Dynamic Trading with Predictable Returns and Transaction Costs. Dynamic Portfolio Choice with Frictions. Nicolae Gârleanu

Similar documents
Dynamic Portfolio Choice with Frictions

Dynamic Trading with Predictable Returns and Transaction Costs

Dynamic Trading with Predictable Returns and Transaction Costs

Dynamic Trading with Predictable Returns and Transaction Costs

Dynamic Portfolio Choice with Frictions

Dynamic Portfolio Choice with Frictions

Multiperiod Portfolio Optimization with Multiple Risky Assets and General Transaction Costs

Multiperiod Portfolio Optimization with Many Risky Assets and General Transaction Costs

Carry. Ralph S.J. Koijen, London Business School and NBER

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

Multiperiod Portfolio Optimization with Many Risky Assets and General Transaction Costs

VALUE AND MOMENTUM EVERYWHERE

Liquidity Regimes and Optimal Dynamic Asset Allocation

Non-Time-Separable Utility: Habit Formation

Dynamic Portfolio Choice II

Liquidity Regimes and Optimal Dynamic Asset Allocation

Should Norway Change the 60% Equity portion of the GPFG fund?

Portfolio Management and Optimal Execution via Convex Optimization

What Can Rational Investors Do About Excessive Volatility and Sentiment Fluctuations?

MULTIPERIOD PORTFOLIO SELECTION WITH TRANSACTION AND MARKET-IMPACT COSTS

A Macroeconomic Framework for Quantifying Systemic Risk. June 2012

Discussion The Changing Relationship Between Commodity Prices and Prices of Other Assets with Global Market Integration by Barbara Rossi

Dynamic Asset Allocation with Predictable Returns and Transaction Costs

Lecture 2. (1) Permanent Income Hypothesis. (2) Precautionary Savings. Erick Sager. September 21, 2015

Parameter Uncertainty in Multiperiod Portfolio. Optimization with Transaction Costs

1 Dynamic programming

Supplementary online material to Information tradeoffs in dynamic financial markets

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

Resolution of a Financial Puzzle

Parameter Uncertainty in Multiperiod Portfolio Optimization with Transaction Costs

Risk-Adjusted Capital Allocation and Misallocation

LECTURE 12: FRICTIONAL FINANCE

Directory. The Value of Life and the Rise in Health Spending p.1/34

Dynamic Portfolio Choice with Transaction Costs and Return Predictability: Linear Rebalancing Rules

Optimal Trading Strategy With Optimal Horizon

Asset Pricing with Heterogeneous Consumers

Optimization Models for Quantitative Asset Management 1

Commitments of Traders: Commodities

Return Decomposition over the Business Cycle

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

Liquidity and Risk Management

Internet Appendix for Infrequent Rebalancing, Return Autocorrelation, and Seasonality

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Optimal Execution: IV. Heterogeneous Beliefs and Market Making

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

Implementing an Agent-Based General Equilibrium Model

Strategic Asset Allocation with Predictable Returns and Transaction Costs

Pricing and Hedging of Oil Futures - A Unifying Approach -

Macroeconomics I Chapter 3. Consumption

OVERVIEW OF THE BACHE COMMODITY INDEX SM

Supply Contracts with Financial Hedging

Term Premium Dynamics and the Taylor Rule. Bank of Canada Conference on Fixed Income Markets

Growth Opportunities, Investment-Specific Technology Shocks and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

Dynamic Asset Pricing Models: Recent Developments

Comparing Different Regulatory Measures to Control Stock Market Volatility: A General Equilibrium Analysis

Multi-period Portfolio Choice and Bayesian Dynamic Models

Credit and hiring. Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California, visiting EIEF Qi Sun University of Southern California.

Liquidity Creation as Volatility Risk

Discussion of "The Banking View of Bond Risk Premia" by Haddad & Sraer

Ferreting out the Naïve One: Positive Feedback Trading and Commodity Equilibrium Prices. Jaap W. B. Bos Paulo Rodrigues Háng Sūn

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions

Comovement and the. London School of Economics Grantham Research Institute. Commodity Markets and their Financialization IPAM May 6, 2015

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Commodity Co-movement, Producer Diversification, and Output Volatility

TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES. Lucas Island Model

A Macroeconomic Framework for Quantifying Systemic Risk

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO SELECTION WITH TRANSACTION COSTS WHEN AN ILLIQUID ASSET PAYS CASH DIVIDENDS

Toward A Term Structure of Macroeconomic Risk

A simple wealth model

What is Cyclical in Credit Cycles?

Booms and Busts in Asset Prices. May 2010

Signal or noise? Uncertainty and learning whether other traders are informed

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Betting Against Beta

TAKE-HOME EXAM POINTS)

Arbitrageurs, bubbles and credit conditions

Term Premium Dynamics and the Taylor Rule 1

A Macroeconomic Framework for Quantifying Systemic Risk

A Multifrequency Theory of the Interest Rate Term Structure

Labor income and the Demand for Long-Term Bonds

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES STRATEGIC ASSET ALLOCATION IN A CONTINUOUS-TIME VAR MODEL. John Y. Campbell George Chacko Jorge Rodriguez Luis M.

Futures Markets, Oil Prices, and the Intertemporal Approach to the Current Account

Dynamic Portfolio Choice with Linear Rebalancing Rules

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan

Chapter 5 Macroeconomics and Finance

Monetary Economics Final Exam

Notes on Macroeconomic Theory II

Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

The Cross-Section and Time-Series of Stock and Bond Returns

Inflation & Welfare 1

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

Optimal Order Placement

Why Surplus Consumption in the Habit Model May be Less Pe. May be Less Persistent than You Think

On the Optimality of Financial Repression

Liquidity Creation as Volatility Risk

Transcription:

Dynamic Trading with Predictable Returns and Transaction Costs Dynamic Portfolio Choice with Frictions Nicolae Gârleanu UC Berkeley, CEPR, and NBER Lasse H. Pedersen New York University, Copenhagen Business School, AQR Capital Management, CEPR, and NBER

Motivation: Dynamic Trading Active investors e.g., hedge funds, mutual funds, proprietary traders, individuals, other asset managers try to predict returns minimize transactions costs minimize risk Dynamic problem: investor trades now and in the future Key research questions: What is the optimal trading strategy? Does it work empirically?

Motivating Example An investor makes the following predictions: Based on strong fundamentals (low M/B, P/E, low accruals, high and stable earnings, etc.) the annualized expected excess return (alpha) on Centurytel Inc. is 10%. this alpha is expected to last for 2 years Based on recent catalysts, improving fundamentals and pricing, the annualized alpha of Treehouse Foods Inc. is also 10% this alpha is expected to last for half a year Based on recent demand pressure from funds with outflow, the annualized alpha of HJ Heinz Co. is -12% this alpha is expected to last for 2 weeks These and other signals are collected for numerous securities All these stocks are positively correlated The investor has estimated the trading cost (incl. market impact) for these stocks based on past experience The investor makes a similar analysis every day

Results: Aim in Front of the Target Closed-form optimal dynamic trading strategy

Results: Aim in Front of the Target Closed-form optimal dynamic trading strategy Two portfolio principles: 1. Aim in front of the target 2. Trade partially towards the current aim

Results: Aim in Front of the Target Closed-form optimal dynamic trading strategy Two portfolio principles: 1. Aim in front of the target 2. Trade partially towards the current aim Aim portfolio : Weighted average of current and future expected Markowitz portfolios Predictors with slower mean reversion: more weight Application topanel commodity A: Construction futures: of superior Current net Optimal returns Trade Markowitz t Position in asset 2 old position x t 1 new position x t E t (aim t+1 ) aim t Position in asset 1

Results: Aim in Front of the Target Closed-form optimal dynamic trading strategy Two portfolio principles: 1. Aim in front of the target 2. Trade partially towards the current aim Aim portfolio : Weighted average of current and future expected Markowitz portfolios Predictors with slower mean reversion: more weight Application topanel commodity A: Construction futures: of superior Current net Optimal returns Trade Markowitz t Position in asset 2 old position x t 1 new position x t E t (aim t+1 ) aim t Position in asset 1

Figure 1. Aim in front of the target. Panels A C show the optimal portfolio choice with two securities. The Markowitz portfolio is the current optimal portfolio in the absence of transaction costs: the target for an investor. It is a moving target, and the solid curve shows how it is expected to mean-revert over time (toward the origin, which could be the market portfolio). Panel A shows Aim in Front ofdynamic the Trading Target: with Predictable Finance Returns and Transaction Beyond Costs 2311 Panel A. Constructing the current optimal portfolio Panel D. Skate to where the puck is going to be Markowitz t Position in asset 2 old position x t 1 new position aim t x t E t (aim t+1 ) Position in asset 1 Panel B. Expected optimal portfolio next period Panel E. Shooting: lead the duck Position in asset 2 x t 1 x t Et (x t+1 ) E t (Markowitz t+1 ) Position in asset 1 Panel C. Expected future path of optimal portfolio Panel F. Missile systems: lead homing guidance Position in asset 2 E t (x t+h ) E t (Markowitz t+h ) Position in asset 1

Related Literature Optimal trading with transactions costs, no predictability Constantinides (86), Amihud and Mendelson (86), Vayanos (98), Liu (04) Predictability, no transactions costs Merton (73), Campbell and Viceira (02) Optimal trade execution with exogenous trade: Perold (88), Almgren and Chriss (00) Numerical results with time-varying investment opportunity set Jang, Koo, Liu, and Loewenstein (07), Lynch and Tan (08) Quadratic programming Used in macroeconomics (Ljungqvist and Sargent (04)) and other fields: solve up to Ricatti equations Grinold (06)

Outline of Talk Basic model Optimal portfolio strategy: Aim in front of the target Persistent price impact Application: Commodity futures

Discrete-Time Model Returns: r s t+1 = k Risk: var t (u t+1 ) = Σ β sk f k t }{{} =E t(r s t+1 ) +u s t+1 Alpha decay: f k t+1 = j Φkj f j t + ε t+1 Transaction costs:whatever TC( x t ) = 1 2 x t Λ x t Assumption A:whatever Λ = λσ Objective: max xt E t (1 ρ)t+1 ( x t r t+1 γ 2 x t Σx t ) (1 ρ) t 2 x t Λ x t

Solution Method: Dynamic Programming Introduce value function V that solves the Bellman equation: { V (x t 1, f t) = max 1 ( x t 2 x t Λ x t + (1 ρ) xt E t(r t+1 ) γ ) } 2 x t Σx t + E t[v (x t, f t+1 )] Proposition The model has a unique solution and the value function is given by V (x t, f t+1 ) = 1 2 x t A xx x t + x t A xf f t+1 + 1 2 f t+1a ff f t+1 + A 0. The coefficient matrices A xx, A xf, A ff can be solved explicitly and A xx is positive definite.

Trade Partially Towards the Aim Proposition (Trade Partially Towards the Aim) i)the optimal dynamic portfolio x t is: x t = x t 1 + Λ 1 A xx (aim t x t 1 ) with trading rate Λ 1 A xx and aim t = A 1 xx A xf f t

Trade Partially Towards the Aim Proposition (Trade Partially Towards the Aim) i)the optimal dynamic portfolio x t is: x t = x t 1 + Λ 1 A xx (aim t x t 1 ) with trading rate Λ 1 A xx and aim t = A 1 xx A xf f t ii) Under Assumption A, the trading rate is the scalar a/λ = (γ + λρ) + (γ + λρ) 2 + 4γλ(1 ρ) 2(1 ρ)λ < 1 The trading rate is decreasing in transaction costs λ and increasing in risk aversion γ.

What is the Target and What is the Aim? What is the moving target, i.e., the optimal position in the absence of transaction costs? Markowitz t = (γσ) 1 Bf t What is the aim portfolio?

Aim in Front of the Target Proposition (Aim in Front of the Target) (i) The aim portfolio is the weighted average of the current Markowitz portfolio and the expected future aim portfolio. Under Assumption A, letting z = γ/(γ + a): aim t = z Markowitz t + (1 z) E t (aim t+1 ). (ii) The aim portfolio is the weighted average of the current and future expected Markowitz portfolios. Under Assumption A, aim t = z(1 z) τ t E t (Markowitz τ ) τ=t The weight of the current Markowitz portfolio z decreases with transaction costs λ and increases in risk aversion γ.

Aim in Front of the Target: Illustration Panel A: Construction of Current Optimal Trade Markowitz t Position in asset 2 old position x t 1 new position x t target t E t (target t+1 ) Position in asset 1

Aim in Front of the Target: Illustration Panel B: Expected Next Optimal Trade Position in asset 2 x t 1 x t E t (x t+1 ) E t (Markowitz t+1 ) Position in asset 1

Aim in Front of the Target: Illustration Panel C: Expected Evolution of Portfolio Position in asset 2 E t (x t+h ) E t (Markowitz t+h ) Position in asset 1

Weight Signals Based on Alpha Decay Proposition (Weight Signals Based on Alpha Decay) (i) Under Assumption A, the aim portfolio is: ( aim t = (γσ) 1 B I + a ) 1 γ Φ f t (ii) If the matrix Φ is diagonal, Φ = diag(φ 1,..., φ K ), then the aim portfolio is: ( aim t = (γσ) 1 B f 1 t 1 + φ 1 a/γ,..., ft K 1 + φ K a/γ I.e., the aim pf. is the Markowitz pf. with factors f k t scaled down based on their own alpha decay given by Φ. )

Weight Signals Based on Alpha Decay: Illustration Panel A: Construction of Current Optimal Trade Markowitz t Position in asset 2 old position x t 1 new position x t E t (aim t+1 ) aim t Position in asset 1

Position Homing In Proposition (Position Homing In) Suppose that the agent has followed the optimal trading strategy from time until time t. Then the current portfolio is an exponentially weighted average of past aim portfolios. Under Assumption A, x t = t τ= a λ (1 a λ )t τ aim τ (1)

Example: Timing a Single Security A security has risk Σ = σ 2 and return The optimal strategy is r t+1 = k β k f k t }{{} =E t(r t+1 ) +u t+1 x t = ( 1 a ) x t 1 + a λ λ 1 γσ 2 K i=1 β i 1 + φ i a/γ f i t.

Example: Relative-Value Trades w/ Security Characteristics Each security s (e.g., IBM) has its own characteristics ft i,s (e.g., its value and momentum) and characteristics predict returns for all securities, with the same coefficients: E t (r s t+1) = i β i f i,s t Each characteristic has the same mean-reversion speed for all securities f i,s t+1 = φi ft i,s + ε i,s t+1.

Example: Relative-Value Trades w/ Security Characteristics Each security s (e.g., IBM) has its own characteristics ft i,s (e.g., its value and momentum) and characteristics predict returns for all securities, with the same coefficients: E t (r s t+1) = i β i f i,s t Each characteristic has the same mean-reversion speed for all securities f i,s t+1 = φi ft i,s + ε i,s t+1. The optimal characteristic-based strategy is x t = ( 1 a ) x t 1 + a I β i λ λ (γσ) 1 1 + φ i a/γ f t i. i=1

Example: Static Model When the future is completely discounted (ρ = 1), objective is max (x t E t (r t+1 ) γ2 x t Σx t λ2 ) x t Σ x t x t

Example: Static Model When the future is completely discounted (ρ = 1), objective is max (x t E t (r t+1 ) γ2 x t Σx t λ2 ) x t Σ x t x t Solution x t = λ γ + λ x t 1 + γ γ + λ (γσ) 1 E t (r t+1 ). No choice of γ, λ recovers the dynamic solution.

Example: Signals (Equally) Valuable for K Days Suppose: All factors equally good B = (β,..., β) Today s yesterday is tomorrow s day-before-yesterday: ft+1 1 = ε 1 t+1 ft+1 k = ft k 1 for k > 1

Example: Signals (Equally) Valuable for K Days Suppose: All factors equally good B = (β,..., β) Today s yesterday is tomorrow s day-before-yesterday: Optimal strategy: x t = ft+1 1 = ε 1 t+1 ft+1 k = ft k 1 for k > 1 ( 1 a ) x t 1 + a λ λ where z = a/(a + γ) < 1. β σ 2 (1 z) k ( 1 z K+1 k) f k t, More weight to recent signals even if they don t predict better.

Persistent Transaction Costs Model Proposition With temporary and persistent transaction costs, the optimal portfolio x t is x t = x t 1 + M rate (aim t x t 1 ), which tracks an aim portfolio, aim t = M aim y t, that depends on the return-predicting factors and the price distortion.

Persistent Transaction Costs Model Panel A: Only Transitory Cost Position in asset 2 E t (x t+h ) E t (Markowitz t+h ) Position in asset 1 Panel B: Persistent and Transitory Cost Position in asset 2 E t (x t+h ) E t (Markowitz t+h ) Position in asset 1 Panel C: Only Persistent Cost Position in asset 2 E t (x t+h ) E t (Markowitz t+h ) Position in asset 1

Application: Dynamic Trading of Commodity Futures Data on liquid futures without tight price limits 01/01/1996 01/23/2009: Aluminum, Copper, Nickel, Zinc, Lead, Tin from London Metal Exchange (LME) Gas Oil from the Intercontinental Exchange (ICE) WTI Crude, RBOB Unleaded Gasoline, Natural Gas from New York Mercantile Exchange (NYMEX) Gold, Silver is from New York Commodities Exchange (COMEX) Coffee, Cocoa, Sugar from New York Board of Trade (NYBOT)

Predicting Returns and Other Parameter Estimates Pooled panel regression: rrrt+1 s = 0.001 + 10.32 f 5D,s t + 122.34 ft 205.59 ft + ut+1 s (0.17) (2.22) (2.82) ( 1.79) Alpha decay: f 5D,s 1Y,s t+1 = 0.2519ft 5D,s + ε 5D,s 1Y,s 1Y,s ft+1 = 0.0034ft + ε 5Y,s 5Y,s ft+1 = 0.0010ft + ε t+1 1Y,s t+1 5Y,s t+1 Risk: Σ estimated using daily price changes Absolute risk aversion: γ = 10 9 Time discount rate: ρ = 1 exp( 0.02/260) Transactions costs: λ = 3 10 7, as well as λ high = 10 10 7 5Y,s

Performance of Trading Strategies Before and After TCs Panel A: Benchmark Transaction Costs Panel B: High Transaction Costs Gross SR Net SR Gross SR Net SR Markowitz 0.83-9.38 0.83-10.11 Dynamic optimization 0.63 0.60 0.58 0.53 Static optimization Weight on Markowitz = 10% 0.63 0.00 0.63-1.45 Weight on Markowitz = 9% 0.62 0.10 0.62-1.10 Weight on Markowitz = 8% 0.62 0.20 0.62-0.78 Weight on Markowitz = 7% 0.62 0.29 0.62-0.49 Weight on Markowitz = 6% 0.62 0.36 0.62-0.22 Weight on Markowitz = 5% 0.61 0.43 0.61 0.00 Weight on Markowitz = 4% 0.60 0.48 0.60 0.19 Weight on Markowitz = 3% 0.58 0.51 0.58 0.33 Weight on Markowitz = 2% 0.52 0.49 0.52 0.39 Weight on Markowitz = 1% 0.36 0.34 0.36 0.31

Positions in Crude and Gold Futures 6 x Position in Crude 104 Markowitz Optimal 4 1.5 x Position in Gold 105 Markowitz Optimal 1 2 0.5 0 0 2 0.5 4 1 6 1.5 8 09/02/98 05/29/01 02/23/04 11/19/06 2 09/02/98 05/29/01 02/23/04 11/19/06

Optimal Trading in Response to Shock to 5-Day Return-Predicting Signal 3.5 x 104 Optimal Trading After Shock to Signal 1 (5 Day Returns) 3 Markowitz Optimal Optimal (high TC) 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70

Optimal Trading in Response to Shock to 1-Year Return-Predicting Signal 3.5 4 x 105 Optimal Trading After Shock to Signal 2 (1 Year Returns) 3 Markowitz Optimal Optimal (high TC) 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 0 50 100 150 200 250 300

Optimal Trading in Response to Shock to 5-Year Return-Predicting Signal 1 0 x 105 Optimal Trading After Shock to Signal 3 (5 Year Returns) Markowitz Optimal Optimal (high TC) 2 3 4 5 6 7 0 100 200 300 400 500 600 700 800

New paper: Dynamic Portfolio Choice with Frictions What s different in this paper: Continuous time Micro foundation for transaction costs Connection between discrete and continuous time What happens when trading becomes more frequent? Generalized factor dynamics and return dynamics, including stochastic volatility Equilibrium implications

Conclusion: Aim in Front of the Target Derive the closed-form optimal dynamic portfolio strategy 1. Aim in front of the target 2. Trade partially towards the current aim at constant rate 3. Give more weight to persistent factors Superior net returns in application