Lecture 3: Information in Sequential Screening

Similar documents
Evaluating Strategic Forecasters. Rahul Deb with Mallesh Pai (Rice) and Maher Said (NYU Stern) Becker Friedman Theory Conference III July 22, 2017

Optimal Information Disclosure in Auctions and the Handicap Auction

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions

Practice Problems 2: Asymmetric Information

Sequential versus Static Screening: An equivalence result

The Benefits of Sequential Screening

SEQUENTIAL INFORMATION DISCLOSURE IN AUCTIONS. Dirk Bergemann and Achim Wambach. July 2013 Revised October 2014

Optimal Procurement Contracts with Private Knowledge of Cost Uncertainty

Countering the Winner s Curse: Optimal Auction Design in a Common Value Model

Optimal Auctions. Game Theory Course: Jackson, Leyton-Brown & Shoham

Auction Theory: Some Basics

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

Recap First-Price Revenue Equivalence Optimal Auctions. Auction Theory II. Lecture 19. Auction Theory II Lecture 19, Slide 1

Discriminatory Information Disclosure

Sequential information disclosure in auctions

Problem Set 3: Suggested Solutions

Up till now, we ve mostly been analyzing auctions under the following assumptions:

Sequential versus Static Screening: An equivalence result

MONOPOLY (2) Second Degree Price Discrimination

Price Discrimination As Portfolio Diversification. Abstract

Information Design in the Hold-up Problem

Auction Theory Lecture Note, David McAdams, Fall Bilateral Trade

Mechanism Design and Auctions

Auctions in the wild: Bidding with securities. Abhay Aneja & Laura Boudreau PHDBA 279B 1/30/14

Where do securities come from

1 Theory of Auctions. 1.1 Independent Private Value Auctions

DARTMOUTH COLLEGE, DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 21. Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02. Topic 5: Information

Problem Set 3: Suggested Solutions

Day 3. Myerson: What s Optimal

Chapter 3. Dynamic discrete games and auctions: an introduction

DYNAMIC SCREENING WITH LIMITED COMMITMENT

Competing Mechanisms with Limited Commitment

Auctions 1: Common auctions & Revenue equivalence & Optimal mechanisms. 1 Notable features of auctions. use. A lot of varieties.

1 Rational Expectations Equilibrium

March 30, Why do economists (and increasingly, engineers and computer scientists) study auctions?

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India July 2012

Conjugate Information Disclosure in an Auction with. Learning

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Optimal Information Disclosure in Auctions and the Handicap Auction

CS364B: Frontiers in Mechanism Design Lecture #18: Multi-Parameter Revenue-Maximization

Practice Problems. U(w, e) = p w e 2,

Optimal Sales Contracts with Withdrawal Rights

SEQUENTIAL INFORMATION DISCLOSURE IN AUCTIONS. Dirk Bergemann and Achim Wambach. July 2013 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO.

Revenue Management with Forward-Looking Buyers

Problem 1: Random variables, common distributions and the monopoly price

Homework 3: Asymmetric Information

Practice Problems. w U(w, e) = p w e 2,

The Optimality of Being Efficient. Lawrence Ausubel and Peter Cramton Department of Economics University of Maryland

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Practice Problems 1: Moral Hazard

Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard with Multidimensional Types

Mechanism Design: Single Agent, Discrete Types

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: August 7, 2017

Persuasion in Global Games with Application to Stress Testing. Supplement

An Ascending Double Auction

Dynamic screening with limited commitment

Multi-agent contracts with positive externalities

Optimal Auctions with Ambiguity

Problem 1: Random variables, common distributions and the monopoly price

Microeconomic Theory III Spring 2009

Price Setting with Interdependent Values

Multiunit Auctions: Package Bidding October 24, Multiunit Auctions: Package Bidding

Dynamic signaling and market breakdown

Recalling that private values are a special case of the Milgrom-Weber setup, we ve now found that

d. Find a competitive equilibrium for this economy. Is the allocation Pareto efficient? Are there any other competitive equilibrium allocations?

Asset Pricing under Asymmetric Information Rational Expectations Equilibrium

Bounding the bene ts of stochastic auditing: The case of risk-neutral agents w

Auctions That Implement Efficient Investments

General Equilibrium under Uncertainty

LI Reunión Anual. Noviembre de Managing Strategic Buyers: Should a Seller Ban Resale? Beccuti, Juan Coleff, Joaquin

(v 50) > v 75 for all v 100. (d) A bid of 0 gets a payoff of 0; a bid of 25 gets a payoff of at least 1 4

Backward Integration and Risk Sharing in a Bilateral Monopoly

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems

Making Collusion Hard: Asymmetric Information as a Counter-Corruption Measure

Signaling in an English Auction: Ex ante versus Interim Analysis

PhD Qualifier Examination

Optimal Information Disclosure in Auctions and The Handicap Auction

Notes on Auctions. Theorem 1 In a second price sealed bid auction bidding your valuation is always a weakly dominant strategy.

Competition and risk taking in a differentiated banking sector

1 Auctions. 1.1 Notation (Symmetric IPV) Independent private values setting with symmetric riskneutral buyers, no budget constraints.

3.4 Copula approach for modeling default dependency. Two aspects of modeling the default times of several obligors

Optimal Dynamic Auctions

Stochastic Games and Bayesian Games

Auditing in the Presence of Outside Sources of Information

Problem Set: Contract Theory

In Diamond-Dybvig, we see run equilibria in the optimal simple contract.

Mechanism Design and Auctions

Basic Assumptions (1)

Auctions: Types and Equilibriums

Games of Incomplete Information ( 資訊不全賽局 ) Games of Incomplete Information

Topic 7. Nominal rigidities

Auctioning a Single Item. Auctions. Simple Auctions. Simple Auctions. Models of Private Information. Models of Private Information

Posted-Price Mechanisms and Prophet Inequalities

Universidade de Aveiro Departamento de Economia, Gestão e Engenharia Industrial. Documentos de Trabalho em Economia Working Papers in Economics

1 The principal-agent problems

ECO 426 (Market Design) - Lecture 8

An Incomplete Contracts Approach to Financial Contracting

Problem Set: Contract Theory

Real Options and Game Theory in Incomplete Markets

Transcription:

Lecture 3: Information in Sequential Screening NMI Workshop, ISI Delhi August 3, 2015

Motivation A seller wants to sell an object to a prospective buyer(s). Buyer has imperfect private information θ about value v. The seller controls additional signal about v. The seller can partially or fully disclose her signal to buyer. Disclosure is private: Seller cannot observe the realization of the disclosed signal, or seller observes signal realization but does not know how it enters buyer s utility function. Research question: What is the jointly optimal selling mechanism and disclosure policy?

Sequential Learning and Information Control Buyers often receive information sequentially: buyers start with some initial incomplete information they receive additional information later airline tickets, hotel booking, new products, business assets, fine art and estate... Sellers often have substantial control over information: supply production information (Lewis and Sappington, 1994, Johnson and Myatt, 2006) control access to information in indicative bidding (Ye, 2007) control how buyers learn by restricting the number and nature of tests they can carry out

Lecture Plan Will first cover the sequential screening model of Courty and Li (2000). Will then cover the full disclosure result of Esö and Szentes (2007). This results depends on a common orthogonalization trick in dynamic mechanism design. Then, will discuss how information disclosure can be profitable if seller controls correlated shocks (Li and Shi 2015). At a technical level, highlights the limitation of orthogonal decomposition approach to information disclosure.

Courty and Li (2000): Sequential Screening Review of Economic Studies

Sequential Screening Example Consider an example of airplane ticket pricing. Seller has a cost of 1 per seat. 1/3 are leisure travelers whose valuation is U[1, 2] 2/3 are business travelers whose valuation is U[0, 1] [2, 3]. Business travelers face greater valuation uncertainty. Once travelers have privately learned their valuations, the value distribution is U[0, 3]. Monopoly price is 2 with expected profit of 1/3. All leisure travelers and half of business travelers are excluded.

Sequential Screening Example Suppose instead that the seller offers two contracts before the travelers learn their valuation. These contracts consist of an advance payment and refund. The first has an advance payment of 1.5 and no refund. The other has an advance payment of 1.75 and a partial refund of 1. Leisure travelers strictly prefer the contract with no refund. Business travelers are indifferent between the two contracts so assume they choose refund contract. The monopolist separates the two types and earns an expected profit of 2/3. Double the monopoly profits after values are learned.

Sequential Screening I will analyze both the discrete and continuous setting. The discrete setting is straightforward The continuous setting is trickier. Necessary conditions for IC is straightforward. Sufficient conditions for IC is tricky: easier for FSD, harder for MPS.

Discrete Model A monopolist airline with unit cost c faces two types of travelers, θ {B, L} Proportions of B and L travelers: f B and f L Type B and L travelers value the ticket v B and v L Valuation distributions: v B G B and v L G L Both seller and travelers are risk neutral, and do not discount Multi-dimensional mechanism design problem But consumers are screened twice (sequentially), instead of just once Can be modeled as a static problem in the first period, where travelers choose a package of delivery probabilities and transfer payments contingent on realization of valuations For discrete model, we use indirect mechanisms: advance payment and refund

Timing of the Game period 1 the traveller first privately learns his type θ the seller and the traveller contract at the end of period 1 period 2 the traveller privately learns his actual valuation v for the ticket, and then decide whether to travel. beginning of period 1 type B/L revealed end of period 1 contract signed beginning of period 2 B/L learns v, travel?

Ranking Distributions Consider the following two ways in which B and L are ordered. First-order stochastic dominance (FSD) G B dominates G L by FSD if G B (v) G L (v) for all v [v, v] business travellers stochastically have higher valuations Second-order stochastic dominance (MPS) G B dominates G L by MPS if they have the same mean and v v [G B (s) G L (s)] ds 0 for all v [v, v] business travellers stochastically have higher uncertainty

Refund Contract refund contract (a, k) an advance payment a at the end of period 1 a refund k that can be claimed at the end of period 2 after the traveller learns v under refund contract (a, k) traveller will travel only if v k type θ {B, L} traveller s expected payoff at the end of period 1: a + kg θ (k) + v k vdg θ (v)

Seller s Optimization Problem The seller offers a menu of contracts {(a B, k B ), (a L, k L )} to maximize her revenue: f B [a B k B G B (k B ) c (1 G B (k B ))]+f L [a L k L G L (k L ) c (1 G L (k L ))] subject to v IR B : a B + k B G B (k B ) + vdg B (v) 0 k B IR L : a L + k L G L (k L ) + IC B : a B + k B G B (k B ) + IC L : a L + k L G L (k L ) + v k L vdg L (v) 0 v v k B vdg B (v) a L + k L G B (k L ) + k L vdg L (v) a B + k B G L (k L ) + v k L v vdg B (v) k B vdg L (v)

Reformulation under either FSD or MPS, IR L and IC B implies IR B constraints IR L and IC B are binding, while IC L is redundant seller chooses {(a B, k B ), (a L, k L )} to maximize her revenue f B [a B k B G B (k B ) c (1 G B (k B ))]+f L [a L k L G L (k L ) c (1 G L (k L ))] subject to IR L and IC B.

Reformulation Using IC B and IR L, write the advance payments a as a function of the refund k. Plug back into the seller s problem to get v f B (v c) dg B (v) + k B }{{} max k B,,k L Ŝ(k B ): suplus from type B v v f L (v c) dg L (v) f B [G L (v) G B (v)] dv k } L k {{}} L {{} S(k L ): surplus from type L R(k L ): rent for type B Optimal refund: k B = c and k L arg max [f L S (k) f B R (k)]. k

Optimal Refund Contract under FSD suppose G B dominates G L in first-order stochastic dominance (FSD) optimal contract: k L c excessive refund or under-consumption for the L type intuition under FSD, the rent R (k L ) for the B type is decreasing in k L surplus S (k L ) is increasing for any k L < c, so an increase in k L increases surplus and reduces rent

Optimal Refund Contract under MPS Single mean-preserving spread (MPS): G B crosses G L only once and from above at z, and g B and g L are symmetric around z: G L (v) G B (v) < 0 if v < z G L (v) G B (v) > 0 if v > z. Eg: G B, G L are normal with same mean, different variance. if c < z, subsidize the low type, i.e., insufficient refund k L < c or selling the ticket below c. if c > z, ration the low type, i.e., excess refund k L > c or selling the ticket above c. Intuition: if c < z, rationing is costly because it prevents profitable trade. if c > z, subsidy is costly because it leads to inefficient. trade

Continuous Model ex ante types θ F ( ) with a density function f (θ) each type θ represents a distribution of valuations with pdf g (v θ) and cdf G (v θ). θ could be information about expected valuation (FSD) or the degree of valuation uncertainty (MPS). distributions g (v θ) have the same support for all θ by revelation principle, focus on the direct revelation mechanism {x (θ, v), t (θ, v)} allocation rule x (θ, v) and payment rule t (θ, v) given the report (θ, v)

Seller s Optimization Problem The seller s maximization problem is given by [t (θ, v) x (θ, v) c] g (v θ) f (θ) dvdθ subject to max x(θ,v),t(θ,v) θ v IC 2 : v arg max x (θ, v ) v t (θ, v ) θ, v v IC 1 : θ arg max [x (θ, v) v t (θ, v)] g (v θ) dv θ θ v IR : [x (θ, v) v t (θ, v)] g (v θ) dv 0 θ v

Characterization of IC in Period 2 consumer s ex post surplus after he truthfully reports θ and v: u (θ, v) = x (θ, v) v t (θ, v) expected surplus of a consumer of type θ by reporting truthfully: U (θ, θ) = u (θ, v) g (v θ) dv v second period IC constraints are satisfied if and only if (M) x (θ, v) is nondecreasing in v. (FOC) u (θ, v) = u (θ, v) + v v x (θ, s) ds.

IC in Period 1 rewrite U (θ) as U (θ) = max θ v = max θ v = max θ u (θ, v) g (v θ) dv [ v u (θ, v) + { u (θ, v) + v v v x (θ, s) ds ] g (v θ) dv } [1 G (v θ)] x (θ, v) dv we would like to use FOA to localize the first period IC constraints but local first-order condition and monotonicity are not sufficient

Necessary Conditions for IC in Period 1 first period IC constraints imply that (M) v v [G (v θ ) G (v θ)] [x (θ, v) x (θ, v)] dv 0. (FOC) U (θ) = U (θ) [ θ ] v G(v s) θ v s x (s, v) dv ds. (M) and (FOC) are necessary but not sufficient for IC 1

Seller s Relaxed Program use FOA to obtain a relaxed problem with ICs replaced by FOCs. seller s revenue is rewritten as = θ v θ v θ v θ v U (θ) [t (θ, v) x (θ, v) c] g (v θ) f (θ) dvdθ [ v c + 1 F (θ) f (θ) ] G(v θ) θ x (θ, v) g (v θ) f (θ) dvdθ g (v θ) using integration by parts

Virtual Value Function virtual surplus function J (θ, v) is given by J (θ, v) = v c + 1 F (θ) f (θ) G(v θ) θ g (v θ). informativeness measure: G(v θ) θ /g (v θ) it represents the informativeness of the first-period type on second-period valuations. solution to the relaxed problem with monotone J is { 1 if J (θ, v) 0 x (θ, v) = 0 if J (θ, v) < 0. when is (FOC) also sufficient for the IC constraints in period 1?

Sufficient Conditions for IC1 under FSD strong monotonicity: x (θ, v) is nondecreasing in both arguments. sketch of proof: U (θ) = U (θ, θ ) + v v θ + G (v s) v θ v G (v θ) [x (θ, v) x (θ, v)] dv x (s, v) dsdv s If θ > θ, G (v s) G (v θ) for s [θ, θ], and v θ v x (s, v) v θ x (s, v) G (v s) dsdv G (v θ) dsdv θ s v θ s The case with θ < θ is similar.

Sufficient Conditions for IC1 under MPS harder to find sufficient conditions under MPS additional restriction on distributions all distributions passing through a single point z additional constraints on the allocation rule x (θ, v) if c < z, x (θ, v) is nonincreasing in θ for all v and nondecreasing in v for all θ if c > z, x (θ, v) is nondecreasing in both θ and v one more condition if c < z: no under production if c > z: no over production

FSD Parameterization AR(1) process: v = γθ + (1 γ) ε θ, where γ (0, 1) ε θ is iid with density h ( ) and distribution H ( ). informativeness measure: ( ) ( ) G(v θ) h v γθ θ g (v θ) = 1 γ γ 1 γ ( ) ( ) = γ. h v γθ 1 1 γ 1 γ virtual surplus function J (θ, v) = v c + 1 F (θ) f (θ) G(v θ) θ g (v θ) 1 F (θ) = v c γ. f (θ) monotone in both v and θ if F has increasing hazard rate solution x (θ, v) to the relaxed problem is monotone both in v and θ.

MPS Parameterization suppose v = z + θε θ, where ε θ is iid with zero mean, density h ( ) and distribution H ( ) informativeness measure G(v θ) θ g (v θ) = h virtual surplus function ( v z ) ( θ v z h ( ) ( v z 1 θ θ ) = v z. θ θ 2 ) J (θ, v) = v c+ 1 F (θ) f (θ) G(v θ) θ g (v θ) 1 F (θ) = v c (v z). θf (θ) if F has increasing hazard rate, solution x (θ, v) to the relaxed problem also solves the original problem

Esö and Szentes (2007): Optimal Information Disclosure in Auctions and the Handicap Auction Review of Economic Studies

The Model Single seller with a unit good to sell. n buyers each with single unit demand. Seller s valuation for the good is normalized to 0. Her objective is to maximize expected revenue. Each buyer s pay-off is the negative of his payment to the seller, plus, in case he wins, the value of the object.

Buyer s Valuation Buyer i s true valuation for the object is v i. He private observes a noisy signal θ i of v i. θ i is drawn from F i (commonly known). f i /(1 F i ) is assumed to be nondecreasing. In addition, the seller can disclose an additional noisy signal z i of v i to buyer i. The seller cannot observe this signal. She may also choose to partially reveal z i. z i is allowed to be correlated with θ i. However, (θ i, z i ) is drawn independently across i.

Buyer s Valuation Since buyer is risk neutral, it is without loss to assume v i = E[v i θ i, z i ]. After observing the signal, the buyer knows his posterior value v i. Assume v i is increasing in z i.

Valuation Distribution H iθi denotes the (twice continuously differentiable) distribution of v i conditional on θ i Assumptions on H iθi : 1. 2. 3. H iθi θ i < 0: θ i > ˆθ i = H iθ i First Order Stochastically Dominates H i ˆθi, H iθi (v i )/ θ i h iθi (v i ) is increasing in v i, H iθi (v i )/ θ i h iθi (v i ) is increasing in θ i. Interpretation: Substitutability in i s posterior valuation between θ i and the part of z i that is new to i.

Recap: Courty and Li (2000) Here, the seller does not control information and v i = z i. The seller screens by offering a menu of contracts with different allocations and prices. Can be thought of as a set of option/refund contracts. Optimal allocation rule is given by the cutoff value that solves v + H iθ i (v i )/ θ i h iθi (v i ) 1 F (θ i ) f (θ i ) = 0. As in Myerson, allocations pin down prices.

Orthogonalization Suppose instead of z i, the seller could disclose a new independent signal s i (z i, θ i ), s i is strictly increasing in z i, hence preserves information of z i. Put differently, buyer s posterior valuation is same whether he observes z i or s i (z i, θ i ). Recall, seller cannot observe z i so does not observe s i.

Orthogonalization: Proof Lemma: (i) There exist functions u i and s i, such that u i (θ i, s i (z i, θ i )) := v i, such that u i is strictly increasing, s i is strictly increasing in z i, and s i (z i, θ i ) is independent of θ i. (ii) All s i s satisfying part (i) are positive monotonic transformations of each other. Proof: Define s i (z i, θ i ) := H iθi (v i ), the percentile of the distribution of v i θ i. Pr (H iθi (v i ) y) = Pr ( v i H 1 iθ i (y) ) = H iθi ( H 1 iθ i (y) ) = y. Note that s i is uniform on [0, 1] irrespective of θ i and hence independent of θ i. Finally, define u i (θ i, s i ) := H 1 iθ i (s i ).

Interpretation of Distributional Assumptions Lemma: (i) H iθ i (v i )/ θ i h iθi (v i ) increasing in v i implies u i12 0. (ii) H iθ i (v i )/ θ i h iθi (v i ) increasing in θ i implies u i11 u i1 u i12 u i2. Interpretation: (i) The marginal impact of the s i shock on i s valuation is non-increasing in his type θ i. (ii) An increase in i s type, holding the ex-post valuation constant, weakly decreases the marginal value of θ i.

Benchmark: Seller Observess i Suppose, the seller observes s i. In this benchmark, the revenue must be weakly higher then any unobserved signal structure as this additional information can be ignored. The seller s revenue can be written as a function of the allocation X i : ( u i (θ i, s i ) 1 F (θ ) i) u i1 (θ i, s i ) X i (θ i, s i )df (v)dg(s) f (θ i ) θ i s i Optimal allocation Xi assigns the good to the highest non-negative virtual value (follows from the same arguments as the Myerson auction).

Properties of Optimal Benchmark Allocation Virtual Value: u i (θ i, s i ) 1 F (θ i ) f (θ i ) u i1 (θ i, s i ) Lemma: (i) Xi is continuous in both arguments. (ii) Xi is weakly increasing in both arguments. (iii) If θ i > ˆθ i, s i < ŝ i and u i (θ i, s i ) = u i (ˆθ i, ŝ i ), then Xi (θ i, s i ) Xi (ˆθ i, ŝ i ). These properties imply that Xi can be implemented even when the seller does not observe s i.

Consistent Deviations Lemma: In the second round of an IC two-stage mechanism, θ i who reported ˆθ i in the first round and has observed s i will report ŝ i = σ i (θ i, ˆθ i, s i ) such that u i (θ i, s i ) u i (θ i, σ i (θ i, ˆθ i, s i )) Proof: If true value and signal were ˆθ i, ŝ i, period 2 IC would imply u i (ˆθ i, ŝ i )X i (ˆθ i, ŝ i ) T i (ˆθ i, ŝ i ) u i (ˆθ i, ŝ i )X i (ˆθ i, s i ) T i (ˆθ i, s i ), for all s i. This implies that u i (θ i, s i )X i (ˆθ i, ŝ i ) T i (ˆθ i, ŝ i ) u i (θ i, s i )X i (ˆθ i, s i ) T i (ˆθ i, s i ).

Main Result Theorem: The benchmark mechanism can be implemented by the seller even without observing the buyer s shock. A key reason this works is: θ i > ˆθ i, and u i (θ i, s i ) = u i (ˆθ i, ŝ i ) implies that Xi (ˆθ i, ŝ i ) Xi (θ i, s i ). In words, θ i and a given ex-post valuation wins the object more often than he does with ˆθ i, but the same ex post valuation This provides the appropriate monotonicity which is required for period 1 IC.

Main Result: Intuition Consider the case where n = 1. The benchmark allocation can be implemented by an option contract: a type θ i, gets a period 2 strike price p i (θ i ) = u i (θ i, s i ), where s i solves u i (θ i, s i ) 1 F (θ i) u i1 (θ i, s i ) = 0. f (θ i ) By revenue equivalence, all implementations provide the same revenue (subject to binding IR of the lowest period 1 type). In this implementation, s i will be reported truthfully even if private information.

Li and Shi (2015): Discriminatory Information Disclosure Working Paper

Binary Example This a two type example where discriminatory information disclosure can help. The distributions are is piecewise uniform around.5. 1 1 ε Pr H(v θ L ) H(v θ H ) ε 1/2 1 Value Buyer ex ante type θ {θ H, θ L }, θ H and θ L equally likely. F ( θ H ) and F ( θ L ) both piecewise uniform with ε (0, 1/2):

Binary Example The distributions are is piecewise uniform around.5. 1 1 ε Pr H(v θ L ) H(v θ H ) ε 1/2 1 Value Seller discloses, without observing, a noisy signal s of ω. Seller s reservation value c = 1/2. Total surplus 1/8: (1 ε)/4 from θ H, and ε/4 from θ L.

Sequential Screening: s = v Buyer chooses between two option contracts before learning v: high fee a H for option of buying at efficient price p H = 1/2. low fee a L for option of buying at high price p L > 1/2. Optimal sequential screening IC H and IR L bind: no rent for θ L. seller revenue = trading surplus information rent for θ H. optimal p L = 1/2 + (1 2ε)/(2 2ε), balancing surplus and rent. information rent for θ H : R H = (1 2ε)(1 p L ) 2 > 0. seller revenue: π = (1 ε (1 2ε) / (1 ε)) /8 < 1/8.

Sequential Screening with Information Control Sequential screening with discriminatory disclosure efficient contract for high type, hence full information. inefficient contract for low type and partial information. Optimal menu with discriminatory disclosure charge a H = (1 ε) /4 for full disclosure and set p H = 1/2. charge a L = 0 for binary partition disclosure (whether v 1/2), and set p L = 3/4. θ H indifferent; θ L strictly prefers binary partition. Extract entire trade surplus of 1/8.

Model: Signals Consider a two-period sequential screening model seller has a single object for sale, with reservation value c 0. both parties are risk-neutral, and do not discount. Buyer s underlying true valuation: v Ω = [v, v] t = 1: buyer privately observes signal θ Θ about v (ex ante type). primitive: v θ H (v θ), with CDF F (θ); for θ > θ, H( θ) first-order stochastic dominates H( θ ). Seller controls additional signal about v t = 2: seller can release to buyer, without observing, a signal s. given θ and s, buyer s posterior estimate of v is v. θ and s are correlated.

Model: Signal Structure and Disclosure Policy Signal structure σ S is a joint distribution H σ (v, θ, s) such that dh σ (v, θ, s) = H (v, θ). (consistency) s S where S is the set of possible signal realizations. Disclosure policy, σ (θ) : Θ S, assigns σ to reported type θ. Different classes of disclosure rules, with varying restrictions on the set of signal structures S: direct disclosure: signal does not depend on true type general disclosure: no additional restriction other than consistency classical sequential screening: S = {σ}, σ: perfect signal structure specific technologies: Gaussian, truth-or-noise...

Model: Direct Disclosure Direct disclosure: signal structure σ : Ω S, direct garbling of the perfect signal σ signal distribution under σ: H σ (s v, θ) = Γ σ (s v). Binary partition: partition threshold k (v, v), signal space S = {s, s + }, probability mass function γ σ ( v) corresponding to Γ σ ( v): 1 if s = s and v < k, γ σ (s v) = 1 if s = s + and v k, 0 otherwise, probability of observing s + for a type-θ buyer under σ is 1 H (k θ), which depends on the true type θ.

Model: Mechanism Disclosure policy {σ(θ)} and direct mechanism {x (θ, v), y (θ, v)}: σ(θ) is the signal structure assigned for reported type θ. x (θ, v) is the trading probability conditional on buyer report (θ, v). y (θ, v) is the corresponding payment from buyer to seller.

Model: Timing First period: v is realized, and buyer privately observes θ. seller commits to {σ (θ)} together with {x (θ, v), y (θ, v)}. buyer submits report θ about his type and σ( θ) is implemented. Second period: buyer observes additional signal s σ( θ) released by seller. [ ] buyer forms posterior estimate v = E v θ, s σ( θ) and reports ṽ. contract {x( θ, ṽ), y( θ, ṽ)} is implemented.

Discrete Types Discrete ex ante type Θ = {θ 1,..., θ n }, f i Pr (θ = θ i ). H (v θ i ) H (v θ i+1 ) for all i and all v [v, v] Restrict to deterministic selling mechanisms menu of option contracts { a i, p i} a i is the non-refundable advance payment in period one p i is the corresponding strike price in period two Under full disclosure, a feasible contract { a i, p i} satisfies: IR i : a i + v p i (v p i )dh (v θ i ) 0, i; IC ij : a i + v p i (v p i )dh (v θ i ) a j + v p j (v p j )dh (v θ i ), i, j.

Full Disclosure Not Optimal Proposition If ex ante types are ordered in FOSD, full disclosure (σ i = σ for all i) is not optimal. Idea of proof: take optimal contract ( a i, p i) under full disclosure; for type θ i θ n, keep σ i = σ and strike price p i ; for type θ n, offer binary partition with cutoff p n, raise strike price p n = p n + δ, with δ small and strictly positive, and reduce a n to bind IR 1 ; due to FOSD, price hike hurts deviating θ i more than θ n ; IC i1 are strictly slack, so we can uniformly raise a i ; same allocation (hence surplus), but lower rent.

Discussion: Two Types Monotone partitions need not be optimal The seller may want to pool high low values onto the same signal. General disclosure may dominate direct disclosure. Types get no information if they misreport. If v v vdh(v θ H) v c vdh(v θ L), full surplus extraction is possible. Offer a binary monotone partition around c. Charge both types no upfront fee and a strike price p i = v c vdh(v θ i) for i h, l. It is without loss to restrict to generalized monotone partitions.

Discussion: Contiuous Types Direct disclosure policies are better than full disclosure. Binary partitions are not optimal in general May be too informative for high type.