Help Session 2. David Sovich. Washington University in St. Louis

Similar documents
Help Session 4. David Sovich. Washington University in St. Louis

Help Session 7. David Sovich. Washington University in St. Louis

Risk-neutral Binomial Option Valuation

Derivative Instruments

Option Properties Liuren Wu

The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing

2 The binomial pricing model

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

An Introduction to the Mathematics of Finance. Basu, Goodman, Stampfli

Advanced Corporate Finance. 5. Options (a refresher)

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing

Lecture 16. Options and option pricing. Lecture 16 1 / 22

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

Hull, Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 9 th Edition

Forwards, Futures, Options and Swaps

The Multistep Binomial Model

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Corporate Finance, Module 21: Option Valuation. Practice Problems. (The attached PDF file has better formatting.) Updated: July 7, 2005

Lecture 6: Option Pricing Using a One-step Binomial Tree. Thursday, September 12, 13

Introduction to Financial Derivatives

MULTIPLE CHOICE QUESTIONS

Financial Derivatives Section 3

The Binomial Model for Stock Options

Name: MULTIPLE CHOICE. 1 (5) a b c d e. 2 (5) a b c d e TRUE/FALSE 1 (2) TRUE FALSE. 3 (5) a b c d e 2 (2) TRUE FALSE.

Introduction Random Walk One-Period Option Pricing Binomial Option Pricing Nice Math. Binomial Models. Christopher Ting.

B8.3 Week 2 summary 2018

non linear Payoffs Markus K. Brunnermeier

Lecture 10 An introduction to Pricing Forward Contracts.

Economic Risk and Decision Analysis for Oil and Gas Industry CE School of Engineering and Technology Asian Institute of Technology

Barrier options. In options only come into being if S t reaches B for some 0 t T, at which point they become an ordinary option.

Notes for Lecture 5 (February 28)

FINANCIAL OPTION ANALYSIS HANDOUTS

Forward Risk Adjusted Probability Measures and Fixed-income Derivatives

Optimization Models in Financial Mathematics

Review of Derivatives I. Matti Suominen, Aalto

ECO OPTIONS AND FUTURES SPRING Options

ECON4510 Finance Theory Lecture 10

Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing. 3.1 Arbitrage and risk neutral probability measures

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards

CHAPTER 17 OPTIONS AND CORPORATE FINANCE

Chapter 17. Options and Corporate Finance. Key Concepts and Skills

1. In this exercise, we can easily employ the equations (13.66) (13.70), (13.79) (13.80) and

Introduction to Financial Mathematics

Notes: This is a closed book and closed notes exam. The maximal score on this exam is 100 points. Time: 75 minutes

MATH 425 EXERCISES G. BERKOLAIKO

1 Asset Pricing: Replicating portfolios

American options and early exercise

Mathematics in Finance

Forwards, Futures, Futures Options, Swaps. c 2009 Prof. Yuh-Dauh Lyuu, National Taiwan University Page 367

EC3070 FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES FUTURES: MARKING TO MARKET

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES

Interest-Sensitive Financial Instruments

Lecture 16: Delta Hedging

DRAFT. 1 exercise in state (S, t), π(s, t) = 0 do not exercise in state (S, t) Review of the Risk Neutral Stock Dynamics

Notes: This is a closed book and closed notes exam. The maximal score on this exam is 100 points. Time: 75 minutes

Homework Assignments

( 0) ,...,S N ,S 2 ( 0)... S N S 2. N and a portfolio is created that way, the value of the portfolio at time 0 is: (0) N S N ( 1, ) +...

Notes: This is a closed book and closed notes exam. The maximal score on this exam is 100 points. Time: 75 minutes

In chapter 5, we approximated the Black-Scholes model

OPTION VALUATION Fall 2000

The Black-Scholes Equation

Risk Neutral Valuation

Computational Finance. Computational Finance p. 1

MATH 361: Financial Mathematics for Actuaries I

#10. Problems 1 through 10, part a). Fi8000 Practice Set #1 Check Solutions 1. Payoff. Payoff #8 Payoff S

Basics of Derivative Pricing

Forward Risk Adjusted Probability Measures and Fixed-income Derivatives

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

MS-E2114 Investment Science Exercise 10/2016, Solutions

MATH 476/567 ACTUARIAL RISK THEORY FALL 2016 PROFESSOR WANG

Forwards, Swaps, Futures and Options

Help Session 2. David Sovich. Washington University in St. Louis

Introduction. Financial Economics Slides

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

Valuation of Options: Theory

Option Pricing Models. c 2013 Prof. Yuh-Dauh Lyuu, National Taiwan University Page 205

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Properties of Stock Options

Lecture 1 Definitions from finance

RMSC 2001 Introduction to Risk Management

δ j 1 (S j S j 1 ) (2.3) j=1

Financial Derivatives Section 5

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

last problem outlines how the Black Scholes PDE (and its derivation) may be modified to account for the payment of stock dividends.

Pricing Options with Binomial Trees

Stochastic Models. Introduction to Derivatives. Walt Pohl. April 10, Department of Business Administration

P&L Attribution and Risk Management

Introduction to Binomial Trees. Chapter 12

B6302 Sample Placement Exam Academic Year

Economics 8106 Macroeconomic Theory Recitation 2

Stochastic Calculus for Finance

Name: T/F 2.13 M.C. Σ

Options Markets: Introduction

Option Pricing Models for European Options

Solving the Black-Scholes Equation

Transcription:

Help Session 2 David Sovich Washington University in St. Louis

TODAY S AGENDA 1. Refresh the concept of no arbitrage and how to bound option prices using just the principle of no arbitrage 2. Work on applying the Law of One Price in the binomial tree: replication and (if time permits) the FTAP * Forewarning: Builds on concepts covered in the Help Session last week

NO ARBITRAGE REFRESHER An arbitrage is either: (1) getting paid to never pay anything out or (2) paying nothing for potentially something - e.g free lunch Suppose there are two time periods t (today) and T > t and there are Ω = {ω 1,...,ω n } possible states of the world at time T A portfolio V is an arbitrage if either 1. V }{{} t < 0, and V T (ω) 0 for every ω Ω }{{} PRICE PAYOFF 2. V t = 0, and V T (ω) 0 for every ω Ω and V T (ω ) > 0 for at least one ω Ω

NO ARBITRAGE REFRESHER No arbitrage is the absence of arbitrage - and no arbitrage is required for prices to make sense This is the main concept in option pricing - all the key theorems follow from assumptions about NA Recall that Futures (linear contracts) can be priced using only NA, for options we can only bound prices via NA

NO ARBITRAGE PRACTICE Suppose there are two dates, t and T, and a stock with price S t. Denote the continuously compounded risk-free rate by r. Assume there are no dividends and all options have strike K Practice: Show that the European call (c t ) and put prices (p t ) must satisfy: ( max 0,S t Ke r(t t)) < c t < S t ) max (0,Ke r(t t) S t < p t < Ke r(t t)

NO ARBITRAGE COOKBOOK To show (for example) that c t < S t, recall the cookbook procedure that we learned: 1. Suppose NA holds. But, to the contrary, that c t S t 2. Construct a candidate arbitrage strategy. Remember the trick of buy low and sell high - e.g. long the stock short the call here 3. Show that the candidate arbitrage is indeed an arbitrage using the definition from two slides ago 4. Finally, since we assume NA and we found an arbitrage, we have arrived at a logical contradiction and hence the claim must be true

NO ARBITRAGE PRACTICE Practice: Assume our previous set-up. Show that if NA holds, then the put-call parity holds for strike K c t + Ke r(t t) = p t + S t Solution: Notice that the time T payoffs of the put-call parity are always equal: c T + K = max(s T K,0) + K = max(s T,K) = S T + max(0,k S T ) = S T + p T Hence, if the equality does not hold then we can long one side and short the other and construct an arbitrage

BOUNDING THE CALL PRICE WITH DIVIDENDS Two slides ago we showed that c t S t for a non-dividend paying stock What if the stock pays a known dividend D at time τ (t,t)? We will show that the no-arbitrage bound is now lower: c t S t De r(τ t) Why? Think about the advantages of owning the stock versus the call In general, c t S t PV(DIVS) for any dividends paid before T

BOUNDING THE CALL PRICE WITH DIVIDENDS Claim: c t S t De r(τ t) Proof: Suppose otherwise that c t > S t De r(τ t) Consider the following strategy: Long the stock, short the call, borrow De r(τ t) at rate r for τ t length, and repay the loan with any dividends The time t cash flow is CF t = c t (S t De r(τ t) ) > 0 The time τ cash flow is CF τ = D De r(τ t) e r(τ t) = 0 And the time T cash flow is CF T = S T (S T K) + 0 for any S T

NO ARBITRAGE WITH DIVIDENDS Note that this was our first example where a security had intermediate payments (e.g. the dividend) Constructing arbitrage strategies is not different though Suppose there are multiple time periods {t,τ 1,..,τ N } and there are Ω(τ) = {ω 1,...,ω n(τ) } possible states at each τ > t A portfolio V is an arbitrage if either (1) V }{{} t < 0 and V τ (ω) 0 for every τ and ω Ω(τ) }{{} PRICE PAYOFF (2) V t = 0 and V τ (ω) 0 for every τ and every ω Ω(τ) and V τ (ω ) > 0 for at least one τ and ω Ω(τ )

OPTIONS PRICING AND THE LOP Getting the exact price of call and put options requires more assumptions about the economy than just NA However, pricing is still done with just NA and the Law of One Price The Law of One Price states that portfolios with the same payoffs must have the same price If the Law of One Price fails (in complete markets), then we can construct an arbitrage

OPTIONS PRICING VIA REPLICATION One way to price options is to assume an economic model and price options via replication That is, suppose we want to price an option with a random payoff of Y t Suppose there are several assets 1,...,N with payoffs,x(2),...,x(n) and known prices X (1) T T T Then we can price the option Y t by: 1. Replicating the payoffs Y T in each state using a portfolio of traded (X (i) ) securities with known prices 2. Apply the Law of One Price - the price of security Y must equal the price of the portfolio of replicating securities

BINOMIAL TREE EXAMPLE Suppose that there are two-time periods t = 0 and T = 1 and two possible states, u and d, at time T Suppose there exists a stock with S 0 = 1 and S T (u) = 2 and S T (d) = 0 Suppose there also exists a bond with B 0 = 1 and r = 0 Problem: What is (a) the price of a call on S with K = 1, and (b) the price of a put on S with K = 1?

BINOMIAL TREE EXAMPLE Solution: Consider first the case of the put option. To price the put, we first need to calculate the payoffs. We have that p T (u) = (1 2) + = 0, and p T (d) = (1 0) + = 1 Now let us find a portfolio of α shares of the stock and β shares of the bond to replicate the payoff of p T in both states This is equivalent to solving the system of two linear equations: αs T (u) + βb T (u) = p T (u) αs T (d) + βb T (d) = p T (d)

BINOMIAL TREE EXAMPLE Plugging in the values for the stock and bond payoffs, we have: 2α + 1β = 0 0α + β = 1 Which implies that β = 1 units of the bond and α = 0.5 shares of the stock replicate the payoff of the put option By the Law of One Price, the price of the replicating portfolio must equal the price of the put option: αs 0 + βb 0 = p 0 And hence, p 0 = 1 2 1 + 1 1 = 1 2

BINOMIAL TREE EXAMPLE Now let us solve for the call option price. First, we calculate the payoffs We have that c T (u) = (2 1) + = 1, and c T (d) = (0 1) + = 0 Now let us find a portfolio of α shares of the stock and β shares of the bond to replicate the payoff of p T in both states This is equivalent to solving the system of two linear equations: 2α + 1β = 1 0α + 1β = 0

BINOMIAL TREE EXAMPLE Thus, a portfolio of long α = 1 2 shares and no position in the bond replicates the call option payoff By the Law of One Price, the time t = 0 price of the option must equal the time t = 0 price of the replicating portfolio And hence we have that c 0 = 1 2 1 + 1 0 = 1 2

REPLICATION COOKBOOK Pricing options via replication always follows the same steps 1. Calculate the payoffs of the option. If this is already done for you, then do nothing. 2. Replicate the payoffs of the option using a portfolio of stocks and bonds. Solve the system of equations. 3. State (in words and numbers) what the replicating portfolio is comprised of 4. Apply the Law of One Price, the time t price of option must be equal to the time t price of the replicating portfolio

OPTION PRICING WITH THE FTAP Another way to price options is via the Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing (FTAP) The FTAP states that if there is no arbitrage, then the price of any asset is equal to its expected discounted value under the risk neutral probability measure In a two state two period world with risk-free rate r, this is equivalent to saying that the t price of any asset X equals X t = e r(t t) [q u X T (u) + q d X T (d)] where q u + q d = 1 are the risk-neutral probabilities and X T are payoffs (or (1 + r) T for discrete compounding)

FTAP PRICING EXAMPLE Practice: Using our previous example, compute the call price using the FTAP Solution: Recall that r = 0 in the previous example. The call price is given by the FTAP equation c t = (1 + r) T [q u c T (u) + (1 q u )c T (d)] We know that c u = 1 and c d = 0. But what is q u?

FTAP PRICING EXAMPLE One way is to compute q u using the formula in Jason s notes Another way is to notice that since the FTAP must hold for any security, it must hold in particular for the stock 1 = S t = (1 + r) 1 (q u S u + (1 q u )S d ) = 1 (2q u + 0(1 q u )) = q u = 1 2 Plugging this in yields c 0 = 1 [ 1 2 1 + 1 2 0] = 1 2

FTAP PRICING EXAMPLE Now that we have q u pricing any asset is easy! For example, the put price is [ 1 p t = 1 2 p T(u) + (1 1 ] 2 )p T(d) = 1 2 And a call with strike K = 1 2 has a price of [ 1 c t = 1 2 (2 0.5)+ + 1 ] (0 0.5)+ = 0.75 2 And a put with strike K = 3 has a price of [ 1 p t = 1 2 (3 2)+ + 1 ] (3 0)+ = 2 2

FTAP PRICING COOKBOOK Pricing options via the FTAP always follows the same steps 1. Calculate the payoffs of the option. If this is already done for you, then do nothing. 2. Calculate the risk-neutral probabilities. Either use the formula in the notes, or use the stock price and payoffs to extract q u 3. Write the FTAP equation for the option out explicitly 4. Plug in q u, the option prices, and the risk-free rate and compute the option price