An Incomplete Contracts Approach to Financial Contracting

Similar documents
Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

Advanced Macroeconomics I ECON 525a - Fall 2009 Yale University

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 6. Separation of Ownership and Control

Online Appendix. Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 5. Property Rights Theory. The key question we are staring from is: What are ownership/property rights?

Rethinking Incomplete Contracts

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: August 7, 2017

PhD Qualifier Examination

Diskussionsbeiträge des Fachbereichs Wirtschaftswissenschaft der Freien Universität Berlin. The allocation of authority under limited liability

Moral hazard, hold-up, and the optimal allocation of control rights

Course Handouts - Introduction ECON 8704 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS. Jan Werner. University of Minnesota

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 3

Homework 1: Basic Moral Hazard

Practice Problems 1: Moral Hazard

Games of Incomplete Information

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 1

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV

Rent Shifting and the Order of Negotiations

Basic Informational Economics Assignment #4 for Managerial Economics, ECO 351M, Fall 2016 Due, Monday October 31 (Halloween).

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV. If any mistakes or typos are spotted, kindly communicate them to

Homework Nonlinear Pricing with Three Types. 2. Downward Sloping Demand I. November 15, 2010

Homework 3: Asymmetric Information

Revision Lecture Microeconomics of Banking MSc Finance: Theory of Finance I MSc Economics: Financial Economics I

Auctions: Types and Equilibriums

Lecture 3: Information in Sequential Screening

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 3

Where do securities come from

Effects of Wealth and Its Distribution on the Moral Hazard Problem

Microeconomic Theory August 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program

Lecture Notes: November 29, 2012 TIME AND UNCERTAINTY: FUTURES MARKETS

CONTRACT THEORY. Patrick Bolton and Mathias Dewatripont. The MIT Press Cambridge, Massachusetts London, England

Definition of Incomplete Contracts

Theories of the Firm. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Game-Theoretic Approach to Bank Loan Repayment. Andrzej Paliński

General Examination in Microeconomic Theory SPRING 2014

Robust Trading Mechanisms with Budget Surplus and Partial Trade

ECON 4245 ECONOMICS OF THE FIRM

DARTMOUTH COLLEGE, DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 21. Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02. Topic 5: Information

Lecture 7: Ex-ante Vs Ex-post Contracts

Finite Memory and Imperfect Monitoring

Graduate Microeconomics II Lecture 7: Moral Hazard. Patrick Legros

Concentrating on reason 1, we re back where we started with applied economics of information

Auctions That Implement Efficient Investments

ECE 586BH: Problem Set 5: Problems and Solutions Multistage games, including repeated games, with observed moves

Stochastic Games and Bayesian Games

In Diamond-Dybvig, we see run equilibria in the optimal simple contract.

Homework 2: Dynamic Moral Hazard

Theories of the Firm. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India October 2012

Simple Efficient Contracts in Complex Environments

1 Appendix A: Definition of equilibrium

Homework 3. Due: Mon 9th December

Understanding and Solving Societal Problems with Modeling and Simulation

Auctions in the wild: Bidding with securities. Abhay Aneja & Laura Boudreau PHDBA 279B 1/30/14

Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence

Relational Incentive Contracts

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017

Advanced Macroeconomics I ECON 525a - Fall 2009 Yale University

Chapter 7: Portfolio Theory

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms

Comparing allocations under asymmetric information: Coase Theorem revisited

Evaluating Strategic Forecasters. Rahul Deb with Mallesh Pai (Rice) and Maher Said (NYU Stern) Becker Friedman Theory Conference III July 22, 2017

Radner Equilibrium: Definition and Equivalence with Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay

Introduction to Political Economy Problem Set 3

The Optimality of Being Efficient. Lawrence Ausubel and Peter Cramton Department of Economics University of Maryland

Competing Mechanisms with Limited Commitment

MS&E 246: Lecture 5 Efficiency and fairness. Ramesh Johari

Lecture 2: Stochastic Discount Factor

An estimated model of entrepreneurial choice under liquidity constraints

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 3: Strategic Form Games - Solution Concepts

MONOPOLY (2) Second Degree Price Discrimination

A Back-up Quarterback View of Mezzanine Finance

Information and Evidence in Bargaining

Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds and The Real Sector

On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation

Monitoring, Liquidation, and Security Design

Problem Set 3: Suggested Solutions

1 Rational Expectations Equilibrium

Monetary Economics. Lecture 23a: inside and outside liquidity, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014 (not examinable)

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay

Competition and risk taking in a differentiated banking sector

A Theory of the Size and Investment Duration of Venture Capital Funds

ISSN BWPEF Uninformative Equilibrium in Uniform Price Auctions. Arup Daripa Birkbeck, University of London.

Information aggregation for timing decision making.

Incomplete Draft. Accounting Rules in Debt Covenants. Moritz Hiemann * Stanford University. January 2011

How to Sell a (Bankrupt) Company

Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium

University of Konstanz Department of Economics. Maria Breitwieser.

Online Appendix for Debt Contracts with Partial Commitment by Natalia Kovrijnykh

General Equilibrium under Uncertainty

Auctions 1: Common auctions & Revenue equivalence & Optimal mechanisms. 1 Notable features of auctions. use. A lot of varieties.

Incomplete contracts and optimal ownership of public goods

PhD Qualifier Examination

Triparty Contracts in Long Term Financing

Mechanism Design: Single Agent, Discrete Types

d. Find a competitive equilibrium for this economy. Is the allocation Pareto efficient? Are there any other competitive equilibrium allocations?

3. Prove Lemma 1 of the handout Risk Aversion.

Transcription:

Ph.D. Seminar in Corporate Finance Lecture 4 An Incomplete Contracts Approach to Financial Contracting (Aghion-Bolton, Review of Economic Studies, 1982) S. Viswanathan The paper analyzes capital structure from the perspective of control rights - who owns the asset controls it - in a framework of incomplete contracts with wealth constraints. The existence of wealth constraints is a key difference from the original Grossman-Hart (1986) paper. Note that these approaches always lead to debt, never equity. For some recent work on equity financing, see Myers, Journal of Finance, 1998. The Model Setup In this bilateral contracting setting, the two parties are: the entrepreneur/manager: needs setup costs K for a project, has zero wealth, and has all the bargaining power (i.e. he can make a take-it-orleave-it offer); the wealthy investor: needs an expected payoff of K. 1

The timing of the game is as follows: at time t = 0 investment K is taken, at time t = 1 the state θ is realized and the signal s is observed, then an action is taken, and finally at time t = 2, the returns r are realized. Both the entrepreneur (manager) and the investor are risk-neutral, with utility functions U E (r, a, θ) = r + l(a, θ) U I (r, a, θ) = r where r is the realization of the returns and l(a, θ) is a non-monetary payoff to the entrepreneur. Note that in a complete contracts framework, the contract specifies a mapping α : Θ A, so that α(θ) a, where θ Θ and a A. Then this needs to be enforced. Assumption 1: The state of nature θ cannot be contracted on. Ex-post, θ is known, but it is not contractible. Assumption 2: There exists a publicly verifiable signal s that is imperfectly correlated with θ. Assumption 3: All monetary payoffs are verifiable and contractible (i.e. r). Other assumptions: There are two states of nature, so that Θ = {θ g, θ b }; 2

There are two actions in the action set: A = {a g, a b }. These actions are the state-dependent optimal actions, i.e. a g = a (θ g ) and a b = a (θ b ); The signal s {0, 1}. Letting β θ = P [s = 1 θ], we assume that β g = Pr[s = 1 θ = θ g ] > 1 2 β b = Pr[s = 1 θ = θ b ] < 1 2 Given β g and β b defined above, let d( β, (1, 0)) = [ 1 β g + 0 β b ]. Then d measures the degree of contract incompleteness. If d = 0 there is perfect correlation between the state of nature θ and the signal s. If d = 1 there is no correlation. The return r {0, 1} Let yj i denote the expected final-period return in state θ i when action a j is chosen, and lj i the private benefit of the entrepreneur in state θ i when action a j is chosen. It follows that y i j = E(r θ = θ i, a = a j ) = Pr[r = 1 θ = θ i, a = a j ] The First Best qyg g + (1 q)yb b > K (feasibility) yg g + lg g > y g b + lg b (a g when θ g ) yb b + lb b > yg b + lg b (a b when θ b ) 1 where q = Pr[θ = θ g ]. The Contract 2 A contract consists of: (i) Compensation schedule for the entrepreneur/manager t(s, r) 0 t(a, s, r) 0 if actions are verifiable 3

(ii) Control allocation rule Individual control: (α 0, α 1 ) [0, 1] 2 where α s probability that the entrepreneur gets the right to decide what action to choose when s = 1 or s = 0, and (1 α s ) probability that the investor gets control Joint control: (µ I 0, µ I 1) (0, 1) 2 and (µ E 0, µ E 1 ) (0, 1) 2 where µ I s + µ E s > 1 for some s {0, 1}. In the case of joint control, both parties have control in some state of the world, and they have to agree on an action, otherwise they both get zero payoffs. It is assumed that the entrepreneur has all the bargaining power and thus makes a takeit-or-leave-it offer. If the investor accepts, the proposed action is taken; if he rejects, the payoff vector is (0, 0). Non-verifiable Actions Three types of control allocation rules are considered: unilateral control, contingent control and joint control. The latter is shown to be (weakly) dominated. Entrepreneur Control Since there are only two possible returns (r {0, 1}), we can always write: t(s, r) = (t(s, 1) t(s, 0))r + t(s, 0) = t s r + t s the contract is affine with only two states 4

The entrepreneur chooses an action a E (θ i, s) such that: Renegotiation a E (θ i, s) = arg max a j A {t sy i j + t s + l i j} Suppose a contract that specifies (t s, t s) results in entrepreneur s decision that for any θ a g when s = 1 a b when s = 0 Consider the case (θ b, s = 1). In this case, the optimal action is a b. If the contract is not renegotiated, the investor gets: U I = y b g(1 t 1 ) t 1 = y b g (t 1 y b g + t 1) If the contract is renegotiated, the entrepreneur offers the investor y b g(1 t 1 ) t 1 but takes action a b and gets: (y b b + l b b) y b g(1 t 1 ) + t 1 > (y b g + l b g) y b g(1 t 1 ) + t 1 = t 1 y b g + t 1 + l b g 5

A similar argument applies to the case (θ g, s = 0). Implication 1 If the entrepreneur has full control, ex-post renegotiation guarantees achieving the first best. Implication 2 This is optimal if the investor s ex-ante individual rationality constraint can be met. 3 Proposition 1 If private benefits l are comonotonic with (y + l), i.e. if l g g > l g b and l b b > lb g, entrepreneur control is always feasible. 4 Proof. Choose t(s, r) = t s, r the entrepreneur chooses first best because t + l g g > t + l g b t + l b b > t + l b g 5 Now choose t such that [qy g g + (1 q)y b b ] t = K. Feasibility ensures such a t exists. 6 Suppose now that l b b < lb g, i.e. comonotonicity is lost. Define: b (y b b + l b b) (y b g + l b g) > 0 b y y b b y b g > 0 π 1 [qy g g + (1 q)y b b] b b y π 2 qy g g + (1 q)y b g π 3 q[β g y g g + (1 β g )y g g b b y ] + (1 q)[β b y b g + (1 β b )y b b b b y ] 6

7 Proposition 2 Entrepreneur control is feasible and implements the first best solution if and only if max(π 1, π 2, π 3 ) K. If K [max(π 1, π 2, π 3 ), qyg g +(1 q)yb b ] entrepreneur control is not feasible. Example Let Pr[θ = θ g ] = 1 2, yg g = 100, l g g = 150, y g b = 200, lg b = 0, yb b = 50, lb b = 0, yb g = 0, l b g = 49. Restrict attention to contracts of the form t s = 0, t s 1. We can do this because if t s > 0, then we can lower t s, so that the investor s IC is relaxed while incentives are not affected. Then we can reallocate in a way not to affect incentives consider t(s, r) = t s r where t s 1. 7.1 No Renegotiation Note the investor always chooses a g in state θ g. In state θ b, we need t s big enough so t s yb b + lb b t s yg b + lg b t s 50 49 t s 49 50 So for t s = 49 50 payoff is: no renegotiation occurs. Investor s maximum π 1 = 1 1 2 50 100 + 1 1 2 50 500 = 3 2 K < 3 2 7

7.2 Full Renegotiation in state θ b 7.3 In this case the contract is such that t s y b b + l b b < t s y b g + l b g t s y b b < l b g t s < 49 50 7.4 Since t s < 49 50, the entrepreneur chooses a g without renegotiation, yielding a payoff of zero for the investor = on renegotiation, the investor gets zero as well. The ex-ante expected payoffs from the contract for the two parties are: Entrepreneur : ( 1 2 t s100 + 1 2 50) + 1 2 50 Investor : 1 2 (1 t s)100 7.5 Therefore, the investor expected payoff is π 2 = 1 1 100 = 2 50 1 if t s = 49, and π 50 2 = 1100 = 50 if t 2 s = 0 = the range of investments that can be supported in this case is K (1, 50). If K (1, 3 ), full renegotiation yields the 2 same outcome in terms of efficiency as no renegotiation (i.e. the first best is implemented). 7.6 Partial renegotiation in state θ b 7.7 In this case, we have t 1 t 0. By setting t 1 < 49, renegotiation occurs in state θ b only when s = 1, so that a b 50 is implemented after renegotiation. By setting t 0 > 49, 50 the action a b is implemented in θ b when s = 0. With these constraints, the values for t s that maximize investor s payoff are: t 1 = 0, t 0 = 49. The investor s expected payoff 50 is: π 3 = 1 2 [βg 100 + (1 β g )(1 49 50 )100] + 1 2 [βg 0 + (1 β g )(1 49 50 )50] = 50β g + 1 β g + 1 βb 2 8

7.8 As β g 1 and β b 0, π 3 gets larger and we get π 3 50.5 > 50. For K (50, 50.5) only partial renegotiation can occur. Investor Control 8 Proposition 3 When monetary benefits are comonotonic with total revenues (y g g > y g b and y b b > yb g) the first best can be achieved under investor control. 9 Proof: Let t(s, r) = t r. Then: (1 t)y g g > (1 t)y g b π g (a g ) > π g (a b ) q.e.d. 10 Set t such that the investor s participation constraint holds. 11 Without loss of generality, consider now the case when yg g < y g b, so that comonotonicity fails. Set t s = 0. Since (1 t s )yg g < (1 t s )y g b, the investor does not take the first-best action a g in state θ g. 12 When t s < 1, we need to renegotiate (i.e. agree on a payment ˆt s )so that (1 ˆt s )y g g (1 t s )y g b or ˆt s 1 (1 t s ) yg b y g g 9

13 So if yg b y is large or t g g s is small, the entrepreneur s wealth constraint may be violated. We need to ensure that ˆt s 0 or (1 t s ) yg b y g g 1 thus t s 1 yg b y g g 14 Proposition 4 If monetary benefits are not comonotonic with total returns, a necessary and sufficient condition for implementing the first-best action plan under investor control is: π 4 = [qy g g + (1 q)y b b] yg b y g g K 15 Example yb b = 50; yg g = 100 < y g b = 200 Investor control is first-best efficient if π 4 = ( 1 2 200 + 1 2 50)1 2 = 62.5 > K. Contingent Control - Debt 10

16 To analyze this type of control, we assume that neither monetary nor private benefits are comonotonic with total benefits: yg g < y g b and lb b < lb g. Consequently, in state θ b, the investor chooses the first-best, while in state θ g the entrepreneur chooses the firstbest. However, control cannot be made contingent on the state θ, but only on the signal s. If s is highly corrleated with θ, and setting { t(s, r) = 0, the optimal contract will s = 1 Entrepreneur control specify: s = 0 Investor control 17 With no renegotiation of contract and contingent control on s, we have: 17.1 { ag if s = 1 - entrepreneur (efficient) In state θ g, a = a b if s = 0 - investor (inefficient) 17.2 { ag if s = 1 - entrepreneur (inefficient) In state θ b, a = a b if s = 0 - investor (efficient) 18 The investor s expected payoff is: π C = q[β g y g g + (1 β g )y g b ] + (1 q)[βb y b g + (1 β b )y b b] 19 As β g 1 and β b 0, π C approaches the first-best monetary payoff π C > π 1, π C > π 2. 20 As β g 1 and β b 0, π 3 approaches the first best monetary payoff as well, but π C π 3 = q(1 β g )(y b g y g g b b y ) + (1 q)(1 β b )(1 b b )yb b y 11

21 Now b < 1 since l b b y b < lg b and yg g < y g b, so π C > π 3 as β g 1 and β b 0 there exist values for K for which contingent control is feasible but entrepreneurial control is not. Suppose π 4 < K (so the condition for Proposition 4 does not hold). Then investor control achieves a b in state θ g, not the firstbest. Under contingent control, as β g 1 and β b 0 the first-best is implemented. 22 Proposition 5 When neither monetary nor private benefits are comonotonic with total benefits, there exist values of K such that: 22.1 (i) entrepreneur control is not feasible 22.2 (ii) investor control is not first-best efficient 22.3 (iii) contingent control ( α 0 = 0, α 1 = 1) dominates when (β g, β b ) (1, 0). 23 The alternative of joint control/ownership exhibits the ex-post hold-up problem as either party has veto power. Examples include joint ventures and alliances. The intruments that implement the control structures discussed in the paper are: Entrepreneur control Preffered stock Investor control Equity voting Contingent control Debt Joint control Partnership 24 Venture Capital applications seem to be consistent. 12