Asset Pricing. Chapter XI. The Martingale Measure: Part I. June 20, 2006

Similar documents
Lecture 2: Stochastic Discount Factor

Economics 8106 Macroeconomic Theory Recitation 2

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

ECON 815. Uncertainty and Asset Prices

Basics of Asset Pricing. Ali Nejadmalayeri

Lecture 8: Asset pricing

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

1 Asset Pricing: Replicating portfolios

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Ramsey Asset Taxation Under Asymmetric Information

General Equilibrium under Uncertainty

Consumption-Savings Decisions and State Pricing

Lecture 8: Introduction to asset pricing

Help Session 2. David Sovich. Washington University in St. Louis

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B. Lecture 7

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

Volume 31, Issue 3. The dividend puzzle and tax: a note. Frank Strobel University of Birmingham

Arrow Debreu Equilibrium. October 31, 2015

Chapter 5 Macroeconomics and Finance

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

Problem Set: Contract Theory

( 0) ,...,S N ,S 2 ( 0)... S N S 2. N and a portfolio is created that way, the value of the portfolio at time 0 is: (0) N S N ( 1, ) +...

Practice of Finance: Advanced Corporate Risk Management

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

Slides III - Complete Markets

Fin 501: Asset Pricing Fin 501:

Economia Financiera Avanzada

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Course Handouts - Introduction ECON 8704 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS. Jan Werner. University of Minnesota

Finance: Lecture 4 - No Arbitrage Pricing Chapters of DD Chapter 1 of Ross (2005)

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure

M.I.T Fall Practice Problems

MATH4210 Financial Mathematics ( ) Tutorial 6

Arbitrage and Pricing Theory

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

ECON 581. Introduction to Arrow-Debreu Pricing and Complete Markets. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

1 Dynamic programming

QI SHANG: General Equilibrium Analysis of Portfolio Benchmarking

Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing. 3.1 Arbitrage and risk neutral probability measures

LECTURE 07: MULTI-PERIOD MODEL

Lecture Notes: November 29, 2012 TIME AND UNCERTAINTY: FUTURES MARKETS

Problem Set: Contract Theory

3 Stock under the risk-neutral measure

6: MULTI-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

Completeness and Hedging. Tomas Björk

Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016

Radner Equilibrium: Definition and Equivalence with Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium

Financial Economics: Risk Sharing and Asset Pricing in General Equilibrium c

B6302 Sample Placement Exam Academic Year

Problem Set. Solutions to the problems appear at the end of this document.

LECTURE 12: FRICTIONAL FINANCE

Mathematics in Finance

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

LECTURE NOTES 3 ARIEL M. VIALE

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

Banks and Liquidity Crises in Emerging Market Economies

Cash-in-Advance Model

Foundations of Asset Pricing

Help Session 4. David Sovich. Washington University in St. Louis

Finance 100: Corporate Finance

Forward Risk Adjusted Probability Measures and Fixed-income Derivatives

Homework Nonlinear Pricing with Three Types. 2. Downward Sloping Demand I. November 15, 2010

To have a concrete example in mind, suppose that we want to price a European call option on a stock that matures in six months.

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010

Asset Pricing Implications of Social Networks. Han N. Ozsoylev University of Oxford

Technical Appendix to Asset Prices in a Huggett Economy

14.02 Quiz 1, Spring 2012

14.02 Principles of Macroeconomics Fall 2004

Arbitrage, State Prices and Portfolio Theory Handbook of the Economics of Finance

Mixed Strategies. Samuel Alizon and Daniel Cownden February 4, 2009

1 A tax on capital income in a neoclassical growth model

Homework # 8 - [Due on Wednesday November 1st, 2017]

Hedge Portfolios, the No Arbitrage Condition & Arbitrage Pricing Theory

Macro (8701) & Micro (8703) option

Macro 1: Exchange Economies

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2007

Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics. Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption

Part 1: q Theory and Irreversible Investment

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Assets with possibly negative dividends

Part A: Questions on ECN 200D (Rendahl)

The stochastic discount factor and the CAPM

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

Speculative Trade under Ambiguity

Finance: A Quantitative Introduction Chapter 7 - part 2 Option Pricing Foundations

Public Information and Effi cient Capital Investments: Implications for the Cost of Capital and Firm Values

Information Aggregation in Dynamic Markets with Strategic Traders. Michael Ostrovsky

Competitive Outcomes, Endogenous Firm Formation and the Aspiration Core

Dynamic Asset Pricing Model

FINANCIAL OPTIMIZATION. Lecture 5: Dynamic Programming and a Visit to the Soft Side

One-Period Valuation Theory

The Analytics of Information and Uncertainty Answers to Exercises and Excursions

Option Pricing. Based on the principle that no arbitrage opportunity can exist, one can develop an elaborate theory of option pricing.

Notation: ti y,x R n. y x y i x i for each i=1,,n. y>x y x and y x. y >> x y i > x i for each i=1,,n. y x = i yx

Techniques for Calculating the Efficient Frontier

Transcription:

Chapter XI. The Martingale Measure: Part I June 20, 2006

1 (CAPM) 2 (Risk Neutral) 3 (Arrow-Debreu) ECF 1 (1 + r 1 f + π) ; ECF 2 (1 + r 2 f + ; ECF 3 ECF τ Π τ π)2 (1 + r 3 f ; or + π)3 (1 + rτ f. )τ X θτ Θτ ÊCF τ (1 + rτ f ; )τ q(θ τ )CF (θ τ ), p j,t = E CF j,t+1 cov( CF j,t+1, r M )[ E r M r f σ M 2 ], 1 + r f

Existence of Risk Neutral Probabilities The setting and the intuition 2 dates J possible states of nature at date 1 State j = θ j with probability π j Risk free security q b (0) = 1, q b (1) q b (θ j, 1) = (1 + r f ) i=1,..., N fundamental securities with prices q e (0), q e i (θ j, 1) Securities market may or may not be complete S is the set of all fundamental securities, including bond and linear combination thereof

Existence of Risk Neutral Probabilities Existence of a set of numbers πj RN, Σπj RN = 1 s.t q e i (0) = q e i (0) = π RN 1 1 (1 + r f ) E π RN (qe i (θ, 1)) = ( q e i (θ 1, 1) 1 + r f ) +...+π RN J No solution if: qs e (0) = qk e (0) with 1 (1 + r f ) J j=1 ( q e i (θ J, 1) 1 + r f π RN j q e i (θ j, 1) (1) ), i = 1, 2,..., N, q e k (θ j, 1) q e s (θ j, 1) for all j, and q e k (θ ĵ, 1) > q e s (θĵ, 1) (3) = arbitrage opportunity (2)

Consider a portfolio, P, composed of n b P risk-free bonds and ni P units of risky security i, i = 1, 2,..., N. N V P (0) = np b qb (0) + np i qe i (0), (4) i=1 N V P (θ j, 1) = np b qb (1) + np i qe i (θ j, 1). (5) i=1

A portfolio P in S constitutes an arbitrage opportunity provided the following conditions are satisfied: (i) V P (0) = 0, (6) (ii) V P (θ j, 1) 0, for all j {1, 2,..., J}, (iii) V P (θĵ, 1) > 0, for at least one ĵ {1, 2,..., J}.

{ } J A probability measure πj RN defined on the set of states (θ j, j=1 j = 1, 2,..., J), is said to be a risk-neutral probability measure if (i) j > 0, for all j = 1, 2,..., J, and (7) { q (ii) qi e e } (0) = E i (θ, 1) π RN, 1 + r f π RN for all fundamental risky securities i = 1, 2,..., N in S.

Table 11.1: Fundamental Securities for Example 11.1 Period t = 0 Prices Period t = 1 Payoffs θ 1 θ 2 q b (0): 1 q b (1): 1.1 1.1 q e (0): 4 q e (θ j, 1): 3 7 complete markets no arbitrage opportunities "objective" state probabilities?

Table 11.2: Fundamental Securities for Example 11.2 Period t = 0 Prices Period t = 1 Payoffs θ 1 θ 2 θ 3 q b (0): 1 q b (1): 1.1 1.1 1.1 q1 e (0): 2 qe 1 (θ j, 1): 3 2 1 q2 e (0): 3 qe 2 (θ j, 1): 1 4 6 The solution to this set of equations, «««2 = π RN 3 1 + π RN 2 2 + π RN 1 3 1.1 1.1 1.1 «««3 = π RN 1 1 + π RN 4 2 + π RN 6 3 1.1 1.1 1.1 1 = π RN 1 + π RN 2 + π RN 3. π RN 1 =.3, π RN 2 =.6, π RN 3 =.1,

Table 11.3: Fundamental Securities for Example 11.3 Period t = 0 Prices Period t = 1 Payoffs θ 1 θ 2 θ 3 q b (0): 1 q b (1): 1.1 1.1 1.1 q1 e(0): 2 qe 1 (θ j, 1): 1 2 3 2 = π RN 1 ( ) ( ) ( ) 1 2 3 + π2 RN + π3 RN 1.1 1.1 1.1 1 = π1 RN + π2 RN + π3 RN System indeterminate; many solutions

2.2 π RN 1 = 2π RN 2 + 3π RN 3 1 π RN 1 = π RN 2 + π RN 3, π RN 1 > 0 π RN 2 =.8 2π RN 1 > 0 π RN 3 =.2 + π RN 1 > 0 0 < π RN 1 <.4, (π RN 1, πrn 2, πrn 3 ) {(λ,8 2λ,.2 + λ) : 0 < λ <.4} Risk Neutral probabilities are not uniquely defined!

Table 11.4: Fundamental Securities for Example 11.4 Period t = 0 Prices Period t = 1 Payoffs θ 1 θ 2 θ 3 q b (0): 1 q b (1): 1.1 1.1 1.1 q1 e(0): 2 qe 1 (θ j, 1): 2 3 1 q2 e(0): 2.5 qe 2 (θ j, 1): 4 5 3 an arbitrage opportunity No solution (or solution with π RN i = 0 for some i)

Consider the two-period setting described earlier in this chapter. Then there exists a risk-neutral probability measure on S, if and only if there are no arbitrage opportunities among the fundamental securities. May not be unique! Until now: Fundamental securities in S Now: Portfolio of fundamental securities.

Suppose the set of securities S is free of arbitrage opportunities. Then for any portfolio ˆP in S VˆP(0) 1 = (1 + r f ) E π RN ṼˆP(θ, 1), (8) for any risk-neutral probability measure π RN on S.

Let ˆP be an arbitrary portfolio in S, and let it be composed of n bˆp bonds and n iˆp shares of fundamental risky asset i. In the absence of arbitrage, ˆP must be priced equal to the value of its constituent securities, in other words, VˆP(0) = n bˆpq b (0) + N n iˆp qi e (0) = n bˆp E π RN i=1 ( ) q b (1) 1+r f + N n iˆp E π RN i=1 ( ) q e i (θ,1) 1+r f, for any risk neutral probability measure π RN, n bˆp q b P (1)+ N n iˆp q e i (θ,1) (ṼˆP(θ, ) i=1 = E π RN 1+r f = 1 (1+r f ) E π 1) RN.

What if risk neutral measure is not unique? remains valid: each of the multiple of risk neutral measures assign the same value to the fundamental securities an thus to the portfolio itself!

Proposition 11.3: Consider an arbitrary period t = 1 payoff x(θ, 1) and let M represent the set of all risk-neutral probability measures on the set S. Assume S contains no arbitrage opportunities. If 1 (1 + r f ) E π RN x(θ, 1) = 1 (1 + r f ) Eˆπ RN x(θ, 1) for any π RN, ˆπ RN M, then there exists a portfolio in S with the same t = 1 payoff as x(θ, 1).

Proposition 11.4: Consider a set of securities S without arbitrage opportunities. Then S is complete if and only if there exists exactly one risk-neutral probability measure. Proof Suppose S is complete and there were two risk-neutral probability measures, {πj RN : j = 1, 2,..., J} and { π j RN : j = 1, 2,..., J}. Then there must be at least one state ĵ for which πĵ RN π ĵ RN. Since the market is complete, one must be able to construct a portfolio P in S such that V P (0) > 0, and { V P (θ j, 1) = 0 j ĵ V P (θ j, 1) = 1 j = ĵ.

This is simply the statement of the existence of an Arrow-Debreu security associated with θĵ. But then {πj RN :j = 1, 2,..., J} and { π j RN :j = 1, 2,..., J} cannot both be risk-neutral measures as, by, V P (0) = 1 (1 + r f ) E π RN ṼP(θ, 1) = π RN ĵ π RN ĵ (1 + r f ) (1 + r f ) = 1 (1 + r f ) E π RN ṼP(θ, 1) = V P (0), a contradiction. Thus, there cannot be more than one risk-neutral probability measure in a complete market economy.

: Back to example 11.2. q j (0) = πrn j (1+r f ) π RN 1 =.3, π RN 2 =.6, π RN 3 =.1, q 1 (0) =.3/1.1 =.27; q 2 (0) =.6/1.1 =.55; q 3 (0) =.1/1.1 =.09. Conversely: JX p rf = q j (0), j=1 and thus (1 + r f ) = 1 p rf = 1 JP q j (0) j=1 We define the risk-neutral probabilities {π RN (θ)} according to π RN j = q j (0) JP q j (0) j=1 (9)

Table 11.6 The Exchange Economy of Section 8.3 Endowments and Preferences Endowments Preferences t = 0 t = 1 Agent 1 10 1 2 U 1 (c 0, c 1 ) = 1 2 c1 0 +.9( 1 3 ln(c1 1 ) + 2 3 ln(c1 2 )) Agent 2 5 4 6 U 2 (c 0, c 1 ) = 1 2 c2 0 +.9( 1 3 ln(c2 1 ) + 2 3 ln(c2 2 )) π1 RN =.24, and πrn 2 =.30.54.54. Suppose a stock were traded where q e (θ 1, 1) = 1, and q e (θ 2, 1) = 3. By risk-neutral valuation (or equivalently, using Arrow-Debreu prices), its period t = 0 price must be [ ].24 q e.30 (0) =.54 (1) +.54.54 (3) = 1.14; the price of the risk-free security is q b (0) =.54.

Table 11.7 Initial Holdings of Equity and Debt Achieving Equivalence with Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium Endowments t = 0 Consumption ˆn i e ˆn i b Agent 1: 10 1 / 2 1 / 2 Agent 2: 5 1 3 max(10 + 1q 1 (0) + 2q 2 (0) c 1 1 q 1(0) c 1 2 q 2(0)) +.9( 1 3 c1 1 + 2 3 c1 2 ) s.t. c 1 1 q 1(0) + c 1 2 q 2(0) 10 + q 1 (0) + 2q 2 (0) The first order conditions are c1 1 : q 1(0) = 1 3.0.9 c2 1 : q 2(0) = 2 3.0.9 from which it follows that π1 RN = 1 3 0.9 0.9 = 1 3 while πrn 2 = 2 3 0.9 0.9 = 2 3