.22) = 85.29. (27) 1.12 The best choice is therefore to contract in state d, and the associated value is 91.09. Now let s move back to year 0. Its value according to DT A is 0.748(122.58) + 0.252(91.09) = 102.36, (28) 1.12 which gives an NP V of 102.36 80 = 22.36. According to DT A the option to contract for project 2 is worth 2.36. Moreover, according to DT A the option to contract should be exercised in year 1 if state d occurs or in year 2 if state ud occurs. Since the NPV for project 1 (2.47) is higher than that for project 2 (2.36), the company should invest in project 1 according to DTA. 2.4 ROA Analysis ROA uses the risk-neutral probabilities and the risk-free rate to perform the discounted expectation for valuation purposes when working backwards through the P V tree. Using ROA requires that an underlying marketable security be identified that can be used to construct the replicating portfolio; here, we take the project without flexibility as such a security. The project and the money complete the market, i.e., span all possible valuations on the event tree, which then implies risk-neutral valuation will work and provide the correct valuation. 29

Table 7: Project 1 NPV event tree with flexibility using ROA (* = contract) t = 0 t = 1 t = 2 23.92 149.18 222.55 74.72 100.00 *59.96 Analysis of project 1 Table 7 records the Project 1 NPV event tree with flexibility using ROA. Here is how these numbers are obtained. For project 1 the risk-neutral probability q 1 must satisfy We now proceed, as before. 149.18q 1 + 67.03(1 q 1 ) = 100 = q 1 = 0.462. (29) Assume the company has reached year 2 and has yet to have exercised its option to contract. The terminal values in year 2 are unaffected here by the change in probabilities and discount rate. The values for states {uu, ud, dd} are, respectively, {222.55, 100, 59.96}. (If the operations have not been contracted by year 2, then the company should contract them in state dd.) Now let s move back to year 1, and suppose the company has not yet exercised its option to contract. In state u it would not pay the company to contract. In this state the value will still be 149.18 = 0.462(222.55) + 0.538(100). (30) Now consider state d. If the company chooses to contract now, then the value would be 0.6(67.03) + 33 = 73.22, (31) which has not changed. The company can, however, choose not to contract, and then the value according to ROA would be 0.462(100) + 0.538(59.96) = 74.72. (32) The best choice is therefore not to contract, and the associated value is 74.72. example of a difference between recommendations using DT A and ROA.) (Here is an 30

Table 8: Project 2 NPV event tree with flexibility using ROA (* = contract) t = 0 t = 1 t = 2 24.16 122.93 149.18 *91.09 *102.00 *82.22 Now let s move back to year 0. Its value according to ROA is 0.462(149.18) + 0.538(74.72) = 103.92, (33) which gives an NP V of 103.92 80 = 23.92. The correct value of the option to contract is 3.92 for Project 1. The company should only contract operations if it reaches state dd in year 2. Analysis of project 2 Table 8 records the Project 2 NPV event tree with flexibility using ROA. Here is how these numbers are obtained. For project 2 the risk-neutral probability q 2 must satisfy We now proceed, as before. 122.14q 2 + 81.87(1 q 2 ) = 100 = q 2 = 0.574. (34) Assume the company has reached year 2 and has not yet exercised its option to contract. The terminal values in year 2 are unaffected here by the change in probabilities and discount rate. The values for states {uu, ud, dd} are, respectively, {149.18, 102, 82.22}. (If the company has not contacted operations by year 2, then it should contract them if either state ud or dd.) Now let s move back to year 1, and suppose the company has not yet exercised its option to contract. In state u it would not pay the company to contract. In this state the value will be 0.574(149.18) + 0.426(102) = 122.93. (35) (This value will change since the value for state ud changed.) Now consider state d. If the company chooses to contract now, then the value would be 0.6(81.87) + 42 = 91.09, (36) 31

which has not changed. The company can, however, choose not to contract, and then the value according to ROA would be 0.574(102) + 0.426(82.22) = 89.12. (37) The best choice is therefore to contract, and the associated value is still 91.09. Now let s move back to year 0. Its value according to ROA is 0.574(122.93) + 0.426(91.09) = 104.16, (38) which gives an NP V of 104.16 80 = 24.16. The correct value of the option to contract is 4.16 for Project 2. The company should contract operations if it reaches state d in year 1. 2.5 Comparison of DTA to ROA DT A recommends Project 1 since 22.47 > 22.36, whereas ROA recommends Project 2 since 24.16 > 23.92. (They are close.) The optimal contract policy changes, too. 32

Table 9: Project value event tree without flexibility t = 0 t = 1 t = 2 t = 3 100 134.99 182.21 245.96 74.08 100.00 134.99 54.88 74.08 40.66 3 Option to Abandon Operations 3.1 Background information A company is considering investing in a project. Relevant information is as follows: 1. The project s present value without flexibility is 100 million. 2. The project pays no dividends. 3. The project s present value without flexibility has an annual volatility of 30%. 4. The project requires an initial investment of 108 million. 5. The appropriate cost of capital for the project is 15%. 6. The company has the option to abandon operations at any time during the next 3 years, and receive an after-tax cash flow (salvage value) of 90 million. 7. The risk-free rate is 5%. 3.2 Analysis of project without flexibility The project s NPV is 100 108 = 8 < 0, and so this the company should not invest in the project without flexibility. For subsequent reference Table 9 records the Project value event tree for the project without flexibility. It has 10 nodes, which we shall label, respectively, as {0, u, d, uu, ud = du, dd, uuu, uud = udu = duu, udd = dud = ddu, ddd}. The value for U is e 0.30 = 1.3499 and D is e 0.30 = 0.7408. 33

Table 10: Project NPV event tree with flexibility using DTA (* = abandon) t = 0 t = 1 t = 2 t = 3-2.69 136.29 182.21 245.96 *90.00 104.55 134.99 *90.00 *90.00 *90.00 3.3 DTA analysis DT A uses the objective probabilities and the cost of capital of the project without flexibility. Let p denote the probability for the up state for the project. We must have 134.99p + 74.08(1 p) 1.15 = 100 = p = 0.672. (39) Table 10 records the NPV event tree with flexibility using DT A. Here is how these numbers were obtained. We work backwards through the value event tree. Suppose it is year 3 and the company has yet to exercise its option to abandon. This option will not be executed in states uuu and uud, and so their values remain the same. In states udd and ddd it does pay to execute the option, and the values in both states are 90. Now let s go back to year 2. In state uu it does not pay to execute the option, and its value will remain the same. It also does not pay to execute the option in state ud; its value is 0.672(134.99) + 0.328(90) 1.15 = 104.55. (40) In state dd it should be clear that the option should be executed, as it is better to receive the 90 now instead of next year. (In both future states from state dd the value is 90.) Now let s go back to year 1. In state u the option will not be executed; its value is 0.672(182.21) + 0.328(104.55) 1.15 = 136.29. (41) Now consider state d. If the option to abandon is executed the company receives 90. However, the company can choose not to abandon now; the value if the company choose not to abandon is 0.672(104.55) + 0.328(90) 1.15 = 86.76. (42) Thus, the option to abandon should be executed in state d, and its value in this state is 90. 34

Table 11: Project NPV event tree with flexibility using ROA (* = abandon) t = 0 t = 1 t = 2 t = 3 3.14 138.52 182.21 245.96 94.17 107.88 134.99 *90.00 *90.00 *90.00 Now let s go back to year 0. The value is 0.672(136.29) + 0.328(90) 1.15 = 105.31. (43) The NP V of the project is therefore 105.31 108 = 2.69 < 0, and so the project should be rejected. According to DT A the value of the option to abandon is worth 5.31 since the change in NP V is 2.69 ( 8) = 5.31. 3.4 ROA analysis For this project the risk-neutral probability q must satisfy 134.99p + 74.08(1 p) = 100 = q = 0.508. (44) Table 11 records the NPV event tree with flexibility using ROA. Here is how these numbers were obtained. We work backwards through the value event tree. Assume the company has reached year 3 and has not yet exercise its option to abandon. The terminal values in year 3 are unaffected here by the change in probabilities and discount rate. The values for states {uuu, uud, udd, ddd} are, respectively, {245.96, 134.99, 90, 90}. (If the company has not abandoned operations by year 3 it should abandon them if it reaches state udd or ddd.) Now let s go back to year 2, and suppose the company has not yet exercised its option to abandon. In state uu it does not pay to abandon, and its value will remain the same. It also does not pay to abandon in state ud; its value is 0.508(134.99) + 0.492(90) = 107.48. (45) In state dd it should be clear that the company should abandon, as it is better to receive the 90 now instead of next year. (In both future states from state dd the value is 90.) 35

Now let s go back to year 1. In state u the option will not be executed; its value is 0.508(182.21) + 0.492(107.48) 1.15 = 138.52. (46) Now consider state d. If the company abandons it receives 90. However, the company can choose not to abandon now; the value if the company continues the project is 0.508(107.48) + 0.492(90) = 94.17. (47) Thus, the option to abandon should not be executed in state d, and its value in this state is 94.17. Now let s go back to year 0. The value is 0.508(138.52) + 0.492(94.17) = 111.14. (48) The NP V of the project is therefore 111.14 108 = 3.14 > 0, and so the project should be accepted. It may be seen that the abandonment option here is equivalent to a three year American put option with strike price equal to 90. 3.5 Comparison of DTA to ROA ROA accepts the project; DT A rejects the project. ROA would not abandon the project if state d is reached in year 1, whereas DT A would. 36

4 The Installment Option 4.1 Background information A company is considering investing in two projects. Background information is as follows. 1. The present value of each project without flexibility is 100 million. 2. Each project pays no dividends. 3. The project value for each project without flexibility has an annual volatility of 80%. 4. The risk-free rate is 5%. 5. The present value (at the risk-free rate) of the required investment for each project is 102 million. 6. The required investment for project 1 is staged over time, as follows: 52 million at time 0, 21 million at time 1 and 33.075 million at time 2. The required investment for project 2 is staged over time, too, as follows: 22 million at time 0, 31.5 million at time 1 and 55.125 million at time 2. 7. For both projects their respective investments must be made to continue the project for the upcoming year. These investments may be viewed as planned. However, at any time the company has the option to default on its planned investment at which point the project is terminated. 8. The appropriate cost of capital for the project (without flexibility) is 20%. 4.2 Analysis of the projects without flexibility Both projects have an NPV of 100 102 = 2 < 0, and so the company should not invest in either project. Table 12 records the project value event tree for both projects. Here, U = e 0.80 = 2.2255 and D = 1/U = 0.4493. 37

Table 12: Project value event tree without flexibility t = 0 t = 1 t = 2 100 222.55 495.30 44.93 100.00 20.19 Table 13: Project 1 NPV event tree with flexibility using ROA (* = default) t = 0 t = 1 t = 2 3.06 169.98 462.22 0.54 66.92 *0.00 4.3 ROA analysis Analysis of project 1 Let q denote the risk-neutral probability for the up state. We must have 222.55q + 44.93(1 q) 100 = = q = 0.338. (49) Table 13 records the Project 2 NPV event tree with flexibility using ROA. Here is how these numbers were obtained. We must work backwards through the value event tree. Assume the company has reached year 2 and has not yet defaulted on its planned investments. In states uu and ud it pays the company to make its final planned investment, and so their values in these states become, respectively, 462.22 and 66.92. It does not pay to make the final investment in state dd, and so its value becomes 0. Now let s move back to year 1, and suppose the company has not yet defaulted on its planned investments. In state u it pays the company to make the investment. Its (new) value would be 0.338(462.22) + 0.662(66.92) 21 = 169.98. (50) Now consider state d. If the company chooses to continue with the project now, then the value at this state would be 0.338(66.92) + 0.662(0) 21 = 0.54. (51) 38

Table 14: Project 2 NPV event tree with flexibility using ROA (* = default) t = 0 t = 1 t = 2 22.58 138.48 440.17 *0.00 44.87 *0.00 Since this value is positive, the company should continue the project in state d. Now let s move back to year 0. Its value is 0.338(169.98) + 0.662(0.54) = 55.06, (52) which gives an NP V of 55.06 52 = 3.06. As the NP V is positive, the project is accepted. The value of the default option is 3.06 ( 2) = 5.06. If state dd is reached, then the final investment should not be made. Analysis of project 2 Table 14 records the Project 2 NPV event tree with flexibility using ROA. Here is how these numbers were obtained. We must work backwards through the value event tree. Assume the company has reached year 2 and has not yet defaulted on its planned investments. In states uu and ud it pays the company to make the final planned investment, and so their values in these states become, respectively, 440.17 and 44.87. It does not pay to make the final investment in state dd, and so its value becomes 0. Now let s move back to year 1, and suppose the company has not yet defaulted on its planned investments. In state u it would pay the company to make the investment. Its (new) value would be 0.338(440.17) + 0.662(44.87) 31.5 = 138.48. (53) Now consider state d. If the company chooses to continue with the project now, then the value at this state would be 0.338(44.87) + 0.662(0) 31.5 = 16.61. (54) Since this value is negative, the company should not make the planned investment in state d. 39

Now let s move back to year 0. Its value is 0.338(138.48) + 0.662(0) = 44.58, (55) which gives an NP V of 44.58 22 = 22.58. As the NP V is positive, the project should be accepted. The value of the default option is 22.58 ( 2) = 24.58. If state d is reached, then the project should be terminated. Remark. Project 2 has a much higher value than project 1 when the default option is in place. This is because its planned investments are back loaded as opposed to the first project s planned investments, which are front loaded. If it is possible to delay investment while learning about the project s value, then this will create extra value, as this example illustrates. 40

5 Switch Use Option A chemical company currently uses technology X to manufacture its final product, which has recently experienced an increase in demand. The company wants to build a new factory to satisfy demand for the next two years. It is considering using technology X again. It is also considering adopting two other technologies, Y and Z. 5.1 Background information 1. Technology X. If the company adopts technology X the current net cash flow is 100 with an annual volatility of 33.65%. The objective probability of going up from each node is 0.5. The appropriate cost of capital for this type of risky cash flows is 9%. The initial investment required to build the factory with technology X is 100. 2. Technology Y. The cost of material inputs used in Y are less volatile than those used in X, but the quality of the final good is less, and so it commands a lower (albeit less volatile) price. If technology Y is adopted, its current net cash flow would also be 100, but its annual volatility would only be 9.53%. The initial investment required to build the factory would also be 100 if technology Y were adopted. 3. Technology Z. Should it pay to do so, the chemical company also has the opportunity to acquire flexible technology Z, which can switch (at a cost) back and forth between technologies X and Y. The changeover cost from X to Y is 15, whereas it only costs 10 to switch from Y to X. The initial investment required to build the factory would be 110 if the flexible technology Z were adopted. 4. The risk-free rate is 5%. 5.2 ROA Analysis Technology X Since technology X has been in use for some time we can use it to model the underlying security. But, we have to be careful in what we model here. The first step here is to determine the cash flow event tree. The values in this tree are recorded in Table 15. Here, U = e 0.3365 = 1.4000 and D = 1/U = 0.7142. The cash flow event tree is not the value event tree. The value event tree at each node represents the present values of future discounted expected cash flows. We shall use the Running PV approach. We shall also use the objective probabilities with the appropriate cost of capital, 41

Table 15: Technology X cash flow event tree t = 0 t = 1 t = 2 100 140.00 196.00 71.42 100.00 51.02 Table 16: Technology X value event tree t = 0 t = 1 t = 2 29 275.78 196.00 140.70 100.00 51.02 since the cash flows with technology X are assumed to be marketed. (We cannot use risk-neutral probabilities here as there is no other underlying security from which to make this calculation.) Table 16 records the value event tree. Here is how these numbers were obtained. The P V s at states {uu, ud, dd} in year 2 correspond to their net cash flows, namely, they are {196, 100, 51.02}, respectively. Now consider state u in year 1. Its value is 0.5(196) + 0.5(100) 1.09 Similarly, the value in state d in year 2 is + 140 = 275.78. (56) In year 0 the P V is 0.5(100) + 0.5(51.02) 1.09 + 71.42 = 140.70. (57) 0.5(275.78) + 0.5(140.70) 1.09 + 100 = 29. (58) To perform ROA one needs an underlying marketable security. We shall use the value event tree for X as our marketed security (along with the money market) upon which to build a replicating portfolio. Constructing portfolios with X and the associated calculation of the risk-neutral probability is different here because the value event tree for X pays dividends. For example, one cannot meaningfully represent the value at time 0, 29, as a discounted expectation of the respective 42

Table 17: Technology Y cash flow event tree t = 0 t = 1 t = 2 100 110.00 121.00 90.91 100.00 82.64 future values 275.78 and 140.70 at time 1. Examining the calculation of 29 in (58), it could just as easily been determined via q(275.78) + (1 q)(140.70) + 100 = 29 = q = 0.443. (59) The cash flow at time 0, 100, does not figure into the calculation of the risk-neutral probability. (It did not figure into the discounted expectation when we used the objective probabilities with the cost of capital.) When constructing a portfolio with X, one assumes it is being valued ex-dividend; that is, after the dividend payout of 100. The ex-dividend cost of X at time 0 is 19. The number 29 is called the cum-dividend value. You may verify that the risk-neutral probability of 0.443 will be the same at every node. For example, 0.443(196.00) + 0.557(100.00) + 140 = 275.78 (60) 0.443(100.00) + 0.557(51.02) + 71.42 = 140.70. (61) For the specific type of cash flow event tree here this fact will always be true. Note that the risk-neutral probability that would be calculated using the cash flow event tree directly is 105 71.42 = 0.4896, (62) 140 71.42 which is definitely not equal to the correct value 0.443. One must always calculate the riskneutral probability on the event tree coinciding with the tradable/marketable security. Technology Y Once again to determine the value event tree we first must determine the cash flow event tree. Table 17 records the cash flow event tree. Here, U = e 0.0953 = 1.1000 and D = 1/U = 0.9091. It is tempting at this point to proceed as we did for technology X; however, the cash flow stream for Y is clearly less volatile than that for X so the cost of capital should be lower. In lieu 43

Table 18: Technology Y value event tree t = 0 t = 1 t = 2 284.19 214.10 121.00 176.94 100.00 82.64 of estimating the cost of capital for Y, we will use the value event tree for X as our marketed security (along with the money market) upon which to build a replicating portfolio. Now we are in position to properly value the present values of future discounted expected cash flows for technology Y. We use the Running PV approach using the risk-neutral probabilities. Table 18 records the value event tree. Here is how these numbers were obtained. The P V s at states {uu, ud, dd} in year 2 correspond to their net cash flows, namely, they are {121, 100, 82.64}, respectively. Now consider state u in year 1. Its value is 0.443(121) + 0.557(100) Similarly, the value in state d in year 2 is In year 0 the P V is 0.443(100) + 0.557(82.64) 0.443(214.10) + 0.557(176.94) + 110 = 214.10. (63) + 90.91 = 176.94. (64) + 100 = 284.19. (65) Remark. To determine the appropriate cost of capital k Y for technology Y we use the objective probabilities; that is, k Y satisfies 0.5(214.10) + 0.5(176.94) 1 + k Y = 184.19 = k Y = 6.15%. (66) It will be the same at any node along the tree. (If one uses the risk-neutral probabilities, the cost of capital would be simply 5%.) Technology Z Table 19 records the value event tree corresponding to technology Z assuming the switching costs are zero. (Assume the value event trees for X and Y correspond to the same states of nature.) Here is how these numbers were calculated. 44

Table 19: Technology Z value event tree with no switching costs. The letter(s) in parentheses indicate the optimal technology to employ at each state. t = 0 t = 1 t = 2 (X/Y) 310.22 (X) 275.78 (X) 196.00 (Y) 176.94 (X/Y) 100.00 (Y) 82.64 Table 20: Technology Z value event tree with switching costs (* = switch) t = 0 t = 1 t = 2 X Y X Y X Y 302.26 306.00 275.78 *265.78 196.00 *186.00 *161.94 176.94 100.00 100.00 *67.64 82.64 With no changeover costs it is clearly optimal to use the technology with the highest net cash flow each period depending on the state of nature. In year 2 the P V s corresponding to states {uu, ud, dd} are, respectively, {196, 100, 82.64}. Now consider state u in year 1. Its value is 0.443(196) + 0.557(100) The value value for state d in year 1 is In year 0 the P V value is 0.443(100) + 0.557(82.64) 0.443(275.78) + 0.557(176.94) + 140 = 275.78. (67) + 90.91 = 176.94. (68) + 100 = 310.22. (69) When there are changeover costs the calculations become more involved, as it is necessary to know what technology is currently in operation in order to decide if it is optimal to switch use. Table 20 records the value event tree with switching costs. Here is how these numbers were obtained. Let V tx ( ), resp. V ty ( ), denote the value function in year t given the company enters year t using technology X (resp. Y ). In state uu in year 2 it pays the company to switch from Y to X, and in state dd in year 2 it pays the company to switch from X to Y ; otherwise, it does not 45

pay to switch use. Thus, V 2X (uu) = 196; V 2X (ud) = 100; V 2X (dd) = 67.64, and V 2Y (uu) = 186; V 2Y (ud) = 100; V 2Y (dd) = 82.64. Now consider year 1. In each state u or d the company must decide whether to switch assuming that it entered each state using either technology X or Y. That is, four separate calculations must be performed, as follows: 0.443V2X(uu) + 0.557V2X(ud) 0.443V2Y (uu) + 0.557V2Y (ud) V 1X(u) = Max{140 + ; (110 15) + } = 275.78; (70) 0.443V2Y (uu) + 0.557V2Y (ud) 0.443V2X(uu) + 0.557V2X(ud) V 1Y (u) = Max{110 + ; (140 10) + } = 265.78; (71) 0.443V2X(du) + 0.557V2X(dd) 0.443V2Y (du) + 0.557V2Y (dd) V 1X(d) = Max{71.42 + ; (90.91 15) + } = 161.94; (72) V 1Y (d) = Max{90.91 + = 176.94. 0.443V2Y (du) + 0.557V2Y (dd) ; (71.42 10) + The asterisk symbol denotes the decision to switch use. Now in year 0 one computes: 0.443V2X(du) + 0.557V2X(dd) } (73) V 0X = Max{100 + 0.443V1X(u) + 0.557V1X(d) ; (100 15) + 0.443V1Y (u) + 0.557V1Y (d) } = 302.26; (74) V 0Y = Max{100 + 0.443V1Y (u) + 0.557V1Y (d) ; (100 10) + 0.443V1X(u) + 0.557V1X(d) } = 306.00. (75) At time 0 the value of technology Z is 302.26 if its initial state is technology X or 306.00 if its initial state is technology Y. Obviously, if one has a choice, it would be preferable to begin in technology Y. The NP V for technology X is 19, the NP V for technology Y is 184.19, and the NP V for technology Z is either 192.26 or 196.00. In any case, technology X is preferred to technology Y, and technology Z is preferred to X regardless of its initial state. 46

REAL OPTIONS CASE STUDY ExpectedCashFlows Period 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Price 30 27.67 25.51 23.53 21.7 20.01 Quantity 200 230 264 303 349 401 UnitCost 9 8.6 8.1 7.7 7.4 7 Revenue 6000 6364 6735 7130 7573 8024 Cost 1800 1978 2138 2333 2583 2807 GrossIncome 4200 4386 4597 4797 4990 5217 Rent 200 200 200 200 200 200 SGA 600 637 676 718 763 810 EBITDA 3400 3549 3721 3879 4027 4207 Depr 3500 3500 3500 3500 3500 3500 EBIT -100 49 221 379 527 707 Taxes 0 20 88 152 211 283 NetIncome -100 29 133 227 316 424 Depr 3500 3500 3500 3500 3500 3500 Investment 35000 0 0 0 0 0 0 FreeCashFlow -35000 3400 3529 3633 3727 3816 3924 ContinueValue 51012 PresentValue 34707 36125 37611 39199 40914 42778 44793 NetPresentValue -293 39525 41140 42832 44641 46594 48717 FCFPercentage 0.086 0.0858 0.0848 0.0835 0.0819 0.0805 OPTIONS: Expand: Increases future cash flow by 30% at a cost of 10500 Abandon: Liquidate hardware investment for 15000 ASSUMPTIONS: Price and Quantity independent stochastic processes 95% lower confidence interval value for price is 15 95% lower confidence interval value for quantity is 190 Risk-free rate = 2.5% Free cash flow percentage is 8.5% each year CALCULATIONS: 51,012 = 3924(1.04)/(0.12 0.04) ln P ~ N(-0.081, 0.0643 2 ) [30e (-0.081*5) = 20. -2 = (ln P α /P 1-5ν P )/ 5 ν P.] ln Q ~ N(0.139, 0.1665 2 ) [200e (0.139*5) = 400. -2 = (ln Q α /Q 1-5ν Q )/ 5ν Q.] Simulated standard deviation of first period ln Return is 0.36 U = 1.433330, D = 0.697676 q = 0.445371 47