OVERVIEW of INTERNATIONAL CAPITAL FLOWS

Similar documents
The New Petrodollar Flows

Global Construction 2030 Expo EDIFICA 2017 Santiago Chile. 4-6 October 2017

An Overview of World Goods and Services Trade

Division on Investment and Enterprise

A short history of debt

Foreign Direct Investment in the United States 2013 Preliminary Data. Organization for International Investment (OFII)

Note: G20 includes only the 19 member countries (excludes European Union).

Belgium s foreign trade 2011

Gold and Dollar Flows in 1958

Foreign Investment in U.S. Securities

GLOBAL FDI OUTFLOWS CONTINUED TO RISE IN 2011 DESPITE ECONOMIC UNCERTAINTIES; HOWEVER PROSPECTS REMAIN GUARDED HIGHLIGHTS

Challenges to the International Monetary System: Rebalancing Currencies, Institutions, and Rates

International Statistical Release

Frequently Asked Questions Transparency International 2008 Bribe Payers Index

Sovereign Development Funds and the Shifting Wealth of Nations

Executive Summary. The Transatlantic Economy Annual Survey of Jobs, Trade and Investment between the United States and Europe

PMITM. The world s leading economic indicator

India s International Trade & Investment

Foreign Direct Investment and Ease of Doing Business: Before, During and After the Global Crisis

Where did the Wealth go? - After twenty years of WTO: only 26 countries are beneficiaries of globalization

UPDATE ON FISCAL STIMULUS AND FINANCIAL SECTOR MEASURES. April 26, 2009

Actuarial Supply & Demand. By i.e. muhanna. i.e. muhanna Page 1 of

UK Trade in Numbers. February 2019

TRANSATLANTIC ECONOMY 2018 THE EXECUTIVE SUMMARY. Annual Survey of Jobs, Trade and Investment between the United States and Europe

CRS Report for Congress

Vietnam. HSBC Global Connections Report. October 2013

FEDERAL RESERVE BULLETIN

New in 2013: Greater emphasis on capital flows Refinements to EBA methodology Individual country assessments

Macroeonomics. 18 this chapter, Open-Economy Macroeconomics: look for the answers to these questions: Introduction. N.

Asia-Pacific Trade Briefs: Hong Kong, China

EQUITY REPORTING & WITHHOLDING. Updated May 2016

International Statistical Release

2018 CAPITAL GAINS DISTRIBUTION ESTIMATES

Chapter 5. Saving and Investment in the Open Economy. Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada

Challenges for financial institutions today. Summary

Quarterly Investment Update First Quarter 2017

Global Economic Indictors: CRB Raw Industrials & Global Economy

Global Economic Briefing: Global Liquidity

Quarterly Investment Update First Quarter 2018

Corrigendum. OECD Pensions Outlook 2012 DOI: ISBN (print) ISBN (PDF) OECD 2012

World s Best Investment Bank Awards 2018

Economic Stimulus Packages and Steel: A Summary

STATISTICS Last update: 03/07/2017

H S B C H O L D I N G S P L C HSBC HOLDINGS PLC THE CAPITAL REQUIREMENTS. (Country-by-Country Reporting) REGULATION 2013

Global Styrene Butadiene Rubber (SBR) Market Study ( )

The Capital Requirements (Country-by-Country Reporting) Regulations December 2017

2012 Canazei Winter Workshop on Inequality

Focus on: Hong Kong. International Business Report 2011 Economy focus series

Reporting practices for domestic and total debt securities

Belgium has a small, open economy. Foreign trade is of major importance to the overall

foreign, and hence it is where the prices of many currencies are set. The price of foreign money is

Global FDI Inflows. Global foreign direct investment (FDI) flows fell by 23 % to $1.43 trillion.

Best Treasury & Cash Management Providers 2017

International Statistical Release

International Monetary Fund. World Economic Outlook. Jörg Decressin Senior Advisor Research Department, IMF

EU-28 STEEL SCRAP STATISTICS. by Rolf Willeke Statistics Advisor of the BIR Ferrous Division For EFR a branch of EuRIC (30 October 2017)

EU-ASEAN cooperation - key trade and investment statistics

Financial wealth of private households worldwide

Foreign Exchange Reserves in India

DOMESTIC CUSTODY & TRADING SERVICES

US Economic Indicators: Import Prices, PPI, & CPI

Foreign Direct Investment in the United States. Organization for International Investment

Chinese Outward Investment: Acceleration Features the U.S.

International Monetary Fund

Technological transformation and payment systems

GLOBAL MARKET OUTLOOK

No October 2013

International Statistical Release

All the BRICs dampening world trade in 2015

U.S. Direct Investment Abroad: Trends and Current Issues

Balanced Select Portfolio Pn

5. Openness in Goods and Financial Markets: The Current Account, Exchange Rates and the International Monetary System

Japan's Balance of Payments Statistics and International Investment Position for 2016

Foreign Direct Investment in the United States. Organization for International Investment

Key Issues in the Design of Capital Gains Tax Regimes: Taxing Non- Residents. 18 July 2014

A. Definitions and sources of data

Global Select International Select International Select Hedged Emerging Market Select

Global Business Barometer April 2008

RECENT EVOLUTION AND OUTLOOK OF THE MEXICAN ECONOMY BANCO DE MÉXICO OCTOBER 2003

World Investment Report 2013

Center for Transatlantic Relations Johns Hopkins University Paul H. Nitze School of Advanced International Studies

DIVERSIFICATION. Diversification

Exchange Traded Funds (ETFs): The New Packaged Product of Choice

Appendix: Analysis of Exchange Rates Pursuant to the Act

RUSSIAN ECONOMIC OUTLOOK AND MONETARY POLICY CHALLENGES RUSSIAN ECONOMIC OUTLOOK AND MONETARY POLICY CHALLENGES. Bank of Russia.

US FISCAL ADJUSTMENT AND FURTHER DOLLAR DECLINE REQUIRED TO CURB RISING US EXTERNAL DEBT

Imports. Exports. T135 Figure 18-1 U.S. Exports and Imports as Ratios of GDP, Ratio to GDP

FEDERAL RESERVE BULLETIN

LONG-TERM PROJECTIONS OF PUBLIC PENSION EXPENDITURE

Fiscal Policy and the Global Crisis

The Global Economic Environment. Chapter 2. Dr Inda Sukati Faculty of Management Universiti Teknologi Malaysia

Trade trends and trade policy developments. Ian Ascough Head of Bilateral Trade Negotiations BIS/DfID Trade Policy Unit

Market Correlations: Expected Inflation in TIPS

Stock Market Briefing: S&P 500 Revenues & the Economy

DFA Global Equity Portfolio (Class F) Quarterly Performance Report Q2 2014

Global Imbalances and Latin America: A Comment on Eichengreen and Park

COUNTRY COST INDEX JUNE 2013

Global Exhibition Barometer 13 th edition (July 2014)

Market Briefing: S&P 500 Forward Earnings & the Economy

IOOF. International Equities Portfolio NZD. Quarterly update

Transcription:

OVERVIEW of INTERNATIONAL CAPITAL FLOWS By Mack Ott, CEE, 2008 [Mack Ott is an international economic consultant whose major assignments have been in theformer Soviet Union countries, the Balkans, and Egypt. During 2003 and 2004 he was macroeconomic adviser to the chief economist of Nigeria and to the West African Monetary Institute. He has also been a U.S. Treasury adviser to the Ministry of Finance of Saudi Arabia.] International Capital flows are the financial side of International Trade in Goods and Services. When someone imports a good or service, the buyer (the importer) gives the seller (the exporter) a monetary payment, just as in domestic transactions. If total exports were equal to total imports, these monetary transactions would balance at net zero: people in the country would receive as much in financial flows as they paid out in financial flows. But generally the trade balance is not zero. The most general description of a country s balance of trade, covering its trade in goods and services, income receipts, and transfers, is called its current account balance. If the country has a surplus or deficit on its current account, there is an offsetting net financial flow consisting of currency, securities, or other real property ownership claims. This net financial flow is called its capital account balance. When a country s imports exceed its exports, it has a current account deficit. Its foreign trading partners who hold net monetary claims can continue to hold their claims as monetary deposits or currency, or they can use the money to buy other financial assets, real property, or equities (stocks) in the trade-deficit country. Net capital flows comprise the sum of these monetary, financial, real property, and equity claims. Capital flows move in the opposite direction to the goods and services trade claims that give rise to them. Thus, a country with a current account deficit necessarily has a capital account surplus. In balance of payments accounting terms, the current-account balance, which is the total balance of internationally traded goods and services, is just offset by the capitalaccount balance, which is the total balance of claims that domestic investors and foreign investors have acquired in newly invested financial, real property, and equity assets in each others countries. While all the above statements are true by definition of the accounting terms, the data on international trade and 1

financial flows are generally riddled with errors, generally because of undercounting. Therefore, the international capital and trade data contain a balancing error term called net errors and omissions. Because the capital account is the mirror image of the current account, one might expect total recorded world trade exports plus imports summed over all countries to equal financial flows payments plus receipts. But in fact, during 1996 2001, the former was $17.3 trillion, more than three times the latter, at $5.0 trillion. There are three explanations for this. First, many financial transactions between international financial institutions are cleared by netting daily offsetting transactions. For example, if on a particular day, U.S. banks have claims on French banks for $10 million and French banks have claims on U.S. banks for $12 million, the transactions will be cleared through their central banks with a recorded net flow of only $2 million from the United States to France even though $22 million of exports was financed. Second, since the 1970s, there have been sustained and unexplained balance-of-payments discrepancies in both trade and financial flows; part of these balance-ofpayments anomalies is almost certainly due to unrecorded capital flows. Third, a huge share of export and import trade is intrafirm transactions; that is, flows of goods, material, or semifinished parts (especially automobiles and other nonelectronic machinery) between parent companies and their subsidiaries. Compensation for such trade is accomplished with accounting debits and credits within the firms books and does not require actual financial flows. Although data on such intrafirm transactions are not generally available for all industrial countries, intrafirm trade for the United States in recent years accounts for 30 40 percent of exports and 35 45 percent of imports. The bulk of capital flows are transactions between the richest nations. In 2003, of the more than $6.4 trillion in gross financial transactions, about $5.4 trillion (84 percent) involved the 24 industrial countries and almost $1.0 trillion (15 percent) involved the 162 less-developed countries (LDCs) or economic territories, with the rest, less than 1 percent, accounted for by international organizations. The shares of both industrial nations and the international organizations have been receding from their highs in 1998: 90 percent for 2

industrial nations and 5 percent for the international organizations. In that year the combination of the Russian debt default and ruble devaluation, the south Asia financial crisis, and the lingering uncertainty about financial consequences of the return of Hong Kong to Chinese sovereignty in July 1997 drove the LDC share down to 5 percent of world capital flows.5 In the more tranquil five years following these crises, 1999 2003, LDC financial transactions involving mainland China and Hong Kong averaged 28 percent of the LDC total, and adding Taiwan, Singapore, and Korea brings the share to 53 percent of the developing-country transactions. Of the remaining forty-seven percentage points of developingcountry transactions, Europe (primarily Russia, Turkey, Poland, and the Czech Republic) and the Western Hemisphere (primarily Mexico, Brazil, and Chile) each accounted for about sixteen percentage points, with the Middle East and Africa combining for the remaining sixteen percentage points. Financing Trade in Goods, Services, and Assets Figure 1 shows that most financial flows involve industrial countries whose gross flows (credits plus debits) during 1995 2003 averaged $4.9 trillion per year. Capital flows involving industrial countries comprised about 90 percent of total transactions, with LDCs and international organizations accounting for the remainder. Perhaps more significant, these gross flows were about ten times the net capital flows, reflecting the netting out of the vast majority of financial flows. 3

Figure 1 World Financial Flows While much international trade is financed by offsetting trade flows, ultimately net trade balances must be financed by net financial flows. As Figure 2 shows, the United States has had large current-account deficits, primarily due to its deficit on merchandise trade; the non-u.s. industrial countries have had large trade surpluses; and LDCs, in aggregate, shifted from trade deficits to growing trade surpluses at the end of the twentieth century. Net capital and financial flows finance these net trade imbalances, which, while primarily between industrial counties in gross terms, increasingly flowed, on net, from both developing and non-u.s. industrial countries to the United States. Reflecting their shift from trade deficits to trade surpluses at the end of the twentieth century, LDCs became net suppliers of capital in 1999 (Figure 3). 4

Figure 2 Current Account Balances (CABs) 5

Figure 3 Capital Account Balances (KABs) Figure 2 and Figure 3 contain two glaring anomalies. First, Figure 2 shows that the U.S. current account deficit is far larger than the sum of the current account surpluses of the other industrial countries and the LDCs. This implies that the world has been running a current account deficit with itself, something that is logically impossible because the sum of all transactions across all countries with exports positive and imports negative must be zero. That is, an export from China to France is an import by France from China. Because the world is a closed system (no country trades with Mars), if trade data were accurate, the sum of world trade in goods and services (including income and 6

transfers) would be zero. Yet, according to the recorded data, the world ran a current account deficit averaging more than $95 billion annually during 1995 2003. Combined with estimated errors and omissions, these missing data constitute omitted exports and financial flows well in excess of $100 billion per year. Second, Figure 3 shows that the sum of capital outflows from the non-u.s. industrial countries and LDCs is far smaller than the reported inflow of capital to the United States. Thus, the world ran a substantial capital surplus again, a logical impossibility (no borrowing from Mars). Although there is no agreed-upon explanation for these discrepancies, there are two possible reasons, depending on whether or not U.S. data on earnings from foreign direct investment are accurate. First, if the U.S. data are correct, then, because the sum of the U.S. current account deficit in Figure 2 and its capital account surplus in Figure 3 is close to zero, there must be underreported exports to the United States from the non- U.S. industrial countries and the LDCs, balanced by unreported financial flows from them to the United States. Alternatively, suppose that the U.S. data on foreign direct investment earnings are not accurate, in particular that U.S. net income from its direct investments has been underreported. Reporting these earnings at their higher actual level would result in a reduction of the U.S. current account deficit (due to the increased income from renting capital to foreigners) and an equal reduction of the U.S. capital-account surplus. The available evidence makes the second explanation more likely than the first. Composition of Capital and Financial Flows Trade imbalances are financed by offsetting capital and financial flows, which generate changes in net foreign assets. These payments can be any combination of the following: capital investments portfolio investments in either debt or equity securities 7

direct investment in domestic firms (FDI) including start-ups international foreign exchange reserves As Table 1 shows, industrial countries financed their current account balances primarily with financial flows other than direct investment or reserve flows. Indeed, while the industrial countries were importing capital in the form of other financial flows, they were at the same time exporting capital as investors in the form of foreign direct investment (outflow of capital indicated by minus sign). The flow of net direct investment from industrial countries averaged $115 billion during the nine years shown in Table 1 and was directed primarily to developing countries. These capital outflows were an important component of financing investment in the LDCs, where the foreign direct investment inflows averaged $154 billion, positive numbers indicating an inflow. The difference between the industrial country outflow and the developing country inflow was primarily due to foreign direct investment in the United States, which averaged $36 billion; that is, investors in LDCs were making substantial investments in the United States, much of it reflecting capital flight from insecure financial markets in LDCs to the greater security of property rights in industrial countries. Because financial claims may be short term or long term, real or financial, the key to development is to raise long-term investments as a percentage of capital inflows into LDCs. Foreign direct investment distinguished from portfolio investment by the investor s substantial ownership share (>10 percent) implies a greater commitment to a long-term interest in the investment project and an active interest in managing the project. While the United States has been, along with developing countries, the major recipient of direct investment inflows, it is also a major supplier of foreign direct investment. As Table 1 shows, flows of net investment from industrial countries to LDCs were substantial and were a major impulse to their growth; however, much of industrial and developing country investment was funneled to the United States. Of these capital flows from LDCs to the United States, a substantial share has been purchases of U.S. government debt taken up by LDCs as reserve assets; LDCs central banks buy and hold a great amount of U.S. debt as international 8

reserves to back their domestic currencies. Purchases of such reserve assets, primarily short-term U.S. Treasury bills, amounted to more than $1 trillion during 1997 2003, with $340 billion in 2003 alone. The non-u.s. industrial countries particularly France, JAPAN, the Netherlands, Switzerland, and the United Kingdom have been the primary net investors; these five countries supplied the largest part of direct investment during the period 1995 2003, equivalent to 76 percent of the annual net direct investment of all LDCs over this period. The distribution of this net foreign direct investment (inflows) was not uniform across LDCs. Almost half of total net direct investment in developing countries was invested in three LDCs: China with 26 percent, Brazil with 13 percent, and Mexico with 8 percent. At the other end of the spectrum, the countries of sub-saharan Africa accounted, in total, for only 5 percent of total direct investment in LDCs. Table 1 Current Account Financing ($ Billions) 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 Industrial Countries Current Account Balance Financing Net foreign direct investment 42 33 73 41 186 292 249 276 314 106 115 133 153 172 18 100 77 202 Reserves 78 77 23 7 40 45 27 66 166 Other financial and capital flows 162 205 168 73 282 413 394 496 714 Net errors and omissions 20 47 84 114 116 93 18 77 32 LDCs Current Account Balance Financing Net foreign direct investment 104 88 81 51 52 136 94 148 245 103 120 155 165 191 169 179 136 141 Reserves 112 112 83 48 110 127 129 204 340 Other financial and capital flows 140 100 50 29 94 149 122 86 85 Net errors and omissions 28 20 41 37 38 30 22 5 39 Notes: Capital flows indicate investments and borrowings of all terms, ranging from currency holdings and short-term lending to long-term bonds or equity investments. Capital inflows (borrowings and 9

investments) are indicated by positive numbers while capital outflows (lending and investments) are indicated by negative numbers. Figure 4 Net Foreign Direct Investment Positions of the Largest Industrial Countries Contemporary Versus Historical Capital and Financial Flows Over the past two hundred years, the world s dominant international investors have been the Western European nations, particularly the United Kingdom, the Netherlands, and Switzerland. Capital from these countries was invested in their own and other European colonies and in other developing nations, first in the Western Hemisphere and, more recently, worldwide, particularly in China and Brazil. During the nineteenth century, the British financed the transcontinental 10

railroads in the United States and Canada and built vast agricultural plantations in Africa and Asia. Today, Great Britain and the Netherlands remain, as they have from colonial times, among the largest direct investors in the United States: Britain is largest, followed by Japan, Germany, the Netherlands, and France. After World War I, the United States emerged as the world s predominant direct investor and, in gross terms, remains so. As of 2003, U.S. foreign direct assets were more than twice those of the United Kingdom, the next largest asset holder at $2.7 trillion, while U.S. foreign direct investment liabilities were $2.4 trillion, implying a net FDI position of $300 billion. During the past two decades, the United Kingdom again became the world s largest net foreign direct investor, with about $600 billion in net holdings at exchange rates prevailing in 2003. Following the United Kingdom in order are the United States, Japan, Switzerland, and the Netherlands. As Figure 4 shows, foreign direct investment flows have cumulated to huge international holdings by these five principal investors. 11