What Bernanke doesn t understand about deflation

Similar documents
The Economic Case Against Bernanke

Follow this and additional works at: Copyright 2009 Australasian Accounting Business and Finance Journal and Authors.

Deleveraging is America s future

Testimony of Dean Baker. Before the Subcommittee on TARP and Financial Resources of the House Committee on Oversight and Government Reform

The Fiscal Cliff Lessons from the 1930s

The Aggregate Expenditures Model. A continuing look at Macroeconomics

TWO VIEWS OF THE ECONOMY

What Should the Fed Do?

Steve Keen s Dynamic Model of the economy.

2. Aggregate Demand and Output in the Short Run: The Model of the Keynesian Cross

ECON Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory

Economic History of the US

10 Chapter Outline What is Keynesianism?

Lecture 7. Unemployment and Fiscal Policy

Sample Exam 1: QEII Labor Market Rescue?

The Impact of Private Debt on the Global Financial System Steve Keen Kingston University London IDEAeconomics Minsky Open Source System Dynamics

The Worst Recession since the Great Depression? Perhaps, But December 15, 2008

Reflections on the Financial Crisis Allan H. Meltzer

Homework Assignment #6. Due Tuesday, 11/28/06. Multiple Choice Questions:

STOP RENTING AND OWN A HOME FOR LESS THAN YOU ARE PAYING IN RENT WITH VERY LITTLE MONEY DOWN

4 BIG REASONS YOU CAN T AFFORD TO IGNORE BUSINESS CREDIT!

Lecture 13: The Great Depression

China & Commodities - the First Major Trend Reversal of the 21st Century

Multiple Choice Questions (3 points each) Please answer the questions on the green scantron.

Supply and Demand over the Business Cycle

Overview. Stanley Fischer

The Government and Fiscal Policy

Transcript of Larry Summers NBER Macro Annual 2018

Whither the US equity markets?

Mortgage rate minus RBA Rate

TWO PRINCIPLES OF DEBT AND NATIONAL INCOME DYNAMICS IN A PURE CREDIT ECONOMY. Jan Toporowski

Interpreting Real Gross Domestic Product

ECONOMICS U$A 21 ST CENTURY EDITION PROGRAM #18 FISCAL POLICY Annenberg Foundation & Educational Film Center

Some Simple Deficit Reduction Arithmetic

Gross Domestic Product: What an Economy Produces

Things you should know about inflation

The Economy: Growth Has Been Weak But Long-Lasting

ECON 1010 Principles of Macroeconomics Exam #2. Section A: Multiple Choice Questions. (30 points; 2 pts each)

Almost everyone is familiar with the

joshuakennon.com by JOSHUA KENNON FEB. 6, 2013

FISCAL POLICY* Chapt er. Key Concepts

The figures in the left (debit) column are all either ASSETS or EXPENSES.

Homework Assignment #6. Due Tuesday, 11/28/06. Multiple Choice Questions:

Practical Problems with Discretionary Fiscal Policy

The yellow highlighted areas are bear markets with NO recession.

Government spending in a model where debt effects output gap

Steve Keen's Debtwatch No 14 October 2007 Draft only

In other words, it s just taking a proven math principle and giving it a real world application that s admittedly shocking.

Unlocking 900% More Money

What Rising Interest Rates Mean for the Economy and You

1 of 24. Modern Macroeconomics: From the Short Run to the Long Run. 2 of 24. They could not have differed more sharply on economic theory and policy.

Notes 6: Examples in Action - The 1990 Recession, the 1974 Recession and the Expansion of the Late 1990s

WHY YOU ARE NOT MAKING THE MOST OF YOUR 401(K)

The Real Problem was Nominal: How the Crash of 2008 was Misdiagnosed. Scott Sumner, Bentley University

BINARY OPTIONS: A SMARTER WAY TO TRADE THE WORLD'S MARKETS NADEX.COM

The Great Depression: An Overview by David C. Wheelock

By JW Warr

Gross Domestic Product

ECONOMIC POLICY. and PUBLIC POLICY

10 AGGREGATE SUPPLY AND AGGREGATE DEMAND* Chapt er. Key Concepts. Aggregate Supply1

Household Debt the final stage in an artificially extended Ponzi Bubble

Excerpts from First Principles: Five Keys to Restoring America s Prosperity

Let Diversification Do Its Job

You have many choices when it comes to money and investing. Only one was created with you in mind. A Structured Settlement can provide hope and a

Some Thoughts on Roller Coaster Investing

ECO155L19.doc 1 OKAY SO WHAT WE WANT TO DO IS WE WANT TO DISTINGUISH BETWEEN NOMINAL AND REAL GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT. WE SORT OF

Macroeconomics, Cdn. 4e (Williamson) Chapter 1 Introduction

Reading Five: A Right Jab & A Left Hook

Forex Illusions - 6 Illusions You Need to See Through to Win

So the first stage is when gold starts rising against fiat currencies. What s the next stage?

China s Financial Markets: An Overview Summary Historical Overview of the Financial Markets

The aggregate supply curve shows the relationship between the aggregate price level and the quantity of aggregate output in the economy.

ECO 209Y MACROECONOMIC THEORY AND POLICY

OVERVIEW. 4. Equilibrium occurs at the level of income where the inflows equal the outflows, I + G = S + T.

In pursuing a strategy of monetary targeting, the central bank announces that it will

Econ 20B Spr 2008 Sample Final Exam

Advanced Macroeconomics 4. The Zero Lower Bound and the Liquidity Trap

Checks and Balances TV: America s #1 Source for Balanced Financial Advice

Discussion of Credit Traps Benmelech and Bergman. Owen Lamont IMF, November 2009

Erkki Liikanen: Population ageing, pension savings and the financial markets

Workplace pensions AUTO ENROLMENT HAS TAKEN OFF

GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT

Mitchell s Musings : Consistency May Be a Hobgoblin We Need to Mind. Daniel J.B. Mitchell

Module 19 Equilibrium in the Aggregate Demand Aggregate Supply Model

International Money and Banking: 15. The Phillips Curve: Evidence and Implications

Toward a New Global Recession? Economic Perspectives for 2016 and Beyond

Value Added TIPS. Executive Summary. A Product of the MOSERS Investment Staff. March 2000 Volume 2 Issue 5

Chapter 4: A First Look at Macroeconomics

Exam #3 (Final Exam) Solution Notes Spring, 2011

The Return of the Bear

The Hard Lessons of Stock Market History

FAQ: Money and Banking

Debt Freedom Day Report Steve Keen

Words on Wealth. Welcome to the winter edition of Meridian s Words on Wealth. Meridian W INTER 2015

How I learnt to stop worrying and love The Bank

Are Your Allocations Right for Social Security?

A Lower Bound on Real Interest Rates

7 AGGREGATE SUPPLY AND AGGREGATE DEMAND* Chapter. Key Concepts

Federal Spending to Top a Record $4 Trillion in FY2017

HOW THE DEAD CAT BOUNCE STOCK TRADING PATTERN WORKS by Michael Swanson

Transcription:

Steve Keen s watch What Bernanke doesn t understand about deflation August 29, 2010 What Bernanke doesn t understand about deflation Bernanke s recent Jackson Hole speech didn t contain one reference to the key force driving the American economy right now: private sector deleveraging. The reason the US economy is not recovering from this crisis is because all sectors of American society took on too much debt during the false boom of the last two decades, and they are now busily getting themselves out of debt any way they can. reduction is now the real story of the American economy, just as real story behind the apparent free lunch of the last two decades was rising debt. The secret that has completely eluded Bernanke is that aggregate demand is the sum of GDP plus the change in debt. So when debt is rising demand exceeds what it could be on the basis of earned incomes alone, and when debt is falling the opposite happens. I ve been banging the drum on this for years now, but it s a hard idea to communicate because it s so alien to the way most economists (and many people) think. For a start, it involves a redefinition of aggregate demand. Most economists are conditioned to think of commodity markets and asset markets as two separate spheres, but my definition lumps them together: aggregate demand is the sum of expenditure on goods and services, PLUS the net amount of money spent buying assets (shares and property) on the secondary markets. This expenditure is financed by the sum of what we earn from productive activities (largely wages and profits) PLUS the change in our debt levels. So total demand in the economy is the sum of GDP plus the change in debt. I ve recently developed a simple numerical example that makes this case easier to understand: imagine an economy with a nominal GDP of $1,000 billion which is growing at 10 percent a year, due to an inflation rate of 5 percent and a real growth rate of 5 percent, and in which private debt is $1,250 billion and is growing at 20% a year. private sector demand in this economy expenditure on all markets, including asset markets is therefore $1,250 billion: $1,000 billion from expenditure from income (GDP) and $250 billion from the change in debt. At the end of the year, private debt will be $1,500 billion. Expenditure is thus 20 percent above the level that could be financed by income alone. Now imagine that the following year, the rate of growth of GDP continues at 10 percent, but the rate of growth of debt slows from 20 to 10 percent. GDP will have grown to $1,100 billion, while the increase in private debt this year will be $150 billion 10 percent of the initial $1,500 billion total and therefore $100 billion less than the $250 billion increase the year before. private sector demand in this economy will therefore be $1,250 billion, consisting of $1,100 billion from GDP and $150 billion from rising debt exactly the same as the year before. But since inflation has been running at 5 percent, aggregate demand will be 5 percent lower than the year before in real terms. So simply stabilising the debt to GDP ratio results in a fall in demand in real terms, and some markets commodities and/or assets must take a hit. www.debtdeflation.com/blogs Page 1 of 5

Steve Keen s watch What Bernanke doesn t understand about deflation August 29, 2010 Putting this example in a table, we get the following illustration: Variable/Year Year 1 Year 2 Nominal GDP 1000 1100 Growth rate of Nominal GDP 10% 10% Real growth rate 5% 5% Inflation Rate 5% 5% Private 1250 1500 Growth rate of Private 20% 10% Private 250 150 Nominal demand (GDP + ) 1250 1250 Notice that nominal GDP remains constant across the two years but this means that real output has to fall, since half of the recorded growth in nominal GDP is inflation. So even stabilising the debt to GDP ratio causes a fall in real aggregate demand. Some markets whether they're for goods and services or assets like shares and property have to take a hit, and the economy will go into a recession. It s far worse if debt levels actually fall, but at the same time, that s necessary to wean this example economy off its dependence on debt. Now let s apply this to the US economy for the last few years, in somewhat more detail. There are some rough edges to the following table the year to year changes put some figures out of whack, and some change in debt is simply compounding of unpaid interest that doesn t add to aggregate demand but in the spirit of I d rather be roughly right than precisely wrong, at your leisure please work your way through the table below. Its key point can be grasped just by considering the GDP and the change in debt for the two years 2008 and 2010: in 2007 2008, GDP was $14.3 trillion while the change in private sector debt was $4 trillion, so aggregate private sector demand was $18.3 trillion. In calendar year 2009 10, GDP was $14.5 trillion, but the change in debt was minus $1.9 trillion, so that aggregate private sector demand was $12.6 trillion. The turnaround in two years in the change of debt has literally sucked almost $6 trillion out of the US economy. Variable\Year 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 GDP 12,915,600 13,611,500 14,337,900 14,347,300 14,453,800 6.3% 5.4% 5.3% 0.1% 0.7% Nominal GDP Real 2.7% 2.4% 2.5% 1.9% 0.1% GDP Inflation Rate 4.0% 2.1% 4.3% 0.0% 2.6% Private 33,196,817 36,553,385 40,596,586 42,045,481 40,185,976 Growth 9.6% 10.1% 11.1% 3.6% 4.4% Rate 2,914,187 3,356,568 4,043,201 1,448,895 1,859,505 GDP + Change in Private 15,829,787 16,968,068 18,381,101 15,796,195 12,594,295 www.debtdeflation.com/blogs Page 2 of 5

Steve Keen s watch What Bernanke doesn t understand about deflation August 29, 2010 0.0% 7.2% 8.3% 14.1% 20.3% Private Government 6,556,391.0 6,893,467.0 7,321,592.0 8,615,051.0 10,167,585.0 478,851.0 337,076.0 428,125.0 1,293,459.0 1,552,534.0 Government GDP + Change 16,308,638.0 17,305,144.0 18,809,226.0 17,089,654.0 14,146,829.0 in Total Total 0.0% 6.1% 8.7% 9.1% 17.2% That sucking sound will continue for many years, because the level of debt that was racked up under Bernanke s watch, and that of his predecessor Alan Greenspan, was truly enormous. In the years from 1987, when Greenspan first rescued the financial system from its own follies, till 2009 when the US hit Peak, the US private sector added $34 trillion in debt. Over the same period, the USA s nominal GDP grew by a mere $9 trillion. Ignoring this growth in debt championing it even in the belief that the financial sector was being clever when in fact it was running a disguised Ponzi Scheme was the greatest failing of the Federal Reserve and its many counterparts around the world. Though this might beggar belief, there is nothing sinister in Bernanke s failure to realize this: it s a failing that he shares in common with the vast majority of economists. His problem is the theory he learnt in high school and university that he thought was simply economics as if it was the only way one could think about how the economy operated. In reality, it was Neoclassical economics, which is just one of the many schools of thought within economics. In the same way that Christianity is not the only religion in the world, there are other schools of thought in economics. And just as different religions have different beliefs, so too do schools of thought within economics only economists tend to call their beliefs assumptions because this sounds more scientific than beliefs. Let s call a spade a spade: two of the key beliefs of the Neoclassical school of thought are now coming to haunt Bernanke because they are false. These are that the economy is (almost) always in equilibrium, and that private debt doesn t matter. One of Bernanke s predecessors who also once believed these two things was Irving Fisher, and just like Bernanke, he was originally utterly flummoxed when the US economy collapsed from prosperity to Depression back in 1930. But ultimately he came around to a different way of thinking that he christened The Deflation Theory of Great Depressions (Fisher 1933). You would think Bernanke, as the alleged expert on the Great Depression after all, that s one of the main reasons he got the job as Chairman of the Federal Reserve had read Fisher s papers. And you d www.debtdeflation.com/blogs Page 3 of 5

Steve Keen s watch What Bernanke doesn t understand about deflation August 29, 2010 be right. But the problem is that he didn t understand them and here we come back to the belief problem. The Great Depression forced Fisher who was also a Neoclassical economist to realize that the belief that the economy was always in equilibrium was false. When Bernanke read Fisher, he completely failed to grasp this point. Just as a religious scholar from, for example, the Hindu tradition might completely miss the key points in the Christian Bible, Bernanke didn t even register how important abandoning the belief in equilibrium was to Fisher. To know this, all you have to do is read Bernanke s summary of Fisher in his Essays on the Great Depression: The idea of debt deflation goes back to Irving Fisher (1933). Fisher envisioned a dynamic process in which falling asset and commodity prices created pressure on nominal debtors, forcing them into distress sales of assets, which in turn led to further price declines and financial difficulties. His diagnosis led him to urge President Roosevelt to subordinate exchange rate considerations to the need for reflation, advice that (ultimately) FDR followed. Fisher s idea was less influential in academic circles, though, because of the counterargument that debt deflation represented no more than a redistribution from one group (debtors) to another (creditors). Absent implausibly large differences in marginal spending propensities among the groups, it was suggested, pure redistributions should have no significant macroeconomic effects. (Bernanke 2000, p. 24) There s no mention of disequilibrium there, and though Bernanke went on to try to develop the concept of debt deflation, he did so while maintaining the belief in equilibrium. Compare this to Fisher himself on how important disequilibrium really is in the real world: We may tentatively assume that, ordinarily and within wide limits, all, or almost all, economic variables tend, in a general way, toward a stable equilibrium But the exact equilibrium thus sought is seldom reached and never long maintained. New disturbances are, humanly speaking, sure to occur, so that, in actual fact, any variable is almost always above or below the ideal equilibrium It is as absurd to assume that, for any long period of time, the variables in the economic organization, or any part of them, will stay put, in perfect equilibrium, as to assume that the Atlantic Ocean can ever be without a wave. (Fisher 1933, p. 339) We might not be in such a pickle now if economics had started to become more of a science and less of a religion by following Fisher s lead, and abandoning key beliefs when reality made a mockery of them. But instead neoclassical economics completely rebuilt its belief system after the Great Depression, and www.debtdeflation.com/blogs Page 4 of 5

Steve Keen s watch What Bernanke doesn t understand about deflation August 29, 2010 here we are again, once more experiencing the disconnect between neoclassical beliefs and economic reality. For the record, here s my GDP plus change in debt table for the 1930s, to give us some idea of what the next decade or so might hold if, once again, we repeat the mistakes of our predecessors. Variable\Year 1929 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 GDP 103,600 91,200 76,500 58,700 56,400 66,000 73,300 6.0% 12.0% 16.1% 23.3% 3.9% 17.0% 11.1% Nominal GDP Inflation Rate 1.2% 0.0% 7.0% 10.1% 9.8% 2.3% 3.0% Private 161,800 161,100 148,400 137,100 127,900 125,300 124,500 Growth 3.7% 0.4% 7.9% 7.6% 6.7% 2.0% 0.6% Rate 5,700 700 12,700 11,300 9,200 2,600 800 GDP + 109,300 90,500 63,800 47,400 47,200 63,400 72,500 Private 0.0% 17.2% 29.5% 25.7% 0.4% 34.3% 14.4% Private Government 30,100 31,200 34,500 37,900 40,600 46,300 50,500 100 1,100 3,300 3,400 2,700 5,700 4,200 Government GDP + 109,200 91,600 67,100 50,800 49,900 69,100 76,700 Total Total 0.0% 16.1% 26.7% 24.3% 1.8% 38.5% 11.0% Bernanke, B. S. (2000). Essays on the Great Depression. Princeton, Princeton University Press. Fisher, I. (1933). "The Deflation Theory of Great Depressions." Econometrica 1(4): 337 357. www.debtdeflation.com/blogs Page 5 of 5