Recording of interest: treatment of premiums and discounts in the case of active trading on the secondary market

Similar documents
EUROPEAN COMMISSION EUROSTAT

TREATMENT OF INTEREST ON INDEX-LINKED DEBT INSTRUMENTS 1

ESA95 Manual on General Government deficit and debt

Accrual of earnings on equity in the SNA

Holding Gains and Interest Accrual

International Accounting Standard 32. Financial Instruments: Presentation

Financial Instruments: Presentation INTRODUCTION

TRACKING TABLE IPSASS AND GFS REPORTING GUIDELINES: COMPARISON OF RECOGNITION AND MEASUREMENT REQUIREMENTS

TRACKING TABLE IPSASS AND GFS REPORTING GUIDELINES: COMPARISON OF RECOGNITION AND MEASUREMENT REQUIREMENTS

Twelfth Meeting of the IMF Committee on Balance of Payments Statistics Santiago, Chile, October 27-29, 1999

I am writing on behalf of the Conseil National de la Comptabilité (CNC) to express our views on the above-mentioned Discussion Paper.

Deficits and Debt: Economic Effects and Other Issues

V. STOCKS, FLOWS, AND ACCOUNTING RULES

Manik Shrestha Statistics Department International Monetary Fund

Sri Lanka Accounting Standard LKAS 32. Financial Instruments: Presentation

TRACKING TABLE IPSASS AND GFS REPORTING GUIDELINES: COMPARISON OF RECOGNITION AND MEASUREMENT REQUIREMENTS

TRACKING TABLE IPSASS AND GFS REPORTING GUIDELINES: COMPARISON OF RECOGNITION AND MEASUREMENT REQUIREMENTS

Financial Instruments: Presentation

Association of Accounting Technicians response to the Financial Reporting Council (FRC) consultation document Improving the Statement of Cash Flows

General Government Gross Debt in Brazil: Methodological Issues Regarding Government Securities Held by the Central Bank. Abstract

Granting of guarantees in an updated SNA 1

Imputation of property income in the case of liabilities between the sponsor and the pension fund

RISK MANAGEMENT OF THE NATIONAL DEBT

Indian Accounting Standard (Ind AS) 32 (Corresponding to IAS 32) Financial Instruments: Presentation

Original SSAP and Current Authoritative Guidance: SSAP No. 15

8 June Re: FEE Comments on IASB/FASB Phase B Discussion Paper Preliminary Views on Financial Statement Presentation

International Accounting Standard 32 Financial Instruments: Presentation. Objective. Scope IAS 32

Eurostat Guidance on accounting rules for EDP 1. Classification of public holding corporations and their subsidiaries in national accounts

Basis for Conclusions. Financial Instruments Section PS July 2011 PSAB. Page 1 of 16

Re: Invitation to comment Exposure Draft ED/2012/4 Classification and measurement: Limited amendments to IFRS 9 Proposed amendments to IFRS 9 (2010)

STRATEGIC GUIDELINES OF THE PUBLIC DEBT MANAGEMENT

Comments on the Discussion Paper A Review of the Conceptual Framework for Financial Reporting

Financial Management Bachelors of Business Administration Study Notes & Tutorial Questions Chapter 3: Capital Structure

March Basis for Conclusions Exposure Draft ED/2009/2. Income Tax. Comments to be received by 31 July 2009

Financial Instruments: Presentation

IFRS Discussion Group

Notes to the Consolidated Financial Statements

Liability or equity? A practical guide to the classification of financial instruments under IAS 32 March 2013

IFRS Foundation 7 Westferry Circus Canary Wharf London E14 4HD United Kingdom. 1 February Dear Mr Hoogervorst,

Paper F7 (UK) Financial Reporting (United Kingdom) Fundamentals Pilot Paper Skills module. The Association of Chartered Certified Accountants

Loan Valuation Issues May 31, 2004

Financial Instruments: Presentation

Comments on the Preliminary Views Financial Instruments with Characteristics of Equity

Hong Kong Accounting Standard 32 Financial Instruments: Disclosure and Presentation

The Czech Republic Funding and Debt Management Strategy

Discussion Paper: A Review of the Conceptual Framework for Financial Reporting

Central Bank of the Republic of Armenia International Financial Reporting Standards Consolidated financial statements

GENERAL DESCRIPTION OF THE NATURE AND RISKS RELATED TO FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS

Public sector debt: end March 1998

Tel: +44 [0] Fax: +44 [0] ey.com. Tel: Fax:

Consolidated and non-consolidated debt measures of non-financial corporations

Accounting policies. 1. Introduction. 2. Basis of presentation. 3. Consolidation

Deutsche Post Finance B.V. Annual Report 2016

Mr. Bäckström explains why price stability ought to be a central bank s principle monetary policy objective

Appendix. 1 Summary... 3

Audited Accounts Financial Year ended 31 December 2011

ACCRUAL RECORDING OF INTEREST REVISITED: WHY THE SNA MUST BE REVISED. A comment on the IMF Paper on Interest Accrual. Peter Hill

IFRS pocket guide inform.pwc.com

Euroclear / Xtrakter Response

Professional Level Essentials Module, Paper P2 (IRL)

FASB Emerging Issues Task Force

The Toronto-Dominion Bank

Fortis Financial Statements 2007

Appendix. 1 Summary Introduction...5

Guidelines for the OECD questionnaire on INSTITUTIONAL INVESTORS ASSETS AND LIABILITIES. (Table 7II)

GUIDELINE OF THE EUROPEAN CENTRAL BANK

maturity extension of mortgage bonds

Guidance notes to reporting agents on SHS regulation. for statistics on holdings of securities by reporting banking groups

PAPER ON THE ACCOUNTING ADVISORY FORUM FOREIGN CURRENCY TRANSLATION -- > -)( *** *** EUROPEAN COMMISSION

Stay informed. Visit IFRS pocket guide 2012

PUBLIC BENEFIT ENTITY STANDARDS. IMPACT ASSESSMENT FOR PUBLIC SECTOR PBEs

Contingent Liabilities

OTP BANK PLC. CONSOLIDATED FINANCIAL STATEMENTS IN ACCORDANCE WITH INTERNATIONAL FINANCIAL REPORTING STANDARDS AS ADOPTED BY THE EUROPEAN UNION

ETFS Equity Securities Limited. ETFS Short Equity Securities. ETFS Leveraged Equity Securities

Independent Auditors Report - to the members 1. Consolidated Statement of Financial Position 2. Consolidated Statement of Comprehensive Income 3

3. Accounting Principles for Financial Soundness Indicators

Re: Comment on the IASB s Discussion Paper Financial Instruments with Characteristics of Equity

Index definition definition definition definition definition definition definition 207

Eurostat Guidance Note. TREATMENT OF DEFERRED TAX ASSETS (DTAs) AND RECORDING OF TAX CREDITS RELATED TO DTAs IN ESA2010.

Notes to the Accounts

Total comprehensive income for year 25 8

PSAK Pocket guide 2018

that finance income/expenses consist of the following five line items:

I am writing on behalf of the Autorité des Normes Comptables (ANC) to express our views on the Exposure draft on proposed amendments to IAS 19.

Hans Hoogervorst Chairman IFRS Foundation 30 Cannon Street London EC4M 6XH. 24 November Dear Hans

CLERICAL MEDICAL FINANCE PLC

GOVERNMENT FINANCE STATISTICS MANUAL 2001 COMPANION MATERIAL GUIDELINES FOR RESPONDING TO THE NONFINANCIAL PUBLIC SECTOR DEBT TEMPLATE (DRAFT VERSION)

DISREGARDED ENTITIES AND PARTNERSHIP LIABILITY ALLOCATIONS: PROPOSED REGS CRITIQUED

Joint Consultation Paper

Federal Ministry of Finance

1. INTRODUCTION Accounting Requirements for Expenses Minor Amendments MAIN REQUIREMENTS... 4

BOND RISK DISCLOSURE NOTICE

Update of the Registration Document Filed with the Autorité des Marchés Financiers on 29 June 2005 under reference number D.

STRIP BONDS AND STRIP BOND PACKAGES

Financial Accounting Series

Illustrative Financial Statement Alternative Investment Funds. December 31, 2018

SNA/M1.17/ th Meeting of the Advisory Expert Group on National Accounts, 5-7 December 2017, New York, USA. Agenda item: 5.

The quantitativ start (bond market)

Key Implications of the EU s new PRIIPs and MiFID II Regimes for Offerings of Debt Securities

Advice to the European Commission on the review of the Financial Conglomerates Directive 1

Transcription:

Peter Burgold, Ulrich Burgtorf, Thomas Bohm (Deutsche Bundesbank) Jens Grütz (Destatis) 1 March 2018 Recording of interest: treatment of premiums and discounts in the case of active trading on the secondary market The calculation of the German central government interest expenditure based on the Capital cost model (CCM) was first presented at the EDPS WG in December 2017. However, while the methodology seems straightforward from an economic perspective, it is not in line with the second part of ESA 20.180 (revaluation), but applies a strict debtor approach. In order to support an enhanced discussion about economically sensible recording options compliant with ESA 2010, Eurostat proposed further input for the discussion with CCM as a starting point. Against this background this short overview aims at highlighting the challenges of finding an appropriate ESA compatible recording of interest expenditure in the case of very active debt management activities on the secondary market, which do not have the character of borrowing or redemption but rather market smoothing (the outstanding amount of an issuance is rather stable, but sizeable selling and buying activities take place even intraday). We start by describing the current calculation of central government interest expenditure in Germany as it is produced by the debt management agency as a new standard product and which has been the basis of the latest German national accounts recording. However, in case of premiums and discounts no revaluation effects are extracted, which may therefore - at least partially - not match with ESA provisions. On the other hand, an asymmetric recording of revaluation effects, particularly in the case of very sizeable debt management activities, does not match the ESA debtor principle and also opens scope for economically disadvantageous practices by increasing or decreasing secondary market activities targeting at shaping interest expenditure in ESA. In a second step, we argue that ESA and MGDD interpretation offer at least two different readings, one of them treating secondary market transactions symmetrically. Given the ESA debtor principle we argue in favour of such a symmetrical treatment. 1

1. Institutional background in Germany The German federal debt agency (Finanzagentur) is an extra-budgetary unit of federal government classified in S.13. 1 Finanzagentur issues various debt instruments on behalf of German (central) government. A broad range of original maturities intends to reconcile government financing needs with the market demand for bonds. In order to ensure high liquidity of the bonds, issuances, especially of instruments with higher maturities, are run in several tranches on the primary market, often over years. While newly issued bonds (first tranche of a series) are usually equipped with coupons close to prevailing market rates, subsequent taps of the same security (same ISIN) obviously carry the first tranche s coupon, which may be considerably remote from the current market rate. Therefore, in an environment of decreasing market interest rates, further tranches entail premiums on the debt instruments face values (and discounts in times of increasing market interest rates). Additionally, Finanzagentur is a very active player on the secondary market, repurchasing and reselling bonds in order to minimize yield differences between market places and to smooth intra-day yield volatility in order to minimize liquidity risks. To this end, important amounts of securities are traded (simultaneously) each day without major impact on the volume in circulation over time and even at the end of the day. However, towards the end of a bond s lifespan, Finanzagentur systematically decreases the volume in circulation by repurchasing more bonds than it sells. This reduces the refinancing volume at maturity. 2. The model of Finanzagentur to monitor interest costs The current so-called capital cost model (CCM) of Finanzagentur is basically an accrual approach matching total cost and (net) cash paid over each instrument s lifespan. Whenever issuing or trading a bond, the difference between its face value and actual cash paid or received is considered to constitute (possibly negative) cost of borrowing. This cost of borrowing is spread over the (daily) remaining lifespan of the bond. In this way, CCM prevents the usual daily secondary market repurchases and re-sales from impacting the recorded cost of borrowing, except through realised arbitrage profits. Thus, given an environment of decreasing interest rates, later issuances (e.g. in the context of additional tranches) tend to create premiums (received) that decrease the cost of borrowing compared to the coupons (as the interest conditions at the time of issuance have improved). Premiums and discounts in the context of debt management secondary market operations (while the outstanding amount remains rather constant) net out more or less, while the net repurchases towards the end of the bond s lifespan cause premiums (paid) that increase the cost of borrowing, in each case over the remaining maturity 2. 1 Public debt management offices, even if they are separate institutional units, should be classified in the general government sector (MGDD 2016, I.7 Government debt management offices). 2 The overall interest expenditure remains unchanged, if the operation is financed with new debt, which is subject to the lower market interest rate (compared to the coupon of the debt which is repaid). 2

In substance, CCM is a strict debtor approach to recording interest, where all cash paid and received is distributed (linearly) over the instrument s remaining lifespan. 3 Therefore, no holding gains or losses are recorded. Its clear advantage is that CCM reflects the effective financial burden for the budget and creates neither an incentive to creatively shape the interest expenditure nor a disincentive to implement a sound debt management (that increases market liquidity by actively trading on secondary markets), because there is no option to strategically avoid or realise holding gains or losses which would then affect interest expenditure and the deficit/surplus. Therefore, CCM provides a clear and transparent tool for monitoring the interest costs of central government while avoiding any economically disadvantageous incentives. On the other side, CCM creates an inconsistency in the system of national accounts when bonds are repurchased at a premium or discount. While a premium is recorded as future interest expenditure in CCM, there is no counterparty in national accounts to receive this income. 4 Similarly, a discount at repurchase is considered to reduce future interest expenditure, without changing the interest income of the remaining creditors. This inconsistency may be considered as prevailing from a disaggregated point of view while from an aggregated perspective, obviously, bonds (even of the same ISIN) continue to exist. 3. Interest recording in ESA ESA 20.179 distinguishes the debtor and the creditor approach to interest recording: [ ] The debtor approach is from the perspective of the unit issuing the security and the creditor approach is from the perspective of the unit holding the security. From the debtor approach, the interest rate agreed on initiation is used throughout the life of the security. From the creditor approach, the current interest rate is used to value the interest between any two points in the life of the security. ESA 20.180 commits to the debtor principle stating: Accrual interest is recorded according to the debtor approach, that is: based on the rate or yield prevailing at the time of creation of the financial instrument. Thus, interest expenditure to be recorded on fixed-rate debt securities does not vary over time in sympathy with market fluctuations, despite the fact that the market value of the securities fluctuates and that, accordingly, the opportunity costs of carrying this debt vary. In that way, interest expenditure avoids the volatility that the creditor approach entails. [ ] The MGDD further clarifies that "ESA 2010 focuses on the financial burden, the cost of borrowing that was anticipated when the debtor raised funds through the issuance of financial instruments" (II.4.3.2.8). Note that the reason indicated for choosing the debtor principle is that interest expenditure should not vary in sympathy with market fluctuations. 3 An exception applies to coupons paid, which are spread only over the preceding coupon period. 4 A similar problem arises while decommissioning nuclear waste. Even if the original energy supplier ceased its activity a notional entry, for the institutional sector, is recorded. See MGDD 2016, III.7.2.2. 3

ESA 20.182 also clarifies the case of issuances in various tranches which is considered a primary market activity: "In many countries, government bonds or notes are issued in fungible tranches, over several years, with the same conditions concerning the nominal rate of interest. Because the market yield at time of further sale of tranches varies, each tranche is actually sold at a premium or at a discount. Thus, the rate of interest agreed on at time of issuing the bond is used for calculating interest, which will vary for each tranche" This is in line with the understanding that the official registered volume has been increased. ESA 20.180 treats repurchases of securities: The repurchase of securities on the market, at a premium or at a discount to the principal outstanding, does not lead to any entry in revenue or expenditure at time of purchase or later on. Instead, any repurchase premium or discount reflects the settlement, recorded in the financial accounts, of a holding gain or loss that accrued in the past and was recorded in the revaluation accounts at that time. In contrast, ESA does not mention re-sales of securities and the treatment of their discounts and premiums. Therefore, it is necessary to conclude indirectly what treatment would be in line with the regulation. Two options may come up: (A) Re-sales should be treated as a new creation of an instrument. (B) Re-sales should be treated symmetrically to repurchases. Both shall now be briefly explained. 3.1. Re-sales should be treated as new issuances ESA 5.30 prescribes: When a department of an institutional unit purchases bonds issued by another department of the same institutional unit, the financial account of the unit does not record the transaction as the acquisition of a claim by one department on another. The transaction is recorded as a redemption of liabilities rather than an acquisition of consolidating assets. In the same vein, ESA 20.130 states: The repurchase by a unit of a liability is recorded as redemption in liabilities and not as an acquisition of assets. Likewise, at a subsector or sector level, the purchase by a government unit of a liability issued by another unit of the subsector in question will be presented in the consolidated presentation, as redemption of liability by that subsector. If ESA considers the repurchase of bonds as redemption, then it seems that their re-sale should be regarded as a new issuance. On the other hand, this reading contradicts the ESA debtor principle, since multiple secondary market transactions, as executed by Finanzagentur, will detach interest expenditure from the yield prevailing at the time of creation of the financial instrument (20.180) towards the current market yield which the debtor principle aims at avoiding. This interpretation 4

therefore may create an incentive for governments to actively trade on secondary markets during times of decreasing interest rates while creating a disincentive to such activities during times of increasing interest rates. The recorded interest and the deficit can be significantly influenced, although the real fiscal burden remains constant. A conceptual inconsistency may be seen in a case of two private investors acquiring exactly the same government bond on the secondary market, but with a different yield for the investor buying the bond from a government unit compared to the other one buying it from a third party, even if the price paid is identical. 3.2. Re-sales should be treated symmetrically to repurchases Both re-sales and repurchases take place on secondary markets. As described above, they are usually carried out every day and, in most cases, do not impact significantly the volume of the bond in circulation. The ESA debtor principle requires that market fluctuations do not impact interest expenditure which, in turn, requires secondary market re-sales to trigger revaluations in the same way as for repurchases 5. This would also be compatible to the MGDD provision Secondary markets transactions, when existing, have no influence on the accrued interest to be recorded (II.4.3.2.8). It might be argued that the issuer cannot, by definition, take part in secondary market transactions of its own instruments, but the understanding that government debt management agencies are performing secondary market activities seems to be common in practice. Primary market transactions follow a very specific procedure with specific provisions for the tendering/auction process as well as for choosing eligible participants of the auctions. This is valid for each separate tranche that is issued, but clearly different from any secondary market trading activity. Also the MGDD clarification "ESA 2010 focuses on the financial burden, the cost of borrowing that was anticipated when the debtor raised funds through the issuance of financial instruments" (II.4.3.2.8) could be understood as excluding trading activity which, in fact, does not raise new funds. The symmetrical treatment of re-sales and repurchases would not necessarily contradict the above cited ESA 5.30 which continues to read: Such financial instruments are viewed as netted. Netting is to be avoided if it is necessary to keep the financial instrument on both the asset side and the liability side to follow the legal presentation. The repurchased debt of the German federal government is not extinguished from the official federal debt register, but recorded separately as own securities on the asset side in the government accounts ( Vermoegensrechnung ). Admittedly, it is arguable whether the mentioned exception applies to the case at hand. At first glance, it seems difficult to see any merits to follow the legal presentation. However, with a view to the issue at stake it may facilitate an ESA interpretation compatible with a symmetric treatment of trading activity. 5 Also Eurostat seems to consider the idea of symmetrical treatment of trading activity, in principle. Cf. EDPS WG July 2017 minutes: On the other hand, Eurostat wondered whether some rules could be applied, for those secondary market operations, such as considering that the instrument resold is not a new issuance, but a resale, when it would come to determine the ESA 2010 nominal value concept. 5

ESA 5.30 and 20.130 might also be reconciled with the proposed symmetrical treatment of secondary market transactions by being thought of referring only to final repurchases, i.e. to government units with the intention to hold until maturity the debt repurchased. This reading would then prevent later re-sales from being regarded as new issuances and therefore allow for a symmetrical treatment. Since in practice, a differentiation of the intention would be rather difficult, practical implementation might require an analysis of the usual intention which should then apply consistently to all observed transactions. An alternative implementation of a debtor principle would be that neither secondary market repurchases nor re-sales trigger revaluations, which corresponds to the concept of CCM. Moreover, CCM represents the only approach, where decreasing market rates do not create the possibility to manipulate downwards interest expenditure by redeeming old bonds (paying a premium that is recorded as revaluation) and issuing new bonds at (lower) market rates, thereby again circumventing the ESA debtor principle. However, it seems difficult to reconcile CCM with the explicit requirement of ESA 20.180 (revaluation). 4. Weighing up the alternatives The current interest recording for central government securities issued by Finanzagentur (CCM) constitutes a straightforward and intuitive concept, neutral in terms of incentives to trading on secondary markets and strictly following the debtor approach. However, it is in conflict with ESA 20.180 (revaluations). Nonetheless, it seems unclear how the pure ESA approach treats premiums and discounts of government bond re-sales, because neither MGDD nor ESA provide explicit guidance in this regard. At least there seems to be a conflict with the MGDD interpretation of the debtor principle (as well as with economic substance) if the rate prevailing at time the funds were raised on the market could be changed by trading activity (i.e. simultaneously repurchasing and re-selling the instrument). Given the fact that there is no obvious stance of ESA on the matter of re-sales, we consider it strongly advisable to treat secondary market repurchases and re-sales symmetrically due to the economic substance and the otherwise induced incentives or disincentives to undertake secondary market trading. We invite all MS to share their thoughts on ESA compatible treatments of government bond re-sales in view of the above arguments. 6