QUANTITATIVE EASING: WHAT MIGHT MILTON FRIEDMAN HAVE SAID?

Similar documents
The August 9 FOMC Decision Ineffective at Best, Dangerous at Worst

Don t End the Fed, Mend the Fed

February 22, Northern Trust Global Economic Research 50 South LaSalle Chicago, Illinois northerntrust.com

Chapter 26 Transmission Mechanisms of Monetary Policy: The Evidence

The Real Problem was Nominal: How the Crash of 2008 was Misdiagnosed. Scott Sumner, Bentley University

Deflation? Yes. Deflationary spiral? No.

2Q16. Don t Be So Negative. June Uncharted territory

Prudential International Investments Advisers, LLC. Global Investment Strategy October 2009

International Money and Banking: 6. Problems with Monetarism

Macroeconomic Policy during a Credit Crunch

Financial Market Outlook & Strategy: Stocks Bottoming On Track to Recovery. Near-term Risks

THE FEDERAL RESERVE AND MONETARY POLICY Macroeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.)

Objectives for Chapter 24: Monetarism (Continued) Chapter 24: The Basic Theory of Monetarism (Continued) (latest revision October 2004)

Sample Exam 1: QEII Labor Market Rescue?

INFLATION AND THE ECONOMIC OUTLOOK By Darryl R. Francis, President. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Financial Market Outlook: Stocks Rebounding from July Correction, Further Gains Likely. Bond Yields Range Bound

Economic Fundamentals

Quarterly Review and Outlook, First Quarter 2018

2012 As the Fundamentals Improve Stateside, They Deteriorate Abroad

Lecture 13: The Great Depression

If Current Bank Credit Trends Continue, Bet Against the Fed s Interest Rate Forecast

Session 12. The New Normal. Deflation and Zero Lower Bound.

To QE or Not to QE? That is the Question

Leandro Conte UniSi, Department of Economics and Statistics. Money, Macroeconomic Theory and Historical evidence. SSF_ aa

Gauging Current Conditions:

Expansions (periods of. positive economic growth)

Monetary Policy and the Expanded Loanable Funds Model

Disclaimer: This resource package is for studying purposes only EDUCATION

Financial Market Outlook: Stock Rally Continues with Faster & Stronger GDP Rebound, Earnings Recovery & Liquidity

The Model at Work. (Reference Slides I may or may not talk about all of this depending on time and how the conversation in class evolves)

INCREASING THE RATE OF CAPITAL FORMATION (Investment Policy Report)

Question 5 : Franco Modigliani's answer to Simon Kuznets's puzzle regarding long-term constancy of the average propensity to consume is that : the ave

Prudential International Investments Advisers, LLC. Global Investment Strategy March 2010

The Case for Money Finance:

October 29, Can the Fed Successfully Exit from Its Recent Policy?

On Abenomics and the Japanese Economy. Motoshige Itoh Member, Council on Economic and Fiscal Policy and Professor, University of Tokyo

Case, Fair and Oster Macroeconomics Chapter 12 Problems -- Aggregate Demand in the Goods and Money Markets

Econ 330 Final Exam Name ID Section Number

Analysis and Action Why is Inflation so Low?

CIE Economics A-level

CRS Report for Congress

Table 1: Economic Growth Measures

Financial Market Outlook: Further Stock Gain on Faster GDP Rebound and Earnings Recovery. Year-end Target Raised

Econ 102 Final Exam Name ID Section Number

Observation. January 18, credit availability, credit

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA Economics 134 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Spring 2018 Professor David Romer

Cost Shocks in the AD/ AS Model

EC 201 Lecture Notes 7 Page 1 of 1

Gold: Early 1930s vs. Early 2010s

Unemployment and Inflation

Econ 102 Final Exam Name ID Section Number

Accelerating Deflation and Monetary Policy

Chapter 10. Conduct of Monetary Policy: Tools, Goals, Strategy, and Tactics. Chapter Preview

The sharp accumulation in government debt can t go on forever

How costly is for Spain to be in the EURO?

Economic & Capital Market Outlook Third Quarter, 2018

Discussant s comments of William R. Emmons, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, on

The Exchange Rate and Canadian Inflation Targeting

Prudential International Investments Advisers, LLC. Global Investment Strategy & Outlook For 2009

COMMENTARY NUMBER 372 April Trade Deficit, Bernanke Shift. June 9, Earthquake-Diminished Imports of Auto Parts Narrowed April Deficit

By John Praveen, Chief Investment Strategist of Prudential International Investments Advisers, LLC.*

Light at the End of the Tunnel or an Oncoming Freight Train? March 20, 2009

Archimedean Upper Conservatory Economics, November 2016 Quiz, Unit VI, Stabilization Policies

Chapter 15. Government Spending and its Financing Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved

Principles of Money, Banking, and Financial Markets, 12e (Ritter / Silber / Udell) Chapter 2 The Role of Money in the Macroeconomy

Paper Published in the February 2005 Journal of Business & Economic Research Why the Quantity of Money Still Matters

Econ 102 Exam 2 Name ID Section Number

FINAL EXAM (Two Hours) DECEMBER 21, 2016 SECTION #

Monetary Policy and Economic Outcomes *

Money and Monetary Policy. Economic Forces in American History

International Journal of Business and Economic Development Vol. 4 Number 1 March 2016

Masaaki Shirakawa: Global financial crisis and policy responses by the Bank of Japan

Current Economic Conditions and Selected Forecasts

Prudential International Investments Advisers, LLC. Global Investment Strategy June 2009

The Influence of Monetary and Fiscal Policy on Aggregate Demand

Monetary Policy. Focusing on interest rates, Influencing real growth rates, affecting inflation rates

Perspectives on the U.S. Economy

Corporate and Household Sectors in Austria: Subdued Growth of Indebtedness

BUDGET. Budget Plan. November 1, 2001

TOPIC 5. Fed Policy and Money Markets

Answers to Questions: Chapter 5

Automatic Stabilizers

ECN 106 Macroeconomics 1. Lecture 10

Gundlach: Treasuries will Rally When QE2 Ends

Midsummer Examinations 2013

Unit: Monetary Policy

Normalizing Monetary Policy

15 th. edition Gwartney Stroup Sobel Macpherson. First page. edition Gwartney Stroup Sobel Macpherson

Answers and Explanations

1 of 15 12/1/2013 1:28 PM

Another Milestone on the Road to Policy Normalization

Use the following to answer question 15: AE0 AE1. Real expenditures. Real income. Page 3

III. 9. IS LM: the basic framework to understand macro policy continued Text, ch 11

CHAPTER 8 FISCAL POLICY: COPING WITH INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT

Outline Conduct of Economic Policy The Implementation of Economic Policy. Macroeconomic Policy. Bilgin Bari

Haruhiko Kuroda: How to overcome deflation

THE INFLUENCE OF MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICY ON AGGREGATE DEMAND

Chapter Twenty 11/26/2017. Chapter 20 Money Growth, Money Demand, and Modern Monetary Policy. In This Chapter. 1. The quantity theory of money.

HELICOPTER BEN, MONETARISM, THE NEW KEYNESIAN CREDIT VIEW AND LOANABLE FUNDS

16-3: Monetary Policy. Notes

Transcription:

QUANTITATIVE EASING: WHAT MIGHT MILTON FRIEDMAN HAVE SAID? COMMENTS TO THE ECONOMIC CLUB OF SHEBOYGAN APRIL 20, 2016 Paul L. Kasriel econtrarian@gmail.com Econtrarian, LLC 920-818-0236 The Econtrarian

Rx for Japan: Back to the Future Milton Friedman, WSJ, December 17, 1997 2 [A]t the Louvre conference in February 1987, the assembled leaders agreed to stabilize the foreign exchange value of the dollar. Japan, as its part of the deal, bought dollars, in the process creating yen. The resulting acceleration in monetary growth led to higher inflation and, initially, to higher real growth. The most notable result was the "bubble economy," an explosion in the prices of land, stocks and other assets; the Nikkei stock index more than doubled in three years. The Bank of Japan reacted belatedly in 1990, reducing monetary growth to less than 3% from 13% in the first year of the new policy, and to negative rates in the second... Tight money was spectacularly effective; the stock market, and also nominal income growth, plunged. Low inflation turned into actual deflation by 1994. The surest road to a healthy economic recovery is to increase the rate of monetary growth, to shift from tight money to easier money Defenders of the Bank of Japan will say, How? The Bank has already cut its discount rate to 0.5%. What more can it do to increase the quantity of money? The answer is straightforward: The Bank of Japan can buy government bonds on the open market, paying for them with either currency or deposits at the Bank of Japan, what economists call highpowered money. There is no limit to the extent to which the Bank of Japan can increase the money supply if it wishes to do so. Higher monetary growth will have the same effect as always. After a year or so, the economy will expand more rapidly; output will grow; and after another delay, inflation will increase moderately.

Rx for Japan: Back to the Future continued 3 Initially, higher monetary growth would reduce short-term interest rates even further. However, as the economy revives, interest rates would start to rise. Low interest rates are generally a sign that money has been tight, as in Japan; high interest rates, that money has been easy. Japan's recent experience of three years of near zero economic growth is an eerie, if less dramatic, replay of the great contraction in the U.S. The Fed permitted the quantity of money to decline by one-third from 1929 to 1933 The U.S. revived when monetary growth resumed, as Japan will. The Fed pointed to low interest rates as evidence that it was following an easy money policy and never mentioned the quantity of money. After the U.S. experience during the Great Depression, and after inflation and rising interest rates in the '70s and disinflation and falling interest rates in the '80s, I thought the fallacy of identifying tight money with high interest rates and easy money with low interest rates was dead. Apparently, old fallacies never die.

4 In terms of the impact on financial corporation profits, the 2008 financial crisis was more severe than that of the 1929 crisis.

5 Following the bursting of the housing bubble and the 2008 financial crisis, bank loan delinquency and charge-off rates rose precipitously.

6 As a result of their severe losses following the 2008 financial crisis, banks tightened their lending terms, which were reflected in widening loan interest-rate spreads.

7 Following the 2008 financial crisis, there was the sharpest contraction in the post-wwii era in loans and securities on the books of depository institutions (commercial banks, S&Ls, and credit unions).

8 It would appear that demand for credit was not the primary factor accounting for the sharp contraction in loans and securities on the books of private depository institutions inasmuch as the US Treasury had an enormous appetite for credit following the 2008 financial crisis. Yet, the increase in the relative acquisition of Treasury securities by depository institutions was modest following the 2008 financial crisis.

Why the emphasis on depository institution credit? 9 Central banks, a.k.a. legal counterfeiters, are able to create credit out of thin air. In a fractional reserve monetary arrangement, the depository institution system, if not constrained by capital or regulatory issues, is able to create an amount of credit that is some multiple of the amount of seed money (i.e., reserves) created out of thin air by the central bank (similar to the moneymultiplier question on your undergrad Money & Banking final). This credit created by the depository institution system also is credit created figuratively out of thin air. The unique characteristic of thin-air credit is that the grantor of this credit need not cut back on his current spending while the recipient of this credit increases his current spending. Thus, there is a presumption that an increase in thin-air credit will result in a net increase in nominal spending or transactions in the economy. The same implication does not categorically hold for the extensions of other types of credit. E.g., if households extend new credit, they typically fund their new lending by cutting back on their current spending, i.e., they increase their current saving, transferring spending capability to borrowers. Thus, an increase in non thin-air credit does not result in a net increase in nominal spending, rather just a change in the composition of a given amount of spending. Austrian economic theory makes a distinction between created (i.e., thin-air ) credit and transfer credit.

10 In the past 60+ years, there has existed a relatively high positive correlation between growth in total thin-air credit and growth in nominal domestic spending on goods and services.

11 The correlation between changes in non-thin-air credit and changes in nominal domestic purchases is considerably lower, at 0.38, than that of thin-air credit, at 0.66. As important, when lead-lag tests are performed, the results suggest that thin-air credit causes domestic purchases while domestic purchases cause non-thin-air credit.

12 Immediately following the financial crisis of 2008, the collapse in the growth of total thin-air credit would have been even more severe had it not been for the Fed s creation of credit. In the current economic expansion, growth in total thin-air credit has been below its long-run median of 7.1%. Had it not been for Fed QE policy, total thin-air credit growth would have been even weaker.

13 Following the 2008 financial crisis, the private depository institution credit multiplier with respect to reserves provided by the Fed collapsed. Because of capital constraints, regulatory restraints, and liquidity concerns, private depository institutions were unable to create much additional credit from the massive increase in seed money reserves provided by the Fed.

Central bank quantitative easing (QE) is a temporary substitute for the creation of thinair credit that the private depository institution system would otherwise create if it were not capital constrained. 14 When the private banking system increases its net lending, it creates new thin-air credit, which enables the recipients of this credit to increase their current spending without requiring other entities to decrease their current spending. If the central bank were allowed to lend to the nonbank public, it, too, would create new thin-air credit, which would enable the recipients of this credit to increase their current spending without requiring other entities to decrease their current spending exactly the same as the case in which the private banking system increased its net lending. If the private banking system is constrained in its ability to create normal amounts of thin-air credit, then normal growth in nominal aggregate demand will slow and a general deflation might occur due to a lack of demand. In order to mitigate this insufficiency in nominal aggregate demand, the central bank can step up its provision of thin-air credit to the nonbank sector by increasing its net purchases of securities in the open market (i.e., QE).

One example of how QE might work : 15 The Fed purchases $X of Treasury and/or Agency mortgage-backed securities from (ultimately) a pension fund. The pension fund now has $X fewer securities in its portfolio and $X more in deposits at its bank. The pension fund s bank and the banking system have $X more in reserves at the Fed. The pension fund chooses to replace $X of securities it sold to the Fed with $X of newly-issued corporate bonds being floated to finance the corporation s purchase of new capital equipment. The pension fund s securities holdings rise back to their pre-qe level and its level of deposits falls back to its pre-qe level. The corporation purchases capital equipment from the proceeds of its bond sale, which was indirectly financed by the Fed s creation of thin-air credit via its QE operation. The corporation has increased its current nominal spending by $X and no other entity has been required to decrease its current nominal spending. On net, then, nominal spending in the economy has increased by $X. Reserves at the Fed have increased by $X, deposits in the banking system have increased by $X, excess reserves in the private banking system have increased by $X minus reserve requirement on $X of additional deposits, private bank thin-air credit has increased by $Zero, and total thin-air credit (sum of private bank thin-air credit and Fed thin-air credit) has increased by $X.

Another way in which QE might work : 16 The pension fund replaces the securities sold to the Fed with newly-issued corporate securities. But instead of the corporation using the proceeds of its bond sale to finance the purchase of capital equipment, the proceeds are used to repurchase outstanding equity.

Has QE resulted in inflation? Depends on your definition of inflation? 17 Although goods/services price inflation has been quite moderate in the past seven years, asset-price inflation has been above its long-run median.

18 Before getting too excited about the inflationary implications of recent Fed QE policy, remember that although the Fed s contribution to thin-air credit has been off the scale, growth in total thin-air credit has been moderate in an historical perspective.

19 It is not the primary purpose of QE to stimulate private bank lending. Rather, QE should be viewed as a temporary substitute for private bank lending when the banking system is constrained in its ability to create normal amounts of credit.

20 If the purpose of Fed QE was to reduce bond yields, it was a failure! In each of the Fed s three rounds of QE, bond yields rose. Bond yields fell when the Fed cut back on its securities purchases.

21 To QE or not to QE: A tale of two central bank policies, the Fed vs. the ECB

How To Properly Manage And Communicate a QE Policy 22 The central bank should announce that it is going to manage its balance sheet so as to hit a specified growth rate in total thin-air credit, i.e., central bank credit and private depository institution credit. If private thin-air credit growth weakens, the central bank might need to increase its provision of thin-air credit so that the targeted growth rate of total thin-air credit is not undershot. Conversely, if private thin-air credit creation strengthens, the central bank might need to slow its provision of thin-air credit so that the targeted growth rate of total thin-air credit is not exceeded. By what logic does a central bank announce a dollar/euro/yen amount of securities it intends to purchase? The amount of securities the central bank should purchase will vary from month-to-month depending on the behavior of private thin-air credit and the target growth rate, preferably constant, of total thin-air credit. The central bank can control either the supply of thin-air credit (i.e., reserves) it provides or the price of central bank thin-air credit (i.e., the overnight interest rate), but not both! So, if the central bank wants to manage QE properly, it needs to abandon interest-rate targeting.

Evaluating the Fed s Quantitative Policy Efforts 23 QE I Too little. QE II About right, but terminated too soon. QE III Almost as if the Fed knew what it was doing. QT I If it ain t broke, why try to fix it? QEI QEII QEIII QTI Median = 7.1%

Quantitative Easing/Tightening A Monetary Policy for All Seasons 24 Milton Friedman argued that the Fed should target some constant rate of growth in the money supply. Why not have the Fed target some constant rate of growth in total thin-air credit? Because growth in total thin-air credit has had a relatively high positive correlation with growth in nominal domestic demand for goods and services over the past 60 years (see slide 10), for the Fed to manage its provision of thin-air credit such that total thin-air credit would grow at some constant rate, would be near the equivalent of the Fed targeting nominal GDP growth. Friedman argued that inflation is a monetary phenomenon. More specifically, I would argue that inflation changes in the prices of goods/services and/or assets -- is a total thin-air credit phenomenon. If the Fed were to manage its provision of thin-air credit such that total thin-air credit were to grow at some constant relatively low rate, then it is unlikely that there would be periods of persistent undesirably high rates of inflation, periods of persistent undesirable rates of deflation or the development of asset-price bubbles.

25 Observations of a Recovering Keynesian

26 Contrary to mainstream Keynesian thinking, changes in fiscal policy have had no significant and consistent effect on the pace of economic activity. According to mainstream economic commentary, a tax rate decrease or an increase in government spending will result in stronger growth in nominal economic activity. Thus, according to mainstream economic commentary, changes in the cyclically-adjusted federal budget surplus/deficit should be negatively related to growth in nominal GDP. E.g., if the budget were in balance and taxes were decreased and/or government spending was increased such that a cyclically-adjusted budget deficit were to result, according to mainstream economic commentary, growth in nominal GDP would be expected to accelerate. 50 years of U.S economic data show no significant relationship between changes in federal budget balance and nominal GDP growth.

What might explain this lack of a relationship between changes in fiscal policy and growth in nominal GDP? 27 If tax revenues decrease because of a tax cut or government spending increases, government borrowing will increase. This means that entities, who otherwise would have lent to private-sector borrowers, might now lend to the government instead. If so, the increase in government spending will offset the decrease in spending from the private sector borrowers who were crowded out of the debt market, implying no net change in nominal aggregate spending. Although admittedly farfetched, in the case of a tax cut, entities might use their increased after-tax income to purchase the additional debt issued by the government the so-called (fairy tale) Ricardian equivalence proposition. The result would be no net increase in aggregate nominal spending. In the case of a tax cut, entities might use their increased after-tax income to increase their current spending, again offsetting the decreased spending emanating from the private-sector borrowers crowded out of the debt market. But there is no net increase in aggregate nominal spending. There is a case in which a tax cut or an increase in government spending could result in a net increase in aggregate spending. This would occur if entities decreased their holdings of deposits to pay for their purchases of the additional government debt. In this special case, where the velocity of money increases, an easier fiscal policy can result in stronger GDP growth From a cyclical perspective, then, changes in fiscal policy that are not accompanied by changes in thin-air credit generally tend not to change aggregate income, but rather redistribute it.

28 Historically, federal government borrowing has a high negative correlation with nonfinancial sector saving. Is it any wonder then that the fiscal stimulus of 2009 had such a small impact on GDP growth?

29 Conclusion Ignore the behavior of total thin-air credit at your own risk!

Thank You 30 Paul L. Kasriel Econtrarian, LLC econtrarian@gmail.com 920-818-0236 The Econtrarian