Why are Banks Exposed to Monetary Policy?

Similar documents
Why are Bank Balance Sheets Exposed to Monetary Policy?

Why are Banks Exposed to Monetary Policy?

Why are Banks Exposed to Monetary Policy?

Disaster risk and its implications for asset pricing Online appendix

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

ECON 815. A Basic New Keynesian Model II

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics

Leads, Lags, and Logs: Asset Prices in Business Cycle Analysis

Uninsured Unemployment Risk and Optimal Monetary Policy

Bank Capital Requirements: A Quantitative Analysis

Networks in Production: Asset Pricing Implications

Uncertainty Shocks In A Model Of Effective Demand

International Monetary Theory: Mundell Fleming Redux

A Model of Financial Intermediation

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics

Household Debt, Financial Intermediation, and Monetary Policy

The Real Business Cycle Model

Extended DSGE Model of the Czech Economy

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound

Foreign Competition and Banking Industry Dynamics: An Application to Mexico

Term Premium Dynamics and the Taylor Rule. Bank of Canada Conference on Fixed Income Markets

Growth Opportunities, Investment-Specific Technology Shocks and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

Frequency of Price Adjustment and Pass-through

The Shape of the Term Structures

Online Appendix to Financing Asset Sales and Business Cycles

Debt Covenants and the Macroeconomy: The Interest Coverage Channel

BIRKBECK (University of London) MSc EXAMINATION FOR INTERNAL STUDENTS MSc FINANCIAL ENGINEERING DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, MATHEMATICS AND STATIS- TICS

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices

Nominal Rigidities, Asset Returns and Monetary Policy

Endogenous Trade Participation with Incomplete Exchange Rate Pass-Through

Vayanos and Vila, A Preferred-Habitat Model of the Term Stru. the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

Oil Price Uncertainty in a Small Open Economy

A Macroeconomic Framework for Quantifying Systemic Risk. June 2012

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption

The Analytics of the Greek Crisis

Monetary Economics Final Exam

Long Run Labor Income Risk

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

. Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium. S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO)

Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

International Asset Pricing and Risk Sharing with Recursive Preferences

Chapter 5 Macroeconomics and Finance

Why Surplus Consumption in the Habit Model May be Less Pe. May be Less Persistent than You Think

Inflation & Welfare 1

Deflation, Credit Collapse and Great Depressions. Enrique G. Mendoza

A Model with Costly-State Verification

Bank Capital, Agency Costs, and Monetary Policy. Césaire Meh Kevin Moran Department of Monetary and Financial Analysis Bank of Canada

Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis

Balance Sheet Recessions

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions

Pricing and hedging with rough-heston models

Microfoundations of DSGE Models: III Lecture

Lorant Kaszab (MNB) Roman Horvath (IES)

Uncertainty, Liquidity and Financial Cycles

International Banks and the Cross-Border Transmission of Business Cycles 1

The Basic New Keynesian Model

Menu Costs and Phillips Curve by Mikhail Golosov and Robert Lucas. JPE (2007)

Optimal Taxation Under Capital-Skill Complementarity

The Tail that Wags the Economy: Belief-driven Business Cycles and Persistent Stagnation

Growth and Inclusion: Theoretical and Applied Perspectives

Leads, Lags, and Logs: Asset Prices in Business Cycle Analysis

What is Cyclical in Credit Cycles?

Macro II. John Hassler. Spring John Hassler () New Keynesian Model:1 04/17 1 / 10

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World

Appendix to: Long-Run Asset Pricing Implications of Housing Collateral Constraints

Stock Price, Risk-free Rate and Learning

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

Optimal Portfolio Composition for Sovereign Wealth Funds

Staggered Wages, Sticky Prices, and Labor Market Dynamics in Matching Models. by Janett Neugebauer and Dennis Wesselbaum

Evaluating Electricity Generation, Energy Options, and Complex Networks

Imperfect Information and Market Segmentation Walsh Chapter 5

The Risk Channel of Unconventional Monetary Policy

Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

The Extensive Margin of Trade and Monetary Policy

The CAPM Strikes Back? An Investment Model with Disasters

Introduction. The Model Setup F.O.Cs Firms Decision. Constant Money Growth. Impulse Response Functions

Investment strategies and risk management for participating life insurance contracts

Pricing Pension Buy-ins and Buy-outs 1

ASSET PRICING WITH LIMITED RISK SHARING AND HETEROGENOUS AGENTS

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

Technology shocks and Monetary Policy: Assessing the Fed s performance

The science of monetary policy

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy. Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University)

Limits to Arbitrage. George Pennacchi. Finance 591 Asset Pricing Theory

1 Dynamic programming

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

A Macroeconomic Framework for Quantifying Systemic Risk

A Macroeconomic Framework for Quantifying Systemic Risk

What Can Rational Investors Do About Excessive Volatility and Sentiment Fluctuations?

John H. Cochrane. April University of Chicago Booth School of Business

Asset Pricing with Left-Skewed Long-Run Risk in. Durable Consumption

Term Premium Dynamics and the Taylor Rule 1

Achieving Actuarial Balance in Social Security: Measuring the Welfare Effects on Individuals

Incorporating Managerial Cash-Flow Estimates and Risk Aversion to Value Real Options Projects. The Fields Institute for Mathematical Sciences

Transcription:

Why are Banks Exposed to Monetary Policy? Sebastian Di Tella and Pablo Kurlat Stanford University Bank of Portugal, June 2017

Banks are exposed to monetary policy shocks Assets Loans (long term) Liabilities Deposits (short term) Net Worth Maturity mismatch interest rate risk Transmission channel of monetary policy Begenau, Piazzesi & Schneider (2014): banks use derivatives (interest rate swaps) to increase exposure to interest rate risk

Why do banks choose this exposure? Focus on banks as providers of liquidity Banks exposure to interest-rate risk is part of dynamic hedging strategy deposit spreads co-move with interest rate (Drechsler et al. 2015) capital gains offset flow returns implement with maturity-mismatched balance sheet Fits level, time series, and cross-section of maturity mismatch

Technology and Preferences Fixed capital stock k produces constant output flow y = ak Households and bankers with the same preferences: ( f (x,u) = ρ(1 γ)u log(x) 1 ) 1 γ log((1 γ)u) Epstein-Zin with EIS=1 and RRA γ Currency-and-deposits in the utility function: x: Cobb-Douglas aggregator of c (consumption) and m (money) x(c,m) = c β m 1 β m: CES aggregator of h (real currency) and d ( real deposits). Elasticity ǫ m(h,d) = (α 1 ǫ h ǫ 1 ǫ ) +(1 α) 1 ǫ ǫ 1 ǫ 1 ǫ d ǫ

Monetary Policy Currency supplied via (stochastic) lump-sum transfers Flexible prices Reverse-engineered to produce stochastic process for interest rates: di t = µ(i t )dt+σ(i t )db t B is standard Brownian Motion Friedman rule is optimal it = 0 In quantitative section, Cox-Ingersoll-Ross process: µ(i) = λ(i ī) σ(i) = σ i

Deposits Bankers can issue deposits up to leverage limit d S φn regulatory constraint/economic condition for deposits to be liquid prevents infinite supply of deposits makes bankers net worth an important state variable In equilibrium deposits pay (endogenous) nominal rate i d t < i t. Spread: s t = i t i d t > 0

Markets Complete markets real interest rate: rt = i t µ p,t trade exposure to B at price πt Capital and lump-sum transfers priced by arbitrage No assumptions on what assets banks hold

Household and Banker s Problems Household s.t. ( dw t = w t max w,x,c,m,h,d,σ w U (x) ) r t +σ w,t π t ĉ t ĥti t ˆd ( t it i d ) t dt+σ w,t db t }{{} s t m t = (α 1 ǫ h ǫ 1 ǫ t x t = c β tm 1 β t +(1 α) 1 ǫ d ǫ 1 ǫ t w t 0 ) ǫ ǫ 1 Banker: same except bankers earn spread on deposits issued: dn ( t = r t +σ n,t π t ĉ t ĥti t n ˆd ) t s t +ˆd S t s t dt+σ n,t db t t ˆd S t φ

Equilibrium Definition State variables: i: current level of interest rates z = n : fraction of total wealth held by bankers n+w Equilibrium 1. Value functions and policy functions 2. Prices 3. Law of motion for z such that 1. Value and policy functions solve household & banker s problem 2. Markets clear 2.1 goods 2.2 currency 2.3 deposits 2.4 capital 3. Law of motion for z is consistent with policy functions

Deposit Spread From the FOCs and market clearing for deposits we get a static equation for the deposit spread: ( ) ǫ ι(i,s) (1 α) (1 β) χ(i,s) ρ = φ z s ι(i,s) χ(i, s) }{{}}{{}}{{}}{{}}{{} d m x d m x ω z n n ω where ι and χ are CES and Cobb-Douglas price indices Solve for spread s(i,z) decreasing in z increasing in i if ǫ > 1 ι(i,s) = ( αi 1 ǫ +(1 α)s 1 ǫ) 1 1 ǫ ( ) 1 β χ(i,s) = (β) β ι(i,s) 1 β

Deposit Spread s(i,z) OLS regression of spread (Drechsler et al. [2014]) on i (Libor 6m) and z (Flow of Funds): s = 0.3% + 0.66 i 0.99 z (0.22%) (0.028) (0.25) s = 0.3% + 0.98 i 4.07 i 2 0.71 z (0.44%) (0.17) (2.02) (0.32)

Exposure of z to monetary shocks B Value function has form Vt h (w) = (ζ tw) 1 γ 1 γ Vt b (n) = (ξ tn) 1 γ 1 γ for household for banker the endogenous ζ t and ξ t capture forward-looking investment opportunities FOCs for risk exposure: σ w = π γ + 1 γ σ ζ γ }{{} household σ n = π γ + 1 γ σ ξ γ }{{} banker Premium + dynamic hedging Income vs. substitution. If γ > 1, income effect dominates

Exposure of z to monetary shocks B Therefore, exposure of z n n+w : σ z = (1 z)(σ n σ w ) = σ z = (1 z) 1 γ γ (σ ξ σ ζ ) How banks share of wealth z reacts to an increase in interest rates depends on: how relative investment opportunities ξ/ζ react: σξ σ ζ > 0 income vs substitution effects: 1 γ γ < 0 Dynamic hedge: banks are willing to take a loss when interest rates rise because they expect large spreads looking forward

Parameter Values Meaning Value Remarks γ Risk aversion 10 Bansal & Yaron (2004) ī Mean interest rate 3.5% σ Volatility of i 0.044 6m LIBOR λ Mean reversion of i 0.056 Volatility of 10-year rates ρ Discount rate 0.055 consumption wealth Checking + Savings Net Worth φ Leverage 8.77 α CES weight on currency 0.95 Time series of s(i,z) β CD consumption share 0.93 (Drechsler et. al. 2014) ǫ Elasticity currency / deposits 6.6 σ a Volatility of TFP 0.073 Risk free rate τ Tax on bank equity 0.195 Average z

Deposit Spread s(i,z)

Banks exposure to movements in interest rates: σn /σi

Maturity Mismatch T Implement σ n with traditional balance sheet: assets: zero coupon nominal bond of maturity T liabilities: short-term nominal liabilities (e.g. deposits) Compute maturity mismatch: Price bonds of every maturity p B (i,z;t) Compute exposure of each bond to interest rates σp B (i,z;t) Find maturity T such that σ n = (1+φ)σ pb (i,z;t)

Maturity Mismatch Higher maturity mismatch when i and z are low: reflects larger sensitivity of s(i,z) to changes in i in that region. OLS: T = 4.4 11.7 i 1.9 z (0.1) (6.8) (0.4)

Quantitative evaluation: time series Construct banks maturity mismatch using Call Reports (English et al. (2012)) record contractual or repricing maturity of assets and liabilities, and substract asset-weighted median across banks compare with model predictions based on time series for i and z

Maturity mismatch time series Levels: avg. maturity mismatch data: 4.4 yrs; model: 3.9 yrs Time pattern: maturity mismatch high when i low; correlation: 0.77

Cross sectional evidence Model: banks with more deposits should have a larger maturity mismatch Re-solve banker s problem with different φ = d/n; for each φ compute the whole time series of maturity mismatch, and take average Regress maturity mismatch on φ: β = 0.42 Same regression in the data Median OLS Constant 2.6 3.6 (0.0023) (0.063) φ 0.43 0.26 (0.0004) (0.013) N 10, 351 10, 351

Real shocks under inflation targeting Shocks to expected growth rate µ a,t : dµ a,t = λ(µ a,t µ a )dt+σ µ a,t µ min a,t db t µ a,t Central bank adjusts currency supply to keep inflation constant (e.g. 2%): i t = r t + µ p Negative growth shock low eq. real interest rate low nominal interest rate Set parameters to match volatility of interest rates Requires large and persistent growth shocks

Maturity Mismatch with Real Shocks Levels: avg. maturity mismatch data: 4.4 yrs; model: 4.7 yrs Time pattern: maturity mismatch high when i low; correlation: 0.51

Conclusions Dynamic hedging of deposit spreads explains banks interest-rate exposure average, time pattern, cross-sectional pattern Does not depend on why interest rates move: monetary and real shocks under inflation targeting Banks maturity mismatch amplifies the effects of monetary policy shock on the cost of liquidity Implications for other types of risk exposure (e.g. credit spreads)

Extra: Static Decisions Currency-deposit choice (from CES): unit cost of m is d ( ι ǫ h ( ι ) ǫ m s) = (1 α) m = α i ι(i,s) = ( αi 1 ǫ +(1 α)s 1 ǫ) 1 1 ǫ Consumption-money choice (from Cobb-Douglas): c = β(χx) ιm = (1 β)(χx) unit cost of x is ( ) 1 β χ(i,s) = (β) β ι(i,s) 1 β

Extra: Dynamic Decisions FOC for ˆx is the same for household and banker: ˆx t }{{} x wealth χ t }{{} unit cost of x = ρ IES = 1 spending = ρ wealth Goods market clearing: ak }{{} output = β }{{} consumption spending ρ }{{} spending wealth ω t }{{} total wealth ω t n t +w t = ak βρ Cobb-Douglas + IES = 1 Constant wealth