Commentary: The Search for Growth

Similar documents
MACROECONOMICS. Economic Growth II: Technology, Empirics, and Policy MANKIW. In this chapter, you will learn. Introduction

Introduction to economic growth (3)

ECONOMIC GROWTH. Objectives. Transforming People s Lives. Transforming People s Lives. Transforming People s Lives CHAPTER

MACROECONOMICS. Economic Growth II: Technology, Empirics, and Policy. N. Gregory Mankiw. PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich

ECON MACROECONOMIC PRINCIPLES Instructor: Dr. Juergen Jung Towson University. J.Jung Chapter 8 - Economic Growth Towson University 1 / 64

How Rich Will China Become? A simple calculation based on South Korea and Japan s experience

macro macroeconomics Government Debt (chapter 15) N. Gregory Mankiw

14.05 Intermediate Applied Macroeconomics Exam # 1 Suggested Solutions

the debate concerning whether policymakers should try to stabilize the economy.

HOW CAN THE FED INFLUENCE INTEREST RATES AND SUSTAIN GROWTH? Remarks by Thomas C. Melzer President, Federal Reserve Bank of St.

Economic Growth II. macroeconomics. fifth edition. N. Gregory Mankiw. PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich Worth Publishers, all rights reserved

Chapter 8. Economic Growth II: Technology, Empirics and Policy 10/6/2010. Introduction. Technological progress in the Solow model

Lyle E. Gramley MEMBER, BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM. Conrnunity Leaders in Seattle

INFLATION AND THE ECONOMIC OUTLOOK By Darryl R. Francis, President. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

TRUE FACTS AND FALSE PERCEPTIONS ABOUT FEDERAL DEFICITS" Remarks by Thomas C. Melzer Rotary Club of Springfield, Missouri December 6, 1988

CRS Report for Congress

Midterm Examination Number 1 February 19, 1996

EXECUTIVE OFFICE OF THE PRESIDENT COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS WASHINGTON, DC 20502

Normalizing Monetary Policy

5.1 Introduction. The Solow Growth Model. Additions / differences with the model: Chapter 5. In this chapter, we learn:

FIRST LOOK AT MACROECONOMICS*

The Importance of Productivity and National Saving

5.1 Introduction. The Solow Growth Model. Additions / differences with the model: Chapter 5. In this chapter, we learn:

Midterm 1. The market value of all final goods and services produced in a particular location over some period of time.

Conditional Convergence: Evidence from the Solow Growth Model

CRS Report for Congress

Use the following to answer question 15: AE0 AE1. Real expenditures. Real income. Page 3

A 45 Year Forecast for the World Economies April 8, 2008

1 Four facts on the U.S. historical growth experience, aka the Kaldor facts

Chapter 6: Long-Run Economic Growth

). In Ch. 9, when we add technological progress, k is capital per effective worker (k = K

DEFICITS AND DEBT Macroeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.)

Check your understanding: Solow model 1

Testing the Solow Growth Theory

Discussion of paper: Quantifying the Lasting Harm to the U.S. Economy from the Financial Crisis. By Robert E. Hall

Advanced Macroeconomics 9. The Solow Model

Chapter 8a: Growth Accounting

Long-term economic growth Growth and factors of production

Long-term economic growth Growth and factors of production

Chapter 8: Economic Growth II: Technology, Empirics, and Policy*

Macroeconomics II Consumption

CHAPTER 11. SAVING, CAPITAL ACCUMULATION, AND OUTPUT

ECON 450 Development Economics

Topic 3: Endogenous Technology & Cross-Country Evidence

3.1 Introduction. 3.2 Growth over the Very Long Run. 3.1 Introduction. Part 2: The Long Run. An Overview of Long-Run Economic Growth

Lab #7. Chapter 7 Growth, Productivity, and Wealth in the Long Run

The Role of Taxes in Economic Development of Kosovo

h Edition Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries

Macroeconomics Sixth Edition

Comments on The International Price System, by Gita Gopinath. Charles Engel University of Wisconsin

Research Summary and Statement of Research Agenda

CROATIA S EU CONVERGENCE REPORT: REACHING AND SUSTAINING HIGHER RATES OF ECONOMIC GROWTH, Document of the World Bank, June 2009, pp.

Principles of Macroeconomics

Ms Hessius comments on the inflation target and the state of the economy in Sweden

BB Chapter 13: Monetary Policy Versus Fiscal Policy Who s Right? BB Chapter 14: Government Deficits and Debts

Solow instead assumed a standard neo-classical production function with diminishing marginal product for both labor and capital.

Lecture notes 2: Physical Capital, Development and Growth

Chapter 20: The Future of NAFTA: A Policy Perspective

Economic growth: Interesting Facts and Examples. 2Topic

The Theory of Economic Growth

The Theory of Economic Growth

Revisionist History: How Data Revisions Distort Economic Policy Research

TOPIC 4 Economi G c rowth

Public Sector Statistics

PRODUCTION and GROWTH. Mankiw, Chapter 25 Krugman, Chapter 25

Masaaki Shirakawa: The transition from high growth to stable growth Japan s experience and implications for emerging economies

Chapter 6: Long-Run Economic Growth

Objectives for Class 26: Fiscal Policy

Usable Productivity Growth in the United States

The U.S. Trade Deficit: A Sign of Good Times. Testimony before The Trade Deficit Review Commission

macro macroeconomics Stabilization Policy N. Gregory Mankiw CHAPTER FOURTEEN PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich fifth edition

Introduction to economic growth (1)

SGPE Summer School: Macroeconomics Lecture 5

Chapter 15. Government Spending and its Financing Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved

Economics. Production and Growth. In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions: N. Gregory Mankiw. Incomes and Growth Around the World

LEARNING FROM BRITAIN S NEXT STEP IN PRIVATIZING SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS

Government Debt and Deficits Revised: March 24, 2009

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

Productivity and Wages

Economic Policy Objectives and Trade-Offs

1 of 24. Modern Macroeconomics: From the Short Run to the Long Run. 2 of 24. They could not have differed more sharply on economic theory and policy.

Dr Andreas Dombret Member of the Executive Board of the Deutsche Bundesbank

Effective Economic Growth for People: The Role of the United States 1

Chapter 11 International Trade and Economic Development

Health Care Spending: What the Future Will Look Like 1

INTRODUCTION TO MODELS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH:

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

The Future Performance of the Canadian Economy

QUESTIONNAIRE A. I. MULTIPLE CHOICE QUESTIONS (2 points each)

2. Suppose a family s annual disposable income is $8000 of which it saves $2000. (a) What is their APC?

MA Macroeconomics 11. The Solow Model

READING 20: DREAMING WITH BRICS: THE PATH TO

Industrial Policy. by Allan H. Meltzer. Testimony Before the Joint Economic Committee October 31, 1983

THE SHORT-RUN TRADEOFF BETWEEN INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT

Social Security Reform: National Saving and Macroeconomic Performance in the Global Economy

Growth, Capital Accumulation, and the Economics of Ideas

Module C. Monetary Policy: How Is It Conducted and How Does It Affect the Economy?

Global Imbalances. January 23rd

Chapter 4. Economic Growth

Economic Outlook, January 2016 Jeffrey M. Lacker President, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

Transcription:

Commentary: The Search for Growth N. Gregory Mankiw For evaluating economic well-being, the single most important statistic about an economy is its income per capita. Income per capita measures how much the typical citizen receives for his contribution to economic activity. And it measures the flow of resources available for current consumption or for investment in the future. Despite all our problems, the United States continues to be blessed with a high level of income per capita. U.S. income per capita is 1.5 times England's, 4.5 times Argentina's, and 23 times India's. The United States and Japan are so close in income per capita that the comparison becomes difficult, but by most measures, the standard of living in the United States is still higher. Yet, another way of looking at the data is less encouraging. Many countries are growing faster than we are. Over the past 30 years, income per capita rose by 5.1 percent per year in Japan and 2.5 percent in Germany, but by only 2.1 percent in the United States. Of the 24 countries in the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), only three grew more slowly than the United States. So the United States is richer than most countries, but many countries are growing faster. Obviously, if the United States continues to grow more slowly than the rest of the world, it will eventually lose its status as the economic frontrunner. And, if history is any guide, it risks losing its role as a military and political superpower as well.

88 N. Gregory Mankiw What determines whether a country grows rapidly like Japan, or slowly like the United States? How should economists model the process of economic growth? How can policymakers encourage faster growth? These are the questions that theorists of economic growth try to answer. In his paper, Charles Plosser surveys some of the prominent theories. He considers traditional theories of economic growth, as derived from the early work of Robert Solow, and endogenous growth theories, which have attracted much interest during the past decade. Although I agree with most of Plosserh assessments, I would put a different "spin" on the conclusion. Rather than saying that we need new theories of economic growth, I would suggest that we merely need to reinterpret traditional theories. Plosser correctly points out that traditional growth theory, such as Solow's, emphasizes the accumulation of capital. The usefulness of the theory is, therefore, limited to capital's importance in the production process. In assessing traditional growth theory, the key question is, how important is capital accumulation to production and growth? To answer this question, Solow's theory points us toward a specific number: the share of national income earned by capital. The capital share has two roles in Solow's theory. First, the larger the capital share, the more important are rates of investment in explaining international differences in steady-state income. Second, the larger the capital share, the longer is the time horizon over which an increase in investment will stimulate economic growth. So how large is the capital share? According to the national income accounts, capital receives only one-third of gross income. If this fact is plugged back into Solow's theory, we learn that capital accumulation cannot easily explain the large international differences that we observe. One-third is simply not a large enough capital share to make capital accumulation the key to understanding economic growth. Economists differ in how they react to this conclusion. A common reaction is to discard Solow's theory and replace it with some newer, fancier theory. By contrast, my reaction is less radical. Perhaps Solow's theory is right, but the fact is wrong. Perhaps capital actually

Commentary receives much more than one-third of income. There are two ways to argue that the capital share is larger than one-third. One argument is that there are positive externalities to capital. That is, some of the benefits to capital accumulation may accrue not to the owners of capital but to others in society. This would occur if, for example, new ideas arise as capital is built and these ideas enter the general pool of knowledge. In this case, even if capital receives only one-third of income, in some sense it deserves credit for more than one-third. How much extra credit is hard to judge. A second argument for a larger capital share is that capital is a much broader concept than is suggested by the national income accounts. In the national income accounts, capital income includes only the income of physical capital, such as plant and equipment. More generally, we accumulate capital whenever we forgo consumption today in order to produce more income tomorrow. Surely, one of the most important forms of capital accumulation is schooling. Yet the return to this human capital is not part of capital income in the national income accounts; instead, it is part of labor income. Therefore, the accounts substantially underestimate the capital share of income. To gauge the true capital share, we need to decide how much of labor income should be credited to human capital. To do this, we might look at the minimum wage, which is roughly the return to labor with minimal human capital. The minimum wage today is roughly onethird of the average wage. This fact suggests that the return to human capital is about two-thirds of labor income, or almost half of national income. Another way to estimate the human-capital share of income is to look at the return to schooling. A large literature in labor economics finds that each year of schooling raises a worker's wage by about 8 percent. Moreover, the average American has about 13 years of schooling. Together these facts imply that the average worker earns almost three times as much as he would without any human capital. In other words, about two-thirds of the average worker's earnings is the return to his education. Again, this suggests that the human-capital share of national income is almost one-half.

90 N. Gregory Mankiw If we add this estimate of the human-capital share to the physicalcapital share of one-third, we find that the income from all forms of capital equals about 80 percent of national income. This increase in the capital share from its traditional value of one-third to this new value of four-fifths is crucial for how we evaluate theories of economic growth. This new higher capital share implies that traditional growth theory, with its emphasis on capital accumulation, can explain the huge international differences in income per capita that we observe. And it implies that high saving and investment can lead to high growth over a horizon of many decades. Let me now turn to the key question for policymakers: How can a country achieve a high rate of economic growth? The Solow growth model, interpreted broadly to include human capital, suggests that there are four secrets to fast growth. Secret to growth #1: Start behind. As Plosser points out, the Solow growth model implies convergence in standards of living. That is, holding other things constant, countries that start off poor will tend to grow faster than countries that start off rich. This prediction of the theory explains much of the slow U.S. growth during the past 30 years. Many countries have grown more quickly than the United States simply because they started so far behind. Germany grew quickly in the period after World War I1 because it was making up for the destruction of the war. Japan had to catch up not only from the war, but also from its low state of development before the war. In 1950, income per capita in Japan was only one-sixth of income in the United States. Now that these countries are approaching the level of income in the United States, their growth rates have fallen and are closer to ours. Secret to growth #2: Save and invest. Individuals build their wealth by consuming less than their income and investing the difference. Nations are no different. The more a nation saves and invests, the more capital its workers have to work

Commentary with, and the greater are their productivity and wages. This simple lesson does not bode well for the United States. During the 1980s, gross national saving in the United Sates averaged about 18 percent of GNP, compared to 3 1 percent for Japan. So not all of Japan's fast growth has been catch-up; part of it has come from greater thriftiness. This comparison leads many to advocate policies to raise national saving. One way would be to stimulate private saving through tax incentives, such as a switch from income taxation to consumption taxation. Another way would be to raise public saving-that is, to reduce the government budget deficit that represents negative saving for the nation. Secret to growth #3: Educate the young. As with physical capital, building human capital requires a sacrifice today in order to reap a benefit in the future. When we spend money on schools and teachers, that money is unavailable for current consumption. Students who are building human capital must forgo the wages they would have earned if they were in the labor force. Fortunately, U.S. investment in human capital is not as meager as U.S. investment in physical capital. An impressive 60 percent of our students continue their education beyond high school, as compared to 30 percent in Japan and Germany. Yet many countries do a better job of educating the students that they do have in school. The typical Japanese high school student spends 240 days per year in school, compared to 180 days for the typical American student. Secret to growth #4: Keep population growth low. When the population of a country grows rapidly, it is more difficult to provide new workers with the tools and skills needed for production. In other words, rapid population growth depresses the amount of physical and human capital available for each worker, which in turn, reduces each worker's productivity.

92 N. Gregoty Mankiw Rapid population growth is not a problem for the United States, but it is a primary cause of poverty in the Third World. Over the past several decades, the U.S. population has been growing at about 1.2 percent per year, which means that the population doubles every 58 years. By contrast, the typical country in sub-saharan Africa has a population growth rate of 2.8 percent per year, so the population doubles every 25 years. Not surprisingly, African productivity lags far behind the rest of the world. So there are the four secrets of economic growth. These secrets come from the most basic Solow growth theory, and they are consistent with the international evidence. One nagging question remains: If the secrets of growth are as simple as I have suggested, why does the United States have such a low growth rate? Why don't we pursue policies to raise the growth rate? To some extent, the failure of American economic policy to promote growth may reflect a genuine confusion about how rapid growth is best achieved. But one can also take a darker view of the situation: If capital accumulation is the key to growth, then prosperity tomorrow requires sacrifice today. It is a rare politician who is willing to be the bearer of such a difficult truth. Endnote '~rofessor ~ankiw's remarks are based on his joint work with David Romerand David Weil. See N. Gregory Mankiw, David Romer, and David Weil, "A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth," Quarterly Journal of Economics, (May 1992). pp. 407-37.