The Gertler-Gilchrist Evidence on Small and Large Firm Sales

Similar documents
V.V. Chari, Larry Christiano, Patrick Kehoe. The Behavior of Small and Large Firms over the Business Cycle

Characteristics of the euro area business cycle in the 1990s

Comments on Foreign Effects of Higher U.S. Interest Rates. James D. Hamilton. University of California at San Diego.

Global Business Cycles

Mitchell s Musings : Consistency May Be a Hobgoblin We Need to Mind. Daniel J.B. Mitchell

Structural changes in the Maltese economy

Potential Output in Denmark

Two New Indexes Offer a Broad View of Economic Activity in the New York New Jersey Region

Solutions to PSet 5. October 6, More on the AS/AD Model

Is there a decoupling between soft and hard data? The relationship between GDP growth and the ESI

Structural Changes in the Maltese Economy

LECTURE 11 Monetary Policy at the Zero Lower Bound: Quantitative Easing. November 2, 2016

An Analysis of Public and Private Sector Earnings in Ireland

THE FED AND THE NEW ECONOMY

1 8 S e p t e m b e r V o l u m e 8 3 1

Spanish deposit-taking institutions net interest income and low interest rates

Notes 6: Examples in Action - The 1990 Recession, the 1974 Recession and the Expansion of the Late 1990s

Productivity, monetary policy and financial indicators

II. Determinants of Asset Demand. Figure 1

Part VII. How Successful Has Inflation Targeting Been?

SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET

Analysing the IS-MP-PC Model

THE U.S. ECONOMY IN 1986

Introduction. Learning Objectives. Chapter 17. Stabilization in an Integrated World Economy

Group Assignment I. database, available from the library s website) or national statistics offices. (Extra points if you do.)

Working Paper Series. Revisiting Gertler-Gilchrist Evidence on the Behavior of Small and Large Firms. Marianna Kudlyak and Juan M.

Financial Frictions in Macroeconomics. Lawrence J. Christiano Northwestern University

COMMENTARY NUMBER 776 November Durable Goods Orders, New-Home Sales December 23, 2015

International Money and Banking: 15. The Phillips Curve: Evidence and Implications

MA Advanced Macroeconomics 3. Examples of VAR Studies

The End of the Business Cycle?

The Big Four Economic Indicators: Industrial Production Down 0.1% in January

Whither the US equity markets?

LECTURE 8 Monetary Policy at the Zero Lower Bound: Quantitative Easing. October 10, 2018

3 The leverage cycle in Luxembourg s banking sector 1

One Policymaker s Wait for Better Economic Data

Journal of Insurance and Financial Management, Vol. 1, Issue 4 (2016)

Investment Company Institute PERSPECTIVE

EXECUTIVE OFFICE OF THE PRESIDENT COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS WASHINGTON, DC 20502

Economic Watch Deleveraging after the burst of a credit-bubble Alfonso Ugarte / Akshaya Sharma / Rodolfo Méndez

The Impact of Model Periodicity on Inflation Persistence in Sticky Price and Sticky Information Models

PERFORMANCE STUDY 2013

Estimating the Impact of Changes in the Federal Funds Target Rate on Market Interest Rates from the 1980s to the Present Day

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. Unemployment after the Recession: A New Natural Rate? Murat Tasci and Saeed Zaman

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Working Paper No Accounting for the unemployment decrease in Australia. William Mitchell 1. April 2005

Saving, wealth and consumption

The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve

Leverage Restrictions in a Business Cycle Model. Lawrence J. Christiano Daisuke Ikeda

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. An Unstable Okun s Law, Not the Best Rule of Thumb. Brent Meyer and Murat Tasci

Travel Hysteresis in the Brazilian Current Account

MONETARY POLICY COMING OUT OF RECESSION. Anna J. Schwartz National Bureau of Economic Research

Risk Tolerance and Risk Exposure: Evidence from Panel Study. of Income Dynamics

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts

Monetary Policy and a Stock Market Boom-Bust Cycle

OVERVIEW OF DEVELOPMENTS IN ICT INVESTMENT IN CANADA, 2011

Practice Test 1: Multiple Choice

Determination of manufacturing exports in the euro area countries using a supply-demand model

Gauging Current Conditions:

COMMENTARY NUMBER 462 June Trade Balance, Consumer Credit. August 9, Bernanke Bemoans GDP Not Reflecting Common Experience

Appendix to: The Myth of Financial Innovation and the Great Moderation

GOVERNMENT DEFICITS, MONETARY POLICY, AND INFLATION Remarks by Darryl R. Francis, President. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Mr Thiessen converses on the conduct of monetary policy in Canada under a floating exchange rate system

International Journal of Business and Economic Development Vol. 4 Number 1 March 2016

Assessing the Risk of Yield Curve Inversion: An Update

Potential Output in Ireland Presentation at TCD-DEW Conference

Supplemental Technical Critique of Reinhart and Rogoff, Growth in a Time of Debt

The Big Four Economic Indicators: Industrial Production Up 0.3% in September

INFLATION AND THE ECONOMIC OUTLOOK By Darryl R. Francis, President. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Figure 3.6 Swing High

William C Dudley: Financial conditions indexes a new look after the financial crisis

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

The Golub Capital Altman Index

A Closer Look at U.S. Economic Weakness

The Big Four Economic Indicators: Industrial Production Up 0.3% in December, New High

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. Not Your Father s Recovery? Kenneth R. Beauchemin. Figure 1. The Severity of the Recession and the Strength of the Recovery

Estimates of the Productivity Trend Using Time-Varying Parameter Techniques

Leverage Restrictions in a Business Cycle Model

A Reply to Roberto Perotti s "Expectations and Fiscal Policy: An Empirical Investigation"

Simple monetary policy rules

For Online Publication. The macroeconomic effects of monetary policy: A new measure for the United Kingdom: Online Appendix

(1) UIP : R = R f + Ee E

Financial Stability: The Role of Real Estate Values

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Easy and Successful Macroeconomic Timing

FRBSF Economic Letter

Part III. Cycles and Growth:

Axioma s new Multi-Asset Class (MAC) Risk Monitor highlights recent trends in market and portfolio

VIEW FROM A. VIEW FROM A MILE HIGH: Tapering the Era of Cap Rate Compression. NOVEMBER 2013 July 2013

Lectures 13 and 14: Fixed Exchange Rates

COMMENTS ON SESSION 1 AUTOMATIC STABILISERS AND DISCRETIONARY FISCAL POLICY. Adi Brender *

The Time Cost of Documents to Trade

Nasdaq Chaikin Power US Small Cap Index

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

Business Cycles II: Theories

Some Thoughts on Inflation, Tax Reform and the Fed

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility

Monetary Policy and Reaching for Income by Daniel, Garlappi and Xiao. Discussant: Annette Vissing-Jorgensen, UC Berkeley.

Comment on Christina and David Romer s Do Tax Cuts Starve the Beast? By Steven J. Davis 2 July 2009

Has the Inflation Process Changed?

Transcription:

The Gertler-Gilchrist Evidence on Small and Large Firm Sales VV Chari, LJ Christiano and P Kehoe January 2, 27 In this note, we examine the findings of Gertler and Gilchrist, ( Monetary Policy, Business Cycles, and the Behavior of Small Manufacturing Firms, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 19, no. 2, May 1994, pp. 39-34.) GG construct a measure of the sales of large and small establishments and argue that small establishment sales fall by more than large establishment sales in response to a contractionary monetary policy shock. This is interpreted as providing support for the notion that a monetary contraction affects the economy in part by making credit relatively tight for small firms. In this note, we investigate a closely related question. We ask what happens to the sales of large versus small firms during a business cycle contraction. Thequestionisadifferent one, to the extent that shocks other than monetary policy also play an important role in triggering recessions. This makes whatever answer we find harder to interpret. At the same time, business cycle recessions are easier to identify in the data than are monetary policy shocks, and so the question we ask allows us to sidestep difficult identification questions. Our analysis is broken into two parts. First, we confine ourselves to the data

set constructed by Gertler and Gilchrist, which cover the period, 199Q1-1991Q4. After reproducing their findings for the response of large and small firm sales to Romer-Romer monetary contractions, we find that small firm sales also drop relative to large firm sales during recessions. At the same time, there is substantial variation in sales across different business cycle episodes. The differences between small and large firms are less significant than they are after Romer-Romer episodes. We suspect that a formal test of the null hypothesis that large and small firm sales respond to recessions in the same way would not be rejected. In the second part, we construct a longer time series on large and small firm sales. This allows us to consider three additional recessions, two in the 19s as well as the 2 recession. We find that the additional business cycle episodes in our data sample overturn the results reported in the first part of our analysis. In particular, the response of large and small firm sales in a recession is roughly the same. 1. Some Key Dates The analysis of the Gertler-Gilchrist places special emphasis on several particular dates. We discuss these here. The first figure below reports log US real GDP, after HP filtering. The observations market * come in couples, with the first one indicating an NBER business cycle peak and the second a trough. Note how these peaks typically occur several quarters after an actual turning point in the data. This motivated us to construct an alternative set of business cycle peaks. These are indicated by the circles, and we refer to these as CCK business cycle dates. They are are local peaks in detrended output, after which output fell by at least several percent. The dates are 193Q2, 19Q3, 196Q1, 1966Q1, 1969Q1, 1973Q2, 1978Q4, 1981Q1, 199Q1, 2Q2. There were two dates, 19Q3 and 1981Q1, that 2

we were unsure of. In the first of these episodes, the economy fell by less than 2 percent in the subsequent year, and then exhibited a brief period of strength in 196Q4, before then plunging by several percent. We could have perhaps picked 196Q4 as the business cycle peak instead. The second date, 1981Q1, satisfies our criterion that the economy fell by more than a couple of percent afterward. However, the expansion before 1981Q1 is very brief, and we thought of defining the 1981Q1 recession as part of a recession that actually began in 1978Q4. In effect, we follow the NBER in this episode in taking the position that there were two recessions at the end of the 197s and the start of the 198s. The boxes indicate Romer and Romer dates. These occur in 1966, Quarter 2, December 1968, April 1974, August 1978, October 1979, and August 1988. The 1974 and 1979 dates occur well after the economy has started to weaken and may perhaps therefore not be considered the primary cause for the business contractions in those 3

two periods. 1 times log deviation from HP trend Figure 1 HP filtered real GDP and RR (square), NBER Business Cycle Dates (*), and CCK Business Cycle Peaks (o) 3 2 1 1 2 3 4 19 196 196 197 197 198 198 199 199 2 percent Federal Funds Rate (APR) 16 14 12 1 8 6 4 2 19 196 196 197 197 198 198 199 199 2 The second graph shows the federal funds rate. Note that the Romer and Romer dates occur while interest rates are rising. Two dates - April 1974 and October 1979 - look somewhat suspicious, as dates when the Fed resolved to initiate a battle against inflation. Each of these two dates occur late during a sharp rise in the interest rate. One might expect that a Fed decision to sharply raise the interest rate would occur 4

near the beginning of an upswing in the interest rate, not near the end. 2. Reproducing the Gertler-Gilchrist Results We obtained the actual sales data, for large and small firms, that Gertler and Gilchrist used in their Figure II, page 321. These data are displayed in Figure 2 below. The actual data were provided by the authors in growth rates. The top panel displays the corresponding levels, obtained by cumulating the first differences and setting the initial condition to zero. Note how large firm sales displays strong growth until the early 198s, whereupon it stabilizes. Small firm sales exhibit little growth throughout the period. The bottom panel displays the level data, after linear detrending. The squares in the figure indicate the Romer and Romer dates and the circles indicate

the CCK business cycle peaks. Figure 2 Cumulative sum of Gertler Gilchrist Log differenced Data, slope of trend in (i) large firms =.86822, (ii) small firms =. 1.2 1.8.6 small trend small large trend, large.4.2 196 196 197 197 198 198 199 Cumulative Data, Linearly Detrended (CCK dates circle; RR dates box).2.1 small large.1.2 196 196 197 197 198 198 199 Consider the Romer-Romer dates (i.e., the squares) first. After the one in 1966 it is clear that small firm sales drop by more than large firm sales. The same is true for the 1968 date, although initially there is a transient rise in small firm sales. After 1974 small firm sales fall more than large firm sales, but the difference looks relatively small. After the 1978 date there is actually a surge in small firm sales. 6

But, the surge in large firm sales is a bit stronger and the small firms slow down and falter before the large firms do. After 1979, the small firms seem to go down faster and more than the large firms. However, one could perhaps debate this by pointing tothefactthatlargefirms ultimately fall much further. Also, the part of the 1978 date that is consistent with GG is actually the same at the 1979 date. So, counting 1978 and 1979 separately seems like double counting. In the wake of the 1988 date, it is not clear which goes down more. We produced a worm chart like Gertler-Gilchrist s Figure II, which displays the detrended data 8 quarters before and 12 quarters after a Romer-Romer date. All data are adjusted by a constant so that in period, the Romer-Romer date, the data are always normalized at zero. The starred line in the figure is the average of the individual curves. Note that the average cumulative drop in the level of sales by small firms after a contraction is about percentage points greater than what it is 7

for large firms. Figure 3 Analysis In Neighborhood of Romer and Romer Dates GG data small firms (Linearly Detrended) 1 * log 1 1 2 2 8 6 4 2 2 4 6 8 1 12 large firms (Linearly Detrended) 1 * log 1 1 2 8 6 4 2 2 4 6 8 1 12 We investigated the robustness of the above finding to the detrending strategy. This is motivated by the evidence in Figure 2 that the trend in the levels of large and small firms is not well captured by a simple linear trend. Repeating the calculations in Figure 2, using the HP filter to detrend the cumulated levels, we obtain the 8

following results: Figure 4 Cumulative sum of Gertler Gilchrist Log differenced Data, slope of trend in (i) large firms =.86822, (ii) small firms =. 1.8.6 small trend small large trend, large.4.2 196 196 197 197 198 198 199.1. Cumulative Data, HP filtered (CCK dates circle; RR dates box) small large..1 196 196 197 197 198 198 199 The behavior of detrended large firm sales is somewhat sensitive to the detrending procedure, because of the apparent break in the trend of that series around 198. As before, small firm sales drop a lot after the 1966 date. There seems to be a bigger surge in small firm sales after the 1968 date, though overall perhaps it can be said that after that date small firm sales drop by a lot more than large firm sales. 9

After the 1974 date, the fall in the two sales figures seem to be of similar magnitude. The 1978 data is much less consistent with the GG hypothesis with the change in detrending, because the surge in sales by small firms thereafter is so great. In the immediate aftermath of the 1979 date, large and small firms seem to react in a similar way. This too, seems not consistent with the GG hypothesis. The fact that after 198 large firm sales are more volatile than small firms sales also seems inconsistent with the spirit of the GG hypothesis. In the period after the 1988 Romer-Romer date, the overall movements in large and small firm sales are similar, except that the former are still more volatile than the latter. Overall, the results seem to favor the GG hypothesis less strongly with the change in detrending procedure. Somewhat inconsistently with our informal analysis of Figure 4, when we compute the worm chart using the data in Figure 4, we obtained once again results that favor the GG conclusion (see Figure ). The average cumulative drop in sales by small firmsisabout7percentbythethird yearafteraromer-romerdate,and the corresponding result of large firms is percent. However, the spread between the mean cumulative drop in sales is larger in the quarters before. In addition, we see that across all Romer-Romer episodes small firms are always below zero after 8 quarters out, whereas large firms sales are more often in the positive region. Overall, the impression from the following figure is that the cumulative drop in small firm 1

salesislargerthanitisforlargefirm sales, in the wake of a Romer-Romer date. Figure Analysis In Neighborhood of Romer and Romer Dates GG data small firms (HP filered) 1 * log 1 1 8 6 4 2 2 4 6 8 1 12 large firms (HP filered) 1 * log 1 1 8 6 4 2 2 4 6 8 1 12 We repeated the worm chart calculations for CCK business cycle peaks and ob- 11

tained the following results: Figure 6 Analysis In Neighborhood of CCK Business Cycle Peaks, GG data 1 small firms (Linearly Detrended) 1 * log 1 2 196Q1 199Q1 mean, across episodes 8 6 4 2 2 4 6 8 1 12 large firms (Linearly Detrended) 1 * log 1 1 1 2 196Q1 199Q1 mean, across episodes 8 6 4 2 2 4 6 8 1 12 Note that the starred line does not extend to the end or to the beginning of the responses. This is because the first and last business cycle peaks are too near the ends of the data set. It seems fair to conclude that these results are somewhat weaker than the Gertler-Gilchrist results, because there is a greater spread among 12

the responses across episodes. Still, the averages that are reported indicate that small firm sales fall more than do large firm sales, after a CCK business cycle peak. In particular, in quarters 6 and 7, small firm sales are down by -4., -., and -7.7 percent, respectively. At the same time, large firm sales are down by -2.33, -3.43, and -.76 percent, respectively. Thus, the point estimates are consistent with the basic Gertler-Gilchrist results, though the differences seem less likely to be statistically significant, because of the high degree of variation across episodes. 3. Bringing More Business Cycle Episodes into the Analysis We expanded the Gertler-Gilchrist data set so that we can include more business cycle episodes in the analysis. We extended the data back to 192Q1 and up to 2Q3 by recovering data from various QFRs. We constructed the data using the simplest version of the procedure applied in Gertler-Gilchrist. The data are total dollar sales by manufacturing establishments in each of several size categories. A firm is in a given size category in a particular quarter if its assets are inside a specific range of values during that quarter. There are 7-9 size categories, with changes in the categories occuring four times in our data set. These changes reflectthatthesize categories are definedinnominalterms,sothatfirms are drifting up through the size categories over time. The changes primarily involve consolidating the smallest size categories and expanding the largest. Following Gertler-Gilchrist, we define the sales of small firmsasaweightedav- erage of cumulative sales growth in the two asset size categories which straddle the 3th percentile of sales during period t. The weights are chosen so that the weighted average of cumulative sales in the two asset size classes average 3 percent of sales in period t. Specifically, we proceed as follows. Let S i,t denote total sales of firms 13

in size category i, in period t, after deflating by the GDP deflator. Let S it denote the sum of sales (scaled by all sales in period t) for asset size categories less than or equal to i, in period t : P i j=1 S it = S jt P Nt j=1 S, jt where N t denotesallthesizecategoriesinperiodt and i =1,..., N t. We then compute i t = min Sit >.3 ª, (3.1) i {1,N t } as well as the weight, ω t, such that ω t Sit 1,t +(1 ω t ) S it,t =.3. Finally, small firm sales growth, s S t, is defined as P it 1 s S j=1 t = ω S P it j,t j=1 t P it 1 j=1 S +(1 ω t ) S j,t P it j,t 1 j=1 S. j,t 1 Large firm sales growth, s L t, is the complement of small firm sales growth. Specifically, P Nt P s L j=i t = ω t S Nt j,t j=i t P Nt +(1 ω t ) S t+1 j,t P j=i t S Nt j,t 1 j=i t +1 S. j,t 1 Note that the GDP deflator has no impact on the computation of the weights, ω t, only on sales themselves. Also, note that the size categories over which sales growth is computed are the same for periods t and t 1. Splicing was done when the size categories in t 1 are different than they are in t. An alternative strategy for computing ω t in (3.1) would have used total assets instead of total sales to construct S it. In this case, firm size would have been based purely on assets. To gain insight into these calculations, consider Figure 7a, which displays S it for i =1,..., N t for each t within our data sets. The differentgraphsmustbecompared 14

with caution, since the asset size categories differ across datasets. However, note how the distribution of production shifts increasingly towards large firms. Indeed, inthelastdateofourlastdataset,wefind i t = N t, the top asset size category. In this case, for the purpose of constructing s L t we set ω t =1. Figure 7a 1.8.6.4.2 Cumulative Distribution of Sales Across Asset size Categories 192Q1 196Q3 198Q1 1976Q2 1.8.6.4.2 2 4 6 8 2 4 6 8 1 1 1976Q3 1987Q3 1 1987Q4 2Q3.8.8.6.6.4.4.2.2 2 4 6 8 2 4 6 8 Figure 7 below compares our computed sales growth data with Gertler and 1

Gilchrist s. The two series are reasonably similar. The ratio of the standard deviation of our measure of small firm sales growth, to the standard deviation of Gertler and Gilchrist s measure is 1.4. The corresponding statistic for large firm sales growth is.93. The correlation between the two measure of small sales growth is.81 and the correlation of the two measures of large firm sales growth is.86. (These statistics were computed over the sample that the two data series share.) Figure 7 Gertler Gilchrist small sales data (*), our constructed data ( ) 1 19 196 196 197 197 198 198 199 199 2 Gertler Gilchrist large sales data (*), our constructed data ( ) 1 19 196 196 197 197 198 198 199 199 2 16

There are a few isolated instances in which there is a sharp difference between the two estimates of sales growth. In each case, the differences reflect a sharp, suspicious, jump in our constructed series. In the case of small firm sales growth, there are two such instances. The small firm sales growth jump in 1981Q3 reflects that there are 2 and 3 percent jumps in nominal sales in the second and third-smallest size categories in 1981Q3 over 1981Q2 (these growth rates are expressed at quarterly rates!). The small firm sales growth drop in 1987Q1 reflects that there is a 24 percent drop in nominal sales of firms in the smallest size category (< million in assets) 1987Q1 over 1986Q4 (again, at a quarterly rate). We suppose that these changes reflect measurement error or data revision. Turning to the growth rate of large firm sales, note that there is one instance, 1974Q1, in which our constructed measure drops sharply. This reflects that there is a 21 percent drop in nominal sales by the largest size category of firms in 1974Q1. Sales then jump back up by 13 percent in 1974Q2, and so we suspect that this represents measurement error. When replaced these suspicious observations with linearly interpolated values, the spikes were attenuated, but not greatly. Apart from the differences just mentioned, there are smaller differences between our constructed series and Gertler-Gilchrist s. Note that in the decade of the 196s, our constructed small firm growth rate is on average below Gertler and Gilchrist s. We now look at the HP-filtered data. The top panel displays the cumulated level of our measure of the sales of large and small firms after HP-filtering. HP filtered, log GDP is also displayed. Note that the volatility of the two series is very similar. Small firms seem to exhibit more volatility in the 196s and 197s, but in the rest of the sample there are times when large firms are more volatile. The bottom panel shows the same results for the Gertler-Gilchrist data. Note that here there is somewhat more that small firms exhibit greater volatility. The relative volatility of small firm 17

sales is 2.8 versus 2.1 for large firms. In part, this reflects the different samples, however. When we recalculated the relative volatility of our measure of sales over the Gertler-Gilchrist time period, we obtained that small firms relative volatility is 2.3 and large firms volatility is 2.6. Figure 7b HP filtered, log levels large firm sales (cck) small firm sales (cck) real GDP...1 std(large firms)/std(gdp) = 2.2896 std(small firms)/std(gdp) = 2.489 19 196 196 197 197 198 198 199 199 2.1 HP filtered, log levels large firm sales (GG) small firm sales (GG) GDP...1 std(large firms)/std(gdp) = 2.1466 std(small firms)/std(gdp) = 2.7792 19 196 196 197 197 198 198 199 199 2 We did a direct comparison, based on HP filtered levels data, between the Gertler- 18

Gilchrist and our measures of sales. These are displayed in Figure 7c: Figure 7c Large Firm Sales. Gertler Gilchrist CCK..1 19 196 196 197 197 198 198 199 199 2 Small firm sales.1. Gertler Gilchrist CCK..1 19 196 196 197 197 198 198 199 199 2 Afewdifferences are notable. In the case of large firm sales in the early 197s our measureandthegertler-gilchrist smeasureareslightlyoutofphase. 19

Figure 8 displays the cumulative levels of the data: Figure 8 Cumulative sum of CCK Log differenced Data, slope of trend in (i) large firms =.1343, (ii) small firms =.43937.. small trend small large trend, large.1.1.2 19 196 196 197 197 198 198 199 199 2 Cumulative Data, Linearly Detrended (CCK dates circle; RR dates box).1.1 small large...1 19 196 196 197 197 198 198 199 199 2 In contrast to what we found with Gertler and Gilchrist s data, there is virtually no trend in either of our level series. This represents a particularly sharp change for the sales of large establishments, since in Gertler and Gilchrist s data these display strong growth. That our level sales data don t display a trend is not surprising, in view of our relatively low estimate of the growth rate of sales in large establishments 2

(see Figure 7). Figure 9 displays the worm chart for Romer and Romer episodes, i.e., the object most comparable to Gertler and Gilchrist s analysis: Figure 9 Analysis In Neighborhood of Romer and Romer Dates small firms (Linearly Detrended) 1 * log 1 1 2 8 6 4 2 2 4 6 8 1 12 1 large firms (Linearly Detrended) 1 * log 1 1 8 6 4 2 2 4 6 8 1 12 Note that the results are essentially unchanged relative to GG s analysis (see Figure ). There is a clear tendency for small firms sales to decline by more than large firm 21

sales. This finding suggests that the differences between our constructed data and Gertler and Gilchrist s are not large from the point of view of the questions that interest us. Figure 1 considers the CCK business cycle dates with linear detrending: Analysis In Neighborhood Figureof 1 CCK Business Cycle Peaks small firms (Linearly Detrended) 1 * log 1 1 2 193Q2 2Q2 mean, across episodes 8 6 4 2 2 4 6 8 1 12 large firms (Linearly Detrended) 1 * log 1 193Q2 2Q2 mean, across episodes 1 2 8 6 4 2 2 4 6 8 1 12 These results are considerably less supportive of the Gertler-Gilchrist hypothesis that the sales growth of small establishments falls more than the sales growth of 22

large establishments in a recession (with HP filtering, the results are not noticeably different). Note that the distribution of responses for large establishments is shifted down relative to that of small establishments. Because the first and last CCK business cycle peaks are too close to the boundaries of the dataset, the mean responses could not be performed over the whole range (i.e., the starred line does not extend all the way to the beginning and end). However, over the few responses that we could compute, large and small firm sales differ by very little. When we drop the first (193Q2) and last peaks (2Q2) from the analysis then mean responses can 23

be computed over the whole range of responses, and are displayed in Figure 11: Figure 11 Analysis In Neighborhood of CCK Business Cycle Peaks small firms (Linearly Detrended) 1 * log 1 1 2 19Q3 196Q1 199Q1 8 6 4 2 2 4 6 8 1 12 large firms (Linearly Detrended) 1 * log 1 19Q3 196Q1 199Q1 1 2 8 6 4 2 2 4 6 8 1 12 Two things are worth noting in Figure 11. First, as in Figure 1, the responses display more variation across episodes than the ones reported by Gertler and Gilchrist (see Figure ). Second, the mean drop in the sales growth of large establishments is greater than the mean response of small establishments (see the starred lines). 24

These results may at first seem puzzling. When we computed worm charts for CCK business cycle peaks using the Gerlter and Gilchrist data, we obtained their basic result that the growth of sales in large establishments falls less during a recession than the growth of sales in small establishments (see Figure 6). What accounts for the difference between the results in Figures 6 and 11? In principle, it could be something about the construction of the sales data, or about the business cycle episodes studied. We argue that the latter is the right answer. The three business cycle episodes included in Figure 11 which are not fully used in Figure 6 are the ones associated with peaks in 19Q3, 196Q1, and 199Q1. These episodes are indicated in Figure 11. Consistent with what we saw in Figure 8, all these episodes are ones in which small firms sales do not drop more than large firm sales. Indeed, in the first of these episodes, small firm sales actually surge as the economy enters the recession. Consistent with the view that these episodes have animportantimpactontheanalysis,we recoverthe Gertler-Gilchrist findings when 2

we drop them: Figure 12 Analysis In Neighborhood of CCK Business Cycle Peaks small firms (Linearly Detrended) 1 * log 1 1 2 8 6 4 2 2 4 6 8 1 12 large firms (Linearly Detrended) 1 * log 1 1 2 8 6 4 2 2 4 6 8 1 12 With the 19Q3, 196Q1, 199Q1 episodes excluded from the analysis, the crossbusiness-cycle-episode mean of small firm sales falls by as much as 1 percent by 7 quarters after the business cycle peak while the mean of large firm sales falls by at most around 6 percent. Generally, the impression from Figure 12 is that small 26

establishment sales falls by more than large establishment sales. Figures 11 and 12 indicate that when all business cycles are introduced in the analysis, there is not a significant difference in the behavior of large and small firm sales in recessions. Figure 13 shows what happens after NBER business cycle peaks: Figure 13 Analysis In Neighborhood of NBER Business Cycle Peaks 1 small firms (Linearly Detrended) 1 * log 1 1 8 6 4 2 2 4 6 8 1 12 large firms (Linearly Detrended) 1 * log 1 1 2 8 6 4 2 2 4 6 8 1 12 These results are also consistent with the proposition that there is no particular 27

difference in the response of the sales of small establishments in recessions. 28