Finance: Lecture 4 - No Arbitrage Pricing Chapters of DD Chapter 1 of Ross (2005)

Similar documents
( 0) ,...,S N ,S 2 ( 0)... S N S 2. N and a portfolio is created that way, the value of the portfolio at time 0 is: (0) N S N ( 1, ) +...

No-arbitrage Pricing Approach and Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing

One-Period Valuation Theory

Lecture 8: Introduction to asset pricing

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

Lecture 8: Asset pricing

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Mathematics of Finance Final Preparation December 19. To be thoroughly prepared for the final exam, you should

Lecture 16: Delta Hedging

Fin 501: Asset Pricing Fin 501:

General Equilibrium under Uncertainty

Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing. 3.1 Arbitrage and risk neutral probability measures

COMP331/557. Chapter 6: Optimisation in Finance: Cash-Flow. (Cornuejols & Tütüncü, Chapter 3)

Follow links for Class Use and other Permissions. For more information send to:

Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1)

Economia Financiera Avanzada

European Contingent Claims

Course Handouts - Introduction ECON 8704 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS. Jan Werner. University of Minnesota

Basics of Asset Pricing. Ali Nejadmalayeri

Finance: A Quantitative Introduction Chapter 7 - part 2 Option Pricing Foundations

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

Financial Market Models. Lecture 1. One-period model of financial markets & hedging problems. Imperial College Business School

Department of Mathematics. Mathematics of Financial Derivatives

Optimizing S-shaped utility and risk management

No-Arbitrage Conditions for a Finite Options System

ECE 586BH: Problem Set 5: Problems and Solutions Multistage games, including repeated games, with observed moves

Predicting the Market

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging

Introduction to Financial Mathematics and Engineering. A guide, based on lecture notes by Professor Chjan Lim. Julienne LaChance

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8

Optimal Investment with Deferred Capital Gains Taxes

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

Mathematics in Finance

3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time.

- Introduction to Mathematical Finance -

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 3

Uncertainty in Equilibrium

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

Chapter 10: Mixed strategies Nash equilibria, reaction curves and the equality of payoffs theorem

Hedging under Arbitrage

Introduction to Industrial Organization Professor: Caixia Shen Fall 2014 Lecture Note 5 Games and Strategy (Ch. 4)

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

A Robust Option Pricing Problem

Compulsory Assignment

Geometric tools for the valuation of performance-dependent options

BUSM 411: Derivatives and Fixed Income

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES

Hedging and Pricing in the Binomial Model

3. The Discount Factor

Robust Pricing and Hedging of Options on Variance

The text book to this class is available at

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 3: Strategic Form Games - Solution Concepts

The Multistep Binomial Model

Non replication of options

Real Options and Game Theory in Incomplete Markets

Stochastic Programming and Financial Analysis IE447. Midterm Review. Dr. Ted Ralphs

Notation: ti y,x R n. y x y i x i for each i=1,,n. y>x y x and y x. y >> x y i > x i for each i=1,,n. y x = i yx

Lecture 16. Options and option pricing. Lecture 16 1 / 22

1.12 Exercises EXERCISES Use integration by parts to compute. ln(x) dx. 2. Compute 1 x ln(x) dx. Hint: Use the substitution u = ln(x).

Practice of Finance: Advanced Corporate Risk Management

MATH4210 Financial Mathematics ( ) Tutorial 6

CHAPTER 2 Concepts of Financial Economics and Asset Price Dynamics

Help Session 4. David Sovich. Washington University in St. Louis

e62 Introduction to Optimization Fall 2016 Professor Benjamin Van Roy Homework 1 Solutions

Empty Promises and Arbitrage

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Arbitrage and Pricing Theory

To have a concrete example in mind, suppose that we want to price a European call option on a stock that matures in six months.

Super-replicating portfolios

Financial Economics: Risk Sharing and Asset Pricing in General Equilibrium c

Carnegie Mellon University Graduate School of Industrial Administration

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED

6: MULTI-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

Final Exam. Please answer all four questions. Each question carries 25% of the total grade.

1 No-arbitrage pricing

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV

Martingale Pricing Applied to Dynamic Portfolio Optimization and Real Options

How do Variance Swaps Shape the Smile?

Arrow Debreu Equilibrium. October 31, 2015

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 5. Property Rights Theory. The key question we are staring from is: What are ownership/property rights?

Help Session 2. David Sovich. Washington University in St. Louis

Arbitrage, State Prices and Portfolio Theory Handbook of the Economics of Finance

Introduction to Binomial Trees. Chapter 12

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV. If any mistakes or typos are spotted, kindly communicate them to

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

A1: American Options in the Binomial Model

Valuation of performance-dependent options in a Black- Scholes framework

Strategy Lines and Optimal Mixed Strategy for R

Application of an Interval Backward Finite Difference Method for Solving the One-Dimensional Heat Conduction Problem

Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing

PhD Qualifier Examination

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 10: Introduction to Game Theory 2

Chapter 3 Common Families of Distributions. Definition 3.4.1: A family of pmfs or pdfs is called exponential family if it can be expressed as

MS-E2114 Investment Science Lecture 10: Options pricing in binomial lattices

1 Rational Expectations Equilibrium

Dynamic Asset Pricing Model

Transcription:

Finance: Lecture 4 - No Arbitrage Pricing Chapters 10-12 of DD Chapter 1 of Ross (2005) Prof. Alex Stomper MIT Sloan, IHS & VGSF March 2010 Alex Stomper (MIT, IHS & VGSF) Finance March 2010 1 / 15

Fundamental theorem This class 1 The fundamental theorem 2 The representation theorem 3 Applications Alex Stomper (MIT, IHS & VGSF) Finance March 2010 2 / 15

Fundamental theorem No arbitrage We use a model with two points in time, s possible states (θ 1,..., θ s ) and n traded assets. p = (p 1,..., p N ) is the price vector, Z is the payoff matrix (rows are states, columns are assets). A portfolio η = (η 1,...η n ) costs pη. The payoff vector is Zη. An arbitrage opportunity is a portfolio η that (i) requires no investment, (ii) will not yield a loss, and (iii) may return a strictly positive gain. pη 0 Zη > 0 where x > y means that all (some) components of a vector x are greater or equal to (strictly greater than) the corresponding components of a vector y. Alex Stomper (MIT, IHS & VGSF) Finance March 2010 3 / 15

Fundamental theorem The fundamental theorem The following statements are equivalent: (i) There do not exist any arbitrage opportunities. (ii) There exists a positive linear pricing rule q that prices all assets: p = qz, where all elements of q are strictly positive. (iii) Each agent has a finite optimal demand for all assets. Proof: (ii) (i): let η be an arbitrage opportunity. Then, 0 pη = (qz)η = q(zη). Since q is positive, we obtain a contradiction in that Zη < 0. Alex Stomper (MIT, IHS & VGSF) Finance March 2010 4 / 15

Fundamental theorem Proof: (i) (ii) (sketch) Absence of arbitrage implies that the set of feasible cost/payoff combinations {x η, x = (pη, Zη)} intersects with R + R S + at zero. Since R + R S + is a cone, use a special version of the separating hyperplane theorem: there exists a separating axis s.t. the projection of any point in the set of feasible cost-payoff combinations onto the axis is strictly smaller than that of any point in the interior of R + R S +. For any such interior point x > 0 and any vector (1, q) representing such a projection, we thus have (1, q)x > 0 (since zero is the projection of the zero cost/payoff combination). Since x > 0, q > 0. Moreover, for any x {x η, x = (pη, Zη)}: (1, q)x = (1, q)aη 0 and (since η is also feasible) (1, q)aη = 0, where A = ( p Z ) Alex Stomper (MIT, IHS & VGSF) Finance March 2010 5 / 15

Fundamental theorem Uniqueness of the pricing rule If the market is complete, Z has full row-rank, and p = qz has a unique solution: q = pz 1 In an incomplete market, the securities payoff vectors don t span the state space, and the pricing rule is not unique. Alex Stomper (MIT, IHS & VGSF) Finance March 2010 6 / 15

Representation theorem This class 1 The fundamental theorem 2 The representation theorem 3 Applications Alex Stomper (MIT, IHS & VGSF) Finance March 2010 7 / 15

Representation theorem The representation theorem The following statements are equivalent: (i) There exists a positive linear pricing rule. (ii) The martingale property: there exist martingale or risk-neutral probabilities (or a density) and an associated riskless rate. (iii) There exists a positive pricing kernel or state price density. We will see the requisite definitions as we go along... Alex Stomper (MIT, IHS & VGSF) Finance March 2010 8 / 15

Representation theorem Risk-neutral probabilities / martingale probabilities We start by valuing a riskless payoff. 1 1 + r f,t+1 = q1 = q i Define: risk neutral probabilities as normalized prices: π = q qi Now we value a payoff X with a vector of realizations x: p = qx = q i π x = where i is the index for states. 1 1 + r f,t+1 π x = 1 1 + r f,t+1 E x Alex Stomper (MIT, IHS & VGSF) Finance March 2010 9 / 15

Representation theorem Pricing kernel / state price density A pricing kernel has been defined by: p = EMX = πmx where M denotes the pricing kernel (with a vector of realizations m) and π denotes the probability vector. Since p = qx, we can define the pricing kernel as a vector with components m i = q i π i Will the components of the pricing kernel sum to one? Alex Stomper (MIT, IHS & VGSF) Finance March 2010 10 / 15

Applications This class 1 The fundamental theorem 2 The representation theorem 3 Applications Alex Stomper (MIT, IHS & VGSF) Finance March 2010 11 / 15

Applications Measuring the state-price density What is the value of a security that yields a unit payoff in state i and zero in any other state? Suppose that the state space consists of 6 states in which the payoff of a stock is {8, 9,..., 13}. Here is a table of call prices of calls on the stock with different strike prices. strike price 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 call price 3.22 2.32 1.54 0.94 0.53 0.28 0.14 Alex Stomper (MIT, IHS & VGSF) Finance March 2010 12 / 15

Applications Measuring the state-price density: ctd. Construct butterfly spreads: strike call bfly Payoff if stock price is... 1st diff 2nd diff 8 9 10 11 12 13 7 3.22-0.9 8 2.32 0.12-0.78 9 1.54 1.54 0 0 1 2 3 4 0.18-0.60 10 0.94-1.88 0 0 0-2 -4-6 0.19-0.41 11 0.53 0.53 0 0 0 0 1 2 0.16-0.25 12 0.28 0.11-0.14 13 0.14 0.19 0 0 1 0 0 0 Alex Stomper (MIT, IHS & VGSF) Finance March 2010 13 / 15

Applications Option pricing with the binomial model We want to value an option on a stock that is currently worth p S and may be worth either up S or dp S when the option expires. How can we value the option? There are two states and three assets: the stock, the riskfree asset, and the call option. Local market completeness. What is the pricing rule? Solve: i.e. q u = p S = q u up S + q d dp S 1 = q u (1 + r f ) + q d (1 + r f ) 1 + r f d (1 + r f )(u d) and q d = u (1 + r f ) (1 + r f )(u d) Why is it true that q = (q u, q d ) > 0? Alex Stomper (MIT, IHS & VGSF) Finance March 2010 14 / 15

Applications Option pricing continued We had: q u = 1 + r f d (1 + r f )(u d) and q d = u (1 + r f ) (1 + r f )(u d) Both are positive since no arbitrage requires that u > 1 + r f > d. Risk-neutral probabilities: π = π u + π d = Pricing kernel: m u = q u π u = q u + q d = 1 + r f d + u (1 + r f ) = 1 q u + q d q u + q d (u d) (u d) 1 + r f d π u (1 + r f )(u d) and m d = q d π d = u (1 + r f ) π d (1 + r f )(u d) Let the option payoff be either x u or x d. The option price is: p = q u x u + q d x d = π ux u + π d x d 1 + r f = π u m u x u + π d m d x d Alex Stomper (MIT, IHS & VGSF) Finance March 2010 15 / 15