The Fallacy of Large Numbers

Similar documents
The Fallacy of Large Numbers and A Defense of Diversified Active Managers

INVESTMENTS Lecture 2: Measuring Performance

Characterization of the Optimum

u (x) < 0. and if you believe in diminishing return of the wealth, then you would require

Time Observations Time Period, t

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary

Portfolio Sharpening

Models of Asset Pricing

Economics 483. Midterm Exam. 1. Consider the following monthly data for Microsoft stock over the period December 1995 through December 1996:

CHAPTER 9: THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL

Risk, return, and diversification

Mathematics of Finance Final Preparation December 19. To be thoroughly prepared for the final exam, you should

P2.T8. Risk Management & Investment Management. Jorion, Value at Risk: The New Benchmark for Managing Financial Risk, 3rd Edition.

Using Monte Carlo Integration and Control Variates to Estimate π

The misleading nature of correlations

Mean Variance Analysis and CAPM

OPTIMAL RISKY PORTFOLIOS- ASSET ALLOCATIONS. BKM Ch 7

Sample Midterm Questions Foundations of Financial Markets Prof. Lasse H. Pedersen

Probability. An intro for calculus students P= Figure 1: A normal integral

Week 2 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Hypothesis Testing and Confidence Intervals

CHAPTER 9: THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV

General Notation. Return and Risk: The Capital Asset Pricing Model

Risk and Return and Portfolio Theory

MS-E2114 Investment Science Lecture 5: Mean-variance portfolio theory

ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Tuesday October 6 Portfolio Allocation Mean-Variance Approach

18.440: Lecture 32 Strong law of large numbers and Jensen s inequality

Data Analysis and Statistical Methods Statistics 651

Markowitz portfolio theory

Chapter. Diversification and Risky Asset Allocation. McGraw-Hill/Irwin. Copyright 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.

Ch. 8 Risk and Rates of Return. Return, Risk and Capital Market. Investment returns

Performance Measurement and Attribution in Asset Management

Testing Capital Asset Pricing Model on KSE Stocks Salman Ahmed Shaikh

Optimal Portfolio Inputs: Various Methods

Extend the ideas of Kan and Zhou paper on Optimal Portfolio Construction under parameter uncertainty

Risk aversion, Under-diversification, and the Role of Recent Outcomes

Maximum Likelihood Estimation Richard Williams, University of Notre Dame, Last revised January 13, 2018

Market Liquidity and Performance Monitoring The main idea The sequence of events: Technology and information

Random Variables and Applications OPRE 6301

Does Portfolio Theory Work During Financial Crises?

Appendix to: AMoreElaborateModel

The Effects of Responsible Investment: Financial Returns, Risk, Reduction and Impact

From optimisation to asset pricing

Portfolio Management

FINC3017: Investment and Portfolio Management

LECTURE NOTES 3 ARIEL M. VIALE

EQUITY RESEARCH AND PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT

Behavioral Finance 1-1. Chapter 2 Asset Pricing, Market Efficiency and Agency Relationships

Expected Value of a Random Variable

University 18 Lessons Financial Management. Unit 12: Return, Risk and Shareholder Value

Investment In Bursa Malaysia Between Returns And Risks

The Case for TD Low Volatility Equities

Maximum Likelihood Estimation Richard Williams, University of Notre Dame, Last revised January 10, 2017

Chapter 8. Markowitz Portfolio Theory. 8.1 Expected Returns and Covariance

Session 10: Lessons from the Markowitz framework p. 1

Econ 250 Fall Due at November 16. Assignment 2: Binomial Distribution, Continuous Random Variables and Sampling

Risk and Return. Nicole Höhling, Introduction. Definitions. Types of risk and beta

Edgeworth Binomial Trees

Advanced Financial Economics Homework 2 Due on April 14th before class

THEORY & PRACTICE FOR FUND MANAGERS. SPRING 2011 Volume 20 Number 1 RISK. special section PARITY. The Voices of Influence iijournals.

MTH6154 Financial Mathematics I Stochastic Interest Rates

RETURN AND RISK: The Capital Asset Pricing Model

The Markowitz framework

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India October 2012

BUSM 411: Derivatives and Fixed Income

Module 6 Portfolio risk and return

FIN 6160 Investment Theory. Lecture 7-10

Leverage Aversion, Efficient Frontiers, and the Efficient Region*

CHAPTER 5 STOCHASTIC SCHEDULING

Active Portfolio Management. A Quantitative Approach for Providing Superior Returns and Controlling Risk. Richard C. Grinold Ronald N.

Application to Portfolio Theory and the Capital Asset Pricing Model

Modelling the Sharpe ratio for investment strategies

Diversification. Chris Gan; For educational use only

Yao s Minimax Principle

Portfolio Management

Efficient Frontier and Asset Allocation

Portfolio selection: the power of equal weight

Martingales, Part II, with Exercise Due 9/21

2. ANALYTICAL TOOLS. E(X) = P i X i = X (2.1) i=1

Portfolio Theory and Diversification

+ = Smart Beta 2.0 Bringing clarity to equity smart beta. Drawbacks of Market Cap Indices. A Lesson from History

Traditional Optimization is Not Optimal for Leverage-Averse Investors

5.7 Probability Distributions and Variance

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms

Derivation of zero-beta CAPM: Efficient portfolios

15 Week 5b Mutual Funds

Stock Price Behavior. Stock Price Behavior

QR43, Introduction to Investments Class Notes, Fall 2003 IV. Portfolio Choice

Topic Nine. Evaluation of Portfolio Performance. Keith Brown

1 Describing Distributions with numbers

Social Value of Public Information: Morris and Shin (2002) Is Actually Pro Transparency, Not Con

FORMAL EXAMINATION PERIOD: SESSION 1, JUNE 2016

Why Indexing Works. October Abstract

Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

Chapter 14 : Statistical Inference 1. Note : Here the 4-th and 5-th editions of the text have different chapters, but the material is the same.

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

Principles of Finance Risk and Return. Instructor: Xiaomeng Lu

Monetary Economics Measuring Asset Returns. Gerald P. Dwyer Fall 2015

Note on Cost of Capital

Transcription:

The Fallacy of Large umbers Philip H. Dybvig Washington University in Saint Louis First Draft: March 0, 2003 This Draft: ovember 6, 2003 ABSTRACT Traditional mean-variance calculations tell us that the return to a well-diversified portfolio of stocks with an average beta of one will be close to the benchmark. This may suggest that an active manager seeking to beat the market cannot succeed with a large diversified portfolio, and that any successful active portfolio must be limited to a small number of stocks. However, the traditional calculations are not appropriate for an active manager, since traditional calculations assume a fixed portfolio, not an active portfolio that varies depending on the information acquired by the manager. For an active manager, a well-diversified portfolio can add trading profits to the market portfolio without adding significant idiosyncratic risk to the return. This implies a defense of holding large active portfolios, which may potentially provide superior performance and do not expose investors to idiosyncratic risk even if the manager has no talent.

Should active managers hold large portfolios or small portfolios? One common argument says that active managers with large well-diversified portfolios are doomed to failure because the power of diversification implies their returns will be close to a benchmark portfolio. In industry, active managers with large portfolios are sometimes referred to disparagingly as closet indexers because it is thought that they are collecting fees for active management but are playing it safe by mimicking an index portfolio. Indeed, the traditional mean-variance analysis of diversification 2 is incompatible with skilled active management, because the traditional analysis assumes the manager does not have any superior ability. This paper modifies the traditional analysis to include the possibility of superior performance, and finds that a well-diversified portfolio can exhibit superior performance. Therefore, there is no logical reason why active managers holding large portfolios cannot be successful. Security Returns and Information Consider a manager who has a skill in choosing between pairs of stocks. There are pairs of stocks, and we index stocks by a pair (n,i), where i = or 2 and n runs from to. Based on research, our manager generates a private signal s n for each pair n. The signal s n can be interpreted as a part of what uninformed investors view as idiosyncratic risk but can be used by our manager to generate trading profits. Specifically, we assume that the return of security (n,i) is given by the market model () R n,i = { R f + β n (R B R f ) + s n + ε n, i = R f + β n (R B R f ) s n + ε n,2 i = 2 where R f is the riskfree rate, β n is the beta coefficient measuring exposure to market risk, R B is the return to the benchmark (or market) portfolio, s n is a signal observed by our informed manager, and ε n,i is the idiosyncratic risk term for security (n,i) (or more precisely the part of idiosyncratic risk that is not known in advance by our manager). ote that we are assuming that both stocks in pair n have the same level β n of market risk exposure. We will assume that the average We are assuming that active managers are trying to beat the benchmark. Of course, matching the benchmark would be an improvement for many actual managers! 2 See, for example, Markowitz [952], Lintner [965], and Sharpe [963,964, and 966]. Samuelson [967] and Ross [978] discuss the value of diversification in more general models. 2

beta coefficient across pairs is one: (2) β n =. This is sensible given that the benchmark, which is supposed to be representative of stocks in our universe, always has a beta of one. 3 To keep the calculations simple, let (3) s n = { δ with probability /2 δ with probability /2 for some δ > 0. In this case, s n, the part of the idiosyncratic noise of asset (n,i) that the informed agent knows about, has mean zero and variance E[(s n 0) 2 ] = E[δ 2 ] = δ 2. We also assume the ε n,i s, the unknowable parts of the idiosyncratic noise terms, all have the same standard deviation σ > 0 (and therefore variance σ 2 > 0). 4 Traditional Analysis: Uninformed Manager Consider a fixed portfolio placing equal amounts in one stock of each of the pairs. Let I(n) be the security chosen from the nth pair; I(n) = if the portfolio chooses the first security in the nth pair, or I(n) = 2 if the portfolio chooses the second security in the nth pair. Further, let (4) s n { sn I(n) = s n I(n) = 2 3 The average beta is one almost by definition if the benchmark is an equal-weighted portfolio. If the benchmark is a value-weighted portfolio, then the value-weighted average beta would have to be one. Of course, the average beta cannot be one for all subsets unless all stocks have the same beta. Any discussion of what happens as varies would be formalized by a sequence of economies, each of which has the same mean and variance parameters R f, R B, σ, and δ, but different sequences of betas. 4 We could generalize the analysis to give individual assets different levels of idiosyncratic risk, provided the idiosyncratic variances are uniformly bounded. Under these assumptions, convergence of the risk term to zero might be slower and the bound on tail probabilities would be different. 3

be the associated signal term. Then the return on our portfolio is (5) R f ixed = R n,i(n) = (R f + β n (R B R f ) + s n + ε n,i(n) ) ( ) ( = R f + β n )(R B R f ) + = R f + (R B R f ) + ( ) s n + ε n,i(n) = R B + (s n + ε n,i(n) ). ( ) (s n + ε n,i(n) ) For this fixed portfolio, the mean deviation from the market return (6) E[R f ixed R B ] = E = 0, [ (s n + ε n,i(n) ) ] because all the s n s and ε n,i(n) s have mean zero. Further, because the s n s and ε n,i(n) s are all jointly independent, the variance of this deviation does not include any cross (covariance) terms. Therefore, the variance of the deviation from the market is (7) ( var(r f ixed R B ) = E (s n + ε n,i(n) ) 0 ) 2 = = ( ) 2 (δ 2 + σ 2 ) ( ) 2 (δ 2 + σ 2 ) 4

= (δ2 + σ 2 ). As increases, the variation of the portfolio s deviation from the market falls towards zero. Having small variance puts definite bounds on the probability of significant deviations. For example, one conservative bound based on the Chebyshev inequality 5 says that the probability of exceeding the market some fixed amount x can be bounded by a number that gets small as gets large: prob(r f ixed R B > x) < var(r f ixed R B ) x 2 = δ2 + σ 2 x 2. Here, / multiplies a constant, so the probability of doing significantly better (defined by any chosen level x > 0) than the benchmark gets smaller and smaller as increases (for fixed x). This is the traditional analysis that is interpreted as showing that a well-diversified portfolio cannot have significant superior performance. What is wrong with the traditional analysis? othing, if the analysis is applied to a fixed portfolio. However, an active manager does not hold a fixed portfolio, and if the manager has ability, the portfolio chosen is correlated with what an uninformed investor would view as the error term. 6 For an active portfolio, the mean and the variance of the deviation are both different than what is computed in the traditional analysis. ew Analysis: Informed Manager However, the traditional analysis is incorrect 5 Chebyshev s inequality says that for any random variable X with finite variance and any constant a > 0, prob( X > a) E[X 2 ]/a 2. In particular, if X has mean zero, this implies that prob(x > a) var(x)/a 2, since prob(x > a) prob( X > a) and var(x) = E[X 2 ] when E[X] = 0. You may have seen the inequality under another phonetically similar name; there is a lot of variation in the conversion from Cyrillic to English spelling of Chebyshev s name. 6 Our analysis concerns a manager whose ability is in picking stocks, not in timing the market. A talented market timer can make money using a well-diversified portfolio whose leverage is changing over time. That is not the most interesting case for the current analysis. Models of market timing (as well as stock selection), including an analysis of the pitfalls of using traditional performance measures to evaluate a market timer, are presented by Dybvig and Ross [985]. 5

if the manager is informed so that the portfolio is not fixed and is chosen instead as a function of the manager s information. For example, suppose that our manager follows the natural strategy of buying the first portfolio in the pair when it is favored (because s n = δ) and the second portfolio in the pair when it is favored (because s n = δ). This will be the correct strategy if shorts are not allowed and is large enough to diversify tracking error to the manager s satisfaction. Let ι(n) be the choice from pair n, i.e., (8) ι(n) { if sn = δ 2 if s n = δ Then the return on the active manager s portfolio is (9) R active = = = ( R n,ι(n) (R f + β n (R B R f ) + δ + ε n,ι(n) ) ) ( R f + = R f + (R B R f ) + δ + = R B + δ + ε n,ι(n). β n )(R B R f ) + δ + ε n,ι(n) ( ) ε n,ι(n) The mean deviation from the benchmark is (0) E[R active R B ] = E = δ, [ δ + ] ε n,ι(n) since each ε n,i has mean zero and ι(n) is a function of s n and is therefore drawn 6

independently of each ε n,i. 7 This means that the portfolio has superior performance of δ on average. For computing the variance, as in the traditional case, our assumptions about independence of various random draws implies that there are no cross (covariance) terms: () ( ( ε n,ι(n) ) ) 2 var(r active R B ) = E δ + δ = = ( ) 2 σ 2 ( ) 2 σ 2 = σ2. As increases, the variance of the deviation declines to zero, and consequently the superior performance of δ becomes more and more of a sure thing. In particular, for any x > 0, Chebyshev s inequality implies that outperforming the benchmark by any less than x δ becomes increasingly improbable as x increases: (2) prob(r active R B < δ x) var(ractive R B δ) x 2 = σ2 x 2 Therefore, the probability of outperforming the benchmark by significantly less than δ gets smaller and smaller as the number of securities increases. A Paradox There may seem to be an inconsistency with the result (8) that for large a passive portfolio is very unlikely to outperform the benchmark significantly and the result (2) that for large the active portfolio is almost sure to 7 More formally, ε n,ι(n) can be written as (s n + δ)εn,/2δ + (δ s n )εn,2/2δ, as can be verified by noting this is true whether s n = δ or s n = δ. Then the result follows from the facts that s n is drawn independently of the ε n,i s and the ε n,i s both have mean zero. 7

outperform the benchmark significantly. After all, each portfolio the active manager might choose as a function of the signals is one of the passive portfolios for which (8) applies. For example, if we let x = δ/2, then (8) would suggest that outperformance greater than δ/2 is very unlikely, while (2) suggests that outperformance less than δ/2 is very unlikely. 8 The two seem incompatible since the probabilities should add to one. 9 The answer to this apparent paradox is that a particular portfolio is chosen only a very small fraction (= /2 ) of the time and this is in situations when an unusually large return to the particular portfolio is expected. Since the probability of the portfolio being chosen is even smaller than the probability of an extreme return, there is no contradiction. That is why it is okay for the probability of performance of approximately δ given that this portfolio is selected can be so much larger than the probability of performance of approximately δ absent knowledge of the signals. A Case for Large Portfolios The analysis above shows that there is no logical inconsistency between holding a large diversified portfolio and superior returns by an active manager. Indeed, a manager following this sort of policy could have some advantages over a manager choosing to hold a small number of stocks. For one, if the manager is not actually skilled, the portfolio return will be close to the index and therefore little damage from exposure to too much idiosyncratic risk will be done. Furthermore, having a large portfolio makes it easier to evaluate performance, since the degree of idiosyncratic risk to hide the performance is so much smaller. Of course, this is just an example, and as such it shows that there is no logical impediment to superior performance. It remains an open question whether investing with an active manager holding a large portfolio is a good idea. Of course, many people are skeptical that any manager can obtain superior performance, and it is not known whether the shortage of concrete evidence of superior performance is due to lack of performance or the difficulty of distinguishing luck and skill. If 8 The argument in the text assumes that outperformance of exactly δ/2 has probability zero, which is exactly true if the idiosyncratic noise terms have densities, and approximately true in general since σ > 0. 9 The heuristic argument in the text assumes that outperformance of exactly δ/2 has probability zero, which is exactly true if the idiosyncratic noise terms have densities, and approximately true in general (for both active and passive portfolios) for large. 8

Standard Deviation of Returns 0 0 20 30 Value of Diversification Passive Portfolio 0 00 200 300 400 500 umber of Securities Figure : The value of diversification declines rapidly as we add securities, as is shown in this traditional figure. superior performance is possible, perhaps the manager knows about only a few stocks, as might be the case for an analyst who specializes in analysis of a small set of industries. This type of manager would not be a good person to hire for active management of a diversified portfolio. On the other hand, a manager with a product for doing quantitative technical analysis to identify temporary liquidity needs might plausibly have a small amount of information about each of a large number of stocks and might be a likely candidate for superior performance. How likely are these scenarios to produce superior performance? Currently, this is a matter for judgment, and fortunate is the pension fund or endowment whose investments committee, by skill or luck, gets the answer right. umerical Results Figure shows the traditional plot of the value of diversification in our context. This assumes the model () with one security chosen from each pair. We assume the benchmark has a standard deviation of 5%/year, that each stock s unknowable idiosyncratic risk has a standard deviation of σ = 30%/year and that each stock s knowable idiosyncratic risk has a standard devi- 9

Passive Return over Benchmark: Mean and Year 50% and 95% Intervals Return (%/year) 0 5 0 5 0 Mean 50% 95% 0 00 200 300 400 500 umber of Securities Figure 2: As we add securities, the passive portfolio s deviation from the benchmark converges slowly to zero. 0

Active Return over Benchmark: Mean and Year 50% and 95% Intervals Return (%/year) 0 5 0 5 0 Mean 50% 95% 0 00 200 300 400 500 umber of Securities Figure 3: As we add securities, the active portfolio s deviation from the benchmark converges slowly to +2%.

Passive Return over Benchmark: Mean and 0 Year 50% and 95% Intervals Return (%/year) 0 5 0 5 0 Mean 50% 95% 0 00 200 300 400 500 umber of Securities Figure 4: As we add securities, the passive portfolio s deviation from the benchmark converges slowly to zero. 2

Active Return over Benchmark: Mean and 0 Year 50% and 95% Intervals Return (%/year) 0 5 0 5 0 Mean 50% 95% 0 00 200 300 400 500 umber of Securities Figure 5: As we add securities, the active portfolio s deviation from the benchmark converges slowly to +2%. 3

Probability of Outperforming the Benchmark by %/year or More Probability (%) 0 20 60 00 0yr 0yr Active Passive yr yr 0 00 200 300 400 500 umber of Securities Figure 6: It becomes easier and easier to distinguish the active and passive portfolios as securities are added. 4

ation δ = 2%/year. The graph is almost indistinguishable if we plot the standard deviation for our informed agent. Figures 2 and 3 describe how the distribution of excess returns depends on the number of securities for the active and passive strategies. In these graphs, the solid line indicates the mean (and median) return, which is independent of the number of securities in the portfolio in both cases. For each number of securities on the horizontal axis, the performance will be between the dashed lines 50% of the time and between the dotted lines 95% of the time. As securities are added, outperformance of the passive portfolio converges slowly to zero, while the the active portfolio converges slowly to 2% above the benchmark. The convergence is slower than in Figure because adding a small amount of idiosyncratic risk does not have much affect on the volatility of the benchmark. 0 These figures serve as a reminder of the difficulty of measuring performance. Although we have given our informed manager a generous 2%/year in superior performance on average, it takes a very-very-well-diversified portfolio before that performance is consistently of larger magnitude than the noise in most years. onetheless, this figure does illustrate that it is much easier to measure performance in a large well-diversified portfolio than in a small portfolio. Figures 4 and 5 show that identifying performance is easier if we are given a 0-year track record. Of course, this does not help much if we have to make decisions about allocations each year. This is why evaluation of managers almost necessarily considers information beyond compared to a benchmark. Summary Traditional analysis of the value of diversification does not apply in the same way to active managers with ability that permits them to outperform the market. In our example, the volatility of the active manager approaches the benchmark volatility as assets are added, but the mean excess performance converges to a positive constant. Hiring a well-diversified active manager might have several advantages. Performance of a well-diversified manager is relatively easy to measure, and such a manager would also do less damage than an undiversified manager if it turns out the manager does not have ability (or no longer has ability). 0 Analytically, this is because variances of independent random variables add, implying that standard deviations are less than additive. 5

References Dybvig, Philip H., and Stephen A. Ross, 985, Differential Information and Performance Measurement Using a Security Market Line, Journal of Finance 40, 383 399. Lintner, John, 965, Security Prices, Risk, and Maximal Gains from Diversification, Journal of Finance 20, 587 65. Markowitz, Harry, 952, Portfolio Selection, Journal of Finance 7, 77 9. Ross, Stephen A., 978, Mutual Fund Separation in Financial Theory The Separating Distributions, Journal of Economic Theory 7, 254 286. Sharpe, William F., 963, A Simplified Model for Portfolio Analysis, Management Science 2, 277 293. Sharpe, William F., 964, Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of Market Equilibrium under Conditions of Risk, Journal of Finance 9, 425 442. Sharpe, William F., 966, Security Prices, Risk, and Maximal Gains from Diversification: Reply, Journal of Finance 2, 743 744. Samuelson, Paul A., 967, General Proof that Diversification Pays, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 2, 3. 6