THE EFFECT OF SOCIAL SECURITY AUXILIARY SPOUSE AND SURVIVOR BENEFITS ON THE HOUSEHOLD RETIREMENT DECISION

Similar documents
The Effect of Social Security Auxiliary Spouse and Survivor s Benefits on the Household Retirement Decision

DIFFERENTIAL MORTALITY, UNCERTAIN MEDICAL EXPENSES, AND THE SAVING OF ELDERLY SINGLES

Saving for Retirement: Household Bargaining and Household Net Worth

Happy Together: A Structural Model of Couples Joint Retirement Choices

Saving During Retirement

Nordic Journal of Political Economy

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE GROWTH IN SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS AMONG THE RETIREMENT AGE POPULATION FROM INCREASES IN THE CAP ON COVERED EARNINGS

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES GENDER, MARRIAGE, AND LIFE EXPECTANCY. Margherita Borella Mariacristina De Nardi Fang Yang

CHAPTER 4 ESTIMATES OF RETIREMENT, SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFIT TAKE-UP, AND EARNINGS AFTER AGE 50

Couples and Singles Savings After Retirement

Medicaid Insurance and Redistribution in Old Age

Retirement, Saving, Benefit Claiming and Solvency Under A Partial System of Voluntary Personal Accounts

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE DECISION TO DELAY SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS: THEORY AND EVIDENCE. John B. Shoven Sita Nataraj Slavov

The Decision to Delay Social Security Benefits: Theory and Evidence

Social Security: Is a Key Foundation of Economic Security Working for Women?

The Effect of the Affordable Care Act on the Labor Supply, Savings, and Social Security of Older Americans

HOW DOES WOMEN WORKING AFFECT SOCIAL SECURITY REPLACEMENT RATES?

Diane Owens, Speaker & Consultant Step Up Your Social Security

Your Social Security Timing Report. Prepared for: Mr. & Mrs. Sample. Prepared by: Leverage Your Social Security

CHAPTER 11 CONCLUDING COMMENTS

Using Data for Couples to Project the Distributional Effects of Changes in Social Security Policy

WHY DO WOMEN CLAIM SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS SO EARLY?

The Behavioral and Consumption Effects of Social Security Changes

Coordinating the Household Retirement Decision

Pensions, Household Saving, and Welfare: A Dynamic Analysis of Crowd Out. David M. Blau. The Ohio State University and IZA

Life Expectancy and Old Age Savings

Reforming Medicaid Long Term Care Insurance

OLD-AGE POVERTY: SINGLE WOMEN & WIDOWS & A LACK OF RETIREMENT SECURITY

Research. Michigan. Center. Retirement. Social Security and Retirement Dynamics Alan L. Gustman and Thomas Steinmeier. Working Paper MR RC WP

Lifetime Distributional Effects of Social Security Retirement Benefits

Today s agenda. Social Security The choice of a lifetime. Social Security basics. Making your Social Security decision

Economic Preparation for Retirement and the Risk of Out-of-pocket Long-term Care Expenses

Accounting for Trends in the Labor Force Participation Rate of Older Men in the United States

Social Security and Your Retirement

Labor Supply Responses to Marginal Social Security Benefits: Evidence from Discontinuities *

Social Security Bene ts, Life Expectancy and Early Retirement

Are Americans Saving Optimally for Retirement?

WHAT REPLACEMENT RATES DO HOUSEHOLDS ACTUALLY EXPERIENCE IN RETIREMENT? Alicia H. Munnell and Mauricio Soto*

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Old, Sick Alone, and Poor: A Welfare Analysis of Old-Age Social Insurance Programs

Social Security Planning Strategies

Older Americans Would Work Longer If Jobs Were Flexible

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES EFFECTS OF SOCIAL SECURITY POLICIES ON BENEFIT CLAIMING, RETIREMENT AND SAVING. Alan L. Gustman Thomas L.

Labor Force Transitions at Older Ages: Burnout, Recovery, and Reverse Retirement

Social Security, Life Insurance and Annuities for Families

Retirement Saving, Annuity Markets, and Lifecycle Modeling. James Poterba 10 July 2008

Accounting for Patterns of Wealth Inequality

How Economic Security Changes during Retirement

The Effect of Social Security (Mis)information on the Labor Supply of Older Americans

In Debt and Approaching Retirement: Claim Social Security or Work Longer?

WHY DO MARRIED MEN CLAIM SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS SO EARLY? IGNORANCE OR CADDISHNESS? Steven A. Sass, Wei Sun, and Anthony Webb*

Research. Michigan. Center. Retirement. Marital Histories and Economic Well-Being Julie Zissimopoulos, Benjamin Karney and Amy Rauer.

Labor Supply Responses to the Social Security Tax-Benefit Link *

BENEFITS TO SURVIVORS

RETIREMENT INCENTIVES AND COUPLES RETIREMENT DECISIONS. Courtney Coile* CRR WP March 2003

Pensions, household saving, and welfare: A dynamic analysis of crowd out

Social Security Bene ts, Life Expectancy and Early Retirement

HCEO WORKING PAPER SERIES

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho

Drawing Down Retirement Wealth: Interactions between Social Security Wealth and Private Retirement Savings

The Economic Consequences of a Husband s Death: Evidence from the HRS and AHEAD

What is the status of Social Security? When should you draw benefits? How a Job Impacts Benefits... 8

Today s agenda. Social Security the choice of a lifetime. Social Security basics. Managing the discussion

The Social Security Early Entitlement Age In A Structural Model of Retirement and Wealth

abacus planning group

Private Pensions, Retirement Wealth and Lifetime Earnings

SOCIAL SECURITY AND RETIREMENT. Courtney Coile* Jonathan Gruber. CRR WP December 2000

Does It Pay to Delay Social Security? * John B. Shoven Stanford University and NBER. and. Sita Nataraj Slavov American Enterprise Institute.

When Will the Gender Gap in. Retirement Income Narrow?

Retirement and Social Security

What You Need to Know About Social Security

Social Security Planning Strategies

The Future of Retirement: How Has the Change in the Full Retirement Age Affected the Social Security Claiming Decisions of US Citizens?

Trying the Impossible - Financing 30-Year Retirements with 40-Year Careers: A Discussion of Social Security and Retirement Policy

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE FINANCIAL FEASIBILITY OF DELAYING SOCIAL SECURITY: EVIDENCE FROM ADMINISTRATIVE TAX DATA

Optimal portfolio choice with health-contingent income products: The value of life care annuities

CHAPTER 7 SUPPLEMENTAL SECURITY INCOME AND LIVING ARRANGEMENTS

Redistribution under OASDI: How Much and to Whom?

IMPACT OF THE SOCIAL SECURITY RETIREMENT EARNINGS TEST ON YEAR-OLDS

The Effects of Changes in Women s Labor Market Attachment on Redistribution under the Social Security Benefit Formula

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE SOCIAL SECURITY EARLY ENTITLEMENT AGE IN A STRUCTURAL MODEL OF RETIREMENT AND WEALTH

The labour force participation of older men in Canada

MULTIVARIATE FRACTIONAL RESPONSE MODELS IN A PANEL SETTING WITH AN APPLICATION TO PORTFOLIO ALLOCATION. Michael Anthony Carlton A DISSERTATION

Reforms to an Individual Account Pension System and their. Effects on Work and Contribution Decisions: The Case of Chile. Viviana Vélez-Grajales

Social Security and Medicare: A Survey of Benefits

THE BEHAVIORAL AND CONSUMPTION EFFECTS OF SOCIAL SECURITY CHANGES. Wenliang Hou and Geoffrey T. Sanzenbacher. CRR WP September 2017

Ch In other countries the replacement rate is often higher. In the Netherlands it is over 90%. This means that after taxes Dutch workers receive

HOW IMPORTANT IS MEDICARE ELIGIBILITY IN THE TIMING OF RETIREMENT?

Demographic and Economic Characteristics of Children in Families Receiving Social Security

Jamie Hopkins, Esq., MBA, LLM, CFP, CLU, RICP Co-Director of the New York Life Center for Retirement Income, Associate Professor of Taxation

Late-Career Job Loss and Retirement Behavior of Couples

The Trajectory of Wealth in Retirement

Maximizing your Family Benefits. Prepared for: Jim and Mary Sample. Prepared by: Robert Esch

CHAPTER 7 U. S. SOCIAL SECURITY ADMINISTRATION OFFICE OF THE ACTUARY PROJECTIONS METHODOLOGY

HOW TO POTENTIALLY OPTIMIZE SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS

Obesity, Disability, and Movement onto the DI Rolls

Social Security Planning Strategies

Fast Facts & Figures About Social Security, 2005

Gender Issues and Social Security Reform: Assessing the Role of Social Security and Personal Savings in Well-Being During Retirement

Social Security: Revisiting Benefits for Spouses and Survivors

Transcription:

THE EFFECT OF SOCIAL SECURITY AUXILIARY SPOUSE AND SURVIVOR BENEFITS ON THE HOUSEHOLD RETIREMENT DECISION DAVID M. K. KNAPP DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN AUGUST 7, 2014 KNAPP (2014) 1/12

CONTRIBUTION I This study answers the question: How responsive are household retirement decisions to spouse and survivor benefits? KNAPP (2014) 2/12

CONTRIBUTION I This study answers the question: How responsive are household retirement decisions to spouse and survivor benefits? I I I Work Benefit Claiming Savings KNAPP (2014) 2/12

SPOUSAL BENEFIT EXAMPLE Individual Entitlement Single Income Dual Income Husband $2000 Wife $0 Husband $1000 Wife $1000 KNAPP (2014) 3/12

SPOUSAL BENEFIT EXAMPLE With no Spouse Benefits Single Income Dual Income Individual Entitlement Husband $2000 Wife $0 Husband $1000 Wife $1000 Household Entitlement $2000 $2000 KNAPP (2014) 3/12

SPOUSAL BENEFIT EXAMPLE Spousal Benefit = max {own benefit, 50% spouse s benefit} Single Income Dual Income Individual Entitlement Husband $2000 Wife $0 Husband $1000 Wife $1000 Spouse Benefit Household Entitlement $1000 $3000 (") KNAPP (2014) 3/12

SPOUSAL BENEFIT EXAMPLE Spousal Benefit = max {own benefit, 50% spouse s benefit} Single Income Dual Income Individual Entitlement Husband $2000 Wife $0 Husband $1000 Wife $1000 Spouse Benefit Household Entitlement $1000 $3000 (") $0 $2000 (no D) KNAPP (2014) 3/12

SURVIVOR S BENEFIT EXAMPLE Survivor Benefit = max {own benefit, deceased s benefit} Single Income Dual Income Individual Entitlement Husband $2000 Wife $0 Husband $1000 Wife $1000 Survivor Benefit Household Entitlement $2000 $2000 KNAPP (2014) 3/12

SURVIVOR S BENEFIT EXAMPLE Survivor Benefit = max {own benefit, deceased s benefit} Single Income Dual Income Individual Entitlement Husband $2000 Wife $0 Husband $1000 Wife $1000 Survivor Benefit Household Entitlement $2000 $2000 $1000 $1000 KNAPP (2014) 3/12

SPOUSAL AND SURVIVOR S BENEFIT EXAMPLE I Spouse Benefit: Can only claim if spouse has claimed benefit. I Survivor Benefit: Reduced based on when the deceased claimed benefit KNAPP (2014) 3/12

SPOUSE AND SURVIVOR BENEFITS In 2012, I Survivor Benefits = 14% of Social Security Expenditures I Spouse Benefits = 4% Future Knowledge KNAPP (2014) 4/12

SPOUSE AND SURVIVOR BENEFITS In 2012, I Survivor Benefits = 14% of Social Security Expenditures I Spouse Benefits = 4% I Survivor Benefits = $88 billion I Spouse Benefits = $24 billion Future Knowledge KNAPP (2014) 4/12

SPOUSE AND SURVIVOR BENEFITS In 2012, I Survivor Benefits = 14% of Social Security Expenditures I Spouse Benefits = 4% I Survivor Benefits = $88 billion I Spouse Benefits = $24 billion I I I Larger than 2012 budget of 27 U.S. state governments Larger than total amount of money spend of aid to families with dependent children (TANF - $17b, 2012) Larger than Canada s 2013 total military expenditures ($22.5b) Future Knowledge KNAPP (2014) 4/12

SPOUSE AND SURVIVOR BENEFITS In 2012, I Survivor Benefits = 14% of Social Security Expenditures I Spouse Benefits = 4% I Survivor Benefits = $88 billion I Spouse Benefits = $24 billion I I I Larger than 2012 budget of 27 U.S. state governments Larger than total amount of money spend of aid to families with dependent children (TANF - $17b, 2012) Larger than Canada s 2013 total military expenditures ($22.5b) I Social Security checks make up the majority of monthly incomes for 53% of couples and 74% of non-married individuals (SSA, 2011) Future Knowledge KNAPP (2014) 4/12

DECISIONS KNAPP (2014) 5/12

DECISIONS KNAPP (2014) 5/12

DECISIONS KNAPP (2014) 5/12

DECISIONS KNAPP (2014) 5/12

DECISIONS KNAPP (2014) 5/12

DECISIONS -SIMULTANEOUSLY KNAPP (2014) 5/12

DECISIONS -SIMULTANEOUSLY KNAPP (2014) 5/12

UNCERTAINTY KNAPP (2014) 6/12

UNCERTAINTY KNAPP (2014) 6/12

DYNAMIC DECISIONS Recursive Form KNAPP (2014) 6/12

DYNAMIC DECISIONS Recursive Form KNAPP (2014) 6/12

DATA Health and Retirement Study (1992-2010) I 12,652 individuals and 4,844 married households in 1992 I I Reduced sample will be 1,728 married households Elimination: Ever applied for disability & missing Pension or Social Security I Estimation: 948 households (born between 1931-35) I Validation: 1,081 households (born between 1936-41) Data Selection I Collects Social Security earnings histories and W-2 earnings I Collected Pension Plan information from employers I Up to 10 interviews for a household KNAPP (2014) 7/12

DATA Health and Retirement Study (1992-2010) I 12,652 individuals and 4,844 married households in 1992 I Estimation: 948 households (born between 1931-35) I Validation: 1,081 households (born between 1936-41) Data Selection I Collects Social Security earnings histories and W-2 earnings I Collected Pension Plan information from employers I I Able to capture each household s unique incentives Estimation procedure chosen to capture this richness I Up to 10 interviews for a household KNAPP (2014) 7/12

DATA Health and Retirement Study (1992-2010) I 12,652 individuals and 4,844 married households in 1992 I Collects Social Security earnings histories and W-2 earnings I Collected Pension Plan information from employers I Up to 10 interviews for a household I Average of 14.95 annual observations I My sample uses a more extensive longitudinal history than most structural papers e.g. van der Klaauw and Wolpin (2008) use three waves I Most of the sample will be older than 70 by 2010 KNAPP (2014) 7/12

SOLUTION CONCEPT -METHOD OF SIMULATED MOMENTS Method of Simulated Moments KNAPP (2014) 8/12

SOLUTION CONCEPT -METHOD OF SIMULATED MOMENTS KNAPP (2014) 8/12

SOLUTION CONCEPT -METHOD OF SIMULATED MOMENTS KNAPP (2014) 8/12

SOLUTION CONCEPT -METHOD OF SIMULATED MOMENTS KNAPP (2014) 8/12

SOLUTION CONCEPT -METHOD OF SIMULATED MOMENTS KNAPP (2014) 8/12

SOLUTION CONCEPT -METHOD OF SIMULATED MOMENTS KNAPP (2014) 8/12

SOLUTION CONCEPT -METHOD OF SIMULATED MOMENTS Method of Simulated Moments KNAPP (2014) 8/12

MODEL FIT Baseline Results Model Fit I The model can capture many of the important details of the data: I Asset accumulation with age I Decline in Labor force participation with age I Capture spikes in male labor force exit at 62 & 65 I Capture significant benefit claiming at age 62 I Capture joint retirement spike KNAPP (2014) 9/12

EXPERIMENTS Conduct counterfactual experiments, such as: 1. Reduce or Eliminate the Spousal Benefit 2. Reduce or Eliminate Spouse and Survivor Benefits 3. Increase Progressivity of Social Security from 90%-32%-15% to 90%-22.4%-10.5% I One of the proposals from the 1994-96 Social Security Advisory Council Primary Benefit Example 4. Increase Normal Retirement Age by two years. KNAPP (2014) 10/12

EFFECT ON WOMEN KNAPP (2014) 11/12

EFFECT ON MEN KNAPP (2014) 11/12

CONCLUSION I This study answers the question: How responsive are household retirement decisions to spouse and survivor benefits? KNAPP (2014) 12/12

CONCLUSION I This study answers the question: How responsive are household retirement decisions to spouse and survivor benefits? I Findings: I Spousal benefits: Small effect (about 1 2-2 months) on women (") and men (#) I Spousal benefits: Substitution effect of dominates the income effect for men. I Spouse and survivor benefits: Large, heterogenous participation effects! WOMEN: " 5-16 months MEN: # 6 months, when eliminated KNAPP (2014) 12/12

CONCLUSION I This study answers the question: How responsive are household retirement decisions to spouse and survivor benefits? I Findings: I Spousal benefits: Small effect (about 1 2-2 months) on women (") and men (#) I Spousal benefits: Substitution effect of dominates the income effect for men. I Spouse and survivor benefits: Large, heterogenous participation effects! WOMEN: " 5-16 months MEN: # 6 months, when eliminated, " 3 months when reduced 50% KNAPP (2014) 12/12

CONCLUSION I This study answers the question: How responsive are household retirement decisions to spouse and survivor benefits? I Findings: I Heterogeneous effects of these policies on labor force participation. I Up to 1.53 years in highest asset tertile ) Large annuity demand I Claiming: # 3-5% at age 62 I Savings to the Social Security Trust Fund: Reducing 50% = 74.1% savings from elimination KNAPP (2014) 12/12

THANK YOU

EVOLUTION OF HEALTH STATUS Back

MORTALITY RATES BASED ON HEALTH STATUS Back

EVOLUTION OF NON-TENURED WAGES Back

MEDIAN ANNUAL EARNINGS, DATA *Non-baseline Jobs Back

MEDIAN ANNUAL HOURS, DATA *Non-baseline Jobs Back

BENEFITS OF DELAYED CLAIMING Average Yearly Income over lifetime Claim at 62 Claim at 70 Difference (50% U.S. Avg. Wage) $21,489.81 $705 $1,249 $544 (100% U.S. Avg. Wage) $42,979.61 $1,106 $1,959 $853 (200% U.S. Avg. Wage) $85,959.22 $1,593 $2,823 $1,230 TABLE : Approximate Social Security Benefit based on Claim Age Back

PRIMARY BENEFIT EXAMPLE I A worker, born in 1942, reaches age 60 in 2002. I Average Indexed Monthly Earnings (AIME) = Â Best 35 years of Indexed Earnings 35 years 12 months = $6787 I Monthly benefit if worker retires at Normal Retirement age (65 and 10 months for this worker) then he receives: I 90% of his first $612 I 32% of his next $3, 689 $612 = $3, 077 I 15% of the rest. I Primary Insurance Amount (PIA) = ($612 0.9) + (3077 0.32) + (3098 0.15) = $2000 Back to Intro Back to Experiments

PENSION BENEFIT GROWTH BY AGE Back

CHANGE IN AVERAGE MALE LABOR SUPPLY Back

CHANGE IN AVERAGE MALE LABOR SUPPLY Back

CHANGE IN AVERAGE MALE CLAIMING Back

CHANGE IN AVERAGE FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY Back

CHANGE IN AVERAGE FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY Back

CHANGE IN AVERAGE FEMALE CLAIMING Back

KNOWLEDGE OF SPOUSE ELIGIBILITY TO COLLECT SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS Note: From AARP study: Assessing Current and Future Beneficiaries Knowledge of Social Security Benefits, 2011. Reported results based on focus groups of individuals from a suburb of Chicago, Illinois and Baltimore, Maryland. This table is restricted to only individuals who are married, widowed, divorced, or separated. This study also shows that 97% of individuals are aware of the survivor benefit. Back

KNOWLEDGE OF SPOUSE ELIGIBILITY TO COLLECT SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS Knowledge of Spousal benefits by Income, Work history, and Sex (conditional on not claiming) Household Income Men Women x < $30, 000 42% 64% $30, 000 apple x < $60, 000 46% 54% $60, 000 apple x < $100, 000 59% 49% $100, 000 apple x 40% 50% Respondent has less than 20 work years. 62% Respondent has at least 20 work years 48% 53% Spouse with less than 20 work years 60%. Spouse with at least 20 work years 46% 54% Note: Author s Calculations using data from the AARP study: Assessing Current and Future Beneficiaries Knowledge of Social Security Benefits, 2011. Reported results based on focus groups of individuals from a suburb of Chicago, Illinois and Baltimore, Maryland. This table is restricted to only individuals who are married, widowed, divorced, or separated. This study also shows that 97% of individuals are aware of the survivor benefit. Back

EXPECTED CHANGE IN SPOUSAL BENEFIT ELIGIBILITY BY COHORT Note: From Wu, Karamcheva, Munnell, and Purcell. CRR Working Paper 2013-16, Table 7. Projections based on The Urban Institute s Modeling Income in the Near Term (MINT) simulation program produced for the Social Security Administration. Back

DIFFERENT APPROACHES Back Wages Social Security Pensions Medical Expenses & Health Insurance Representative Individual Permit Wage Uncertainty (most) Simplified Transition Function (most) Based on Social Security (French & Jones, 2011) Rust & Phelan, 1997 Blau & Gilleskie, 2006 Solves Model for: Each Household Fixed Wage Paths (Gustman & Steinmeier, this paper) Individual Earnings Histories (Gustman & Steinmeier, this paper) Individual s Employer Reports (Gustman & Steinmeier, this paper) (this paper) Bequests Consumption Floors Preference Heterogeneity Denardi, French, & Jones, 2011 Hubbard, Skinner, & Zeldes, 1995 van der Klaauw & Wolpin, 2008 French & Jones, 2011 (this paper) (this paper) (this paper)

DIFFERENT APPROACHES Back This paper French & Jones 2011 van der Klaauw & Wolpin 2008 Gustman & Steinmeier, 1986-? Blau & Gilleskie, 2006 Estimation Method MSM MSM II MSM ML Solve Individually X X Interview waves used in sample 10 8 3 5-6 4 Moments Matched on Asset Levels X X X Include Married 1 X X Households 2 X Individuals Choose when to X X Claim Benefits Individuals face uncertain Medical Expenses X X X Wage Uncertainty X X X Job Search Preference Heterogeneity Fixed, by Own & Joint Leisure Pref. Predicted, by Own Leisure Pref. X Predicted, by Sex Based on Self-Rpt Retirement None

WHAT HAPPENS WHEN WE DIE? Back to Preferences When one member of the household dies, I must make an assumption for what happens to the household utility. I Economies of scale: $1 of consumption in a two person household = $1.50 of consumption in a widowed household i.e. C single = 1.5 C married I Consumption Floor: follows a similar rule I Preferences: I U Ch,t, L W,t = at C1 1 h(single),t 1 a t + D W,tL 1 gw,t W,t 1 1 g W,t I bh,sp,t(s) 1 [Wife works] + b H,SFT,t(s) 1 [Wife works full-time] = 0 I Preference Type remains unchanged I Pensions and Social Security: The deceased s DB pension plan ends, and Social Security converts to a widow benefit (if applicable) KNAPP (2014) 33/12

METHOD OF SIMULATED MOMENTS Back to MSM I use a two-step Method of Simulated Moment (MSM) procedure (Gourchinas & Parker, 2002; French, 2005) I First step (c): I I The earnings profiles and health & mortality transitions are estimated from the data Other parameters are calibrated: r = 4%, Leisure Endowment (L) = 4, Economies of Scale: C single = 1.5 C married KNAPP (2014) 34/12

METHOD OF SIMULATED MOMENTS Back to MSM I use a two-step Method of Simulated Moment (MSM) procedure (Gourchinas & Parker, 2002; French, 2005) I Second step: Given ĉ, preference parameters q = a t, d t, k, q B, c min, g i,t, b i,t(s), b i,age,b i,health, b i,sp,t(s), b i,sft,t(s) o, are estimated, using MSM: I I I solve for each household s optimal set of decision rules, by backward recursion, then simulate 200 life cycle histories per household for random realizations of health, mortality, and medical expenses (189,600 life cycle profiles), then match moments from the simulated life cycles with moments from the data. KNAPP (2014) 34/12

DATA Back I Data comes from the Health and Retirement Study (HRS), 1992-2010. I From the original HRS sample of 4,844 married households at baseline, I keep households that 1. are not missing spousal information in wave 1 [4,584], 2. are not missing information on their labor force participation or birth year in wave 1 [4,575], 3. never apply for Social Security disability benefits [3,300], 4. are without missing pension or Social Security information [2,197], 5. have a spousal age difference of less than 10 years [1,943], and 6. are not missing information on individual earnings if household members report working [1,898]. 7. have no more than one pension [1,728]. I After this sample selection, I am left with 1,728 married households. I I will use only households with at least one member born between 1931-35 for main analysis: 948 married households. I I use the rest of the sample for a validation test. KNAPP (2014) 35/12

HEALTH AND MORTALITY Back I Individuals can take on one of two state possible health states: I I Good (self reported in Excellent, Very good, or Good health) Bad (self reported in Fair or Poor health) I Construct transition probabilities using a logit model, where I I Probability of transitioning health states is a function of previous health status, gender, and age Health Probability of survival is a function of previous health status, gender, and age Mortality KNAPP (2014) 36/12

HEALTH INSURANCE AND MEDICAL EXPENSES Back Households can have one of three types of health insurance (HI) through their baseline job: I Retiree - if he or she leaves baseline job, then HI is preserved I Tied - if he or she leaves baseline job, then HI is lost I None Medical expenses take on a log-normal distribution I Stochastic and transitory (not persistent like in French and Jones, 2011) I Depend on age, health, health insurance, and work status. KNAPP (2014) 37/12

BEQUESTS Back As in De Nardi (2004), households value their bequests from assets, A T, in the last period T according to the function b(a t )= q B 1 a t (A T + k) 1 a t where k is a bequest shifter and q B is a measure of bequest intensity. KNAPP (2014) 38/12

ANNUAL EARNINGS Back I Earnings are known to the individual (i.e. there is no wage uncertainty) I Baseline Jobs: I I Assume 0% nominal wage growth - consistent with data Must be fixed in order to use pension calculator I Non-baseline Jobs (NB): I I I Every individual, regardless of baseline is eligible for a full-time (FT) or part-time (PT) job FT-NB earnings: determined from a fixed-effect regression of log wages on a quartic in age and quadratic in tenure, conditional on FT-NB PT-NB earnings: determined from a fixed-effect regression of log wages on a quartic in age, conditional on PT-NB. Mean Annual Earnings Profiles KNAPP (2014) 39/12

BASELINE RESULTS Back Parameters based on type Preference Type Type 0 Type 1 Type 2 Type 3 Type 4 (Work,Spouse) (Out) (Low, Low) (High, Low) (Low, High) (High, High) a t 3.1480 2.8592 2.8193 2.9502 2.8736 Consumption (0.0924) (0.0085) (0.0096) (0.0102) (0.0082) d t 0.9072 0.8903 0.9242 0.9414 0.9013 Discount Rate (0.0205) (0.0079) (0.0095) (0.0089) (0.0083) g H,t 1.7676 1.5762 1.6042 1.7080 1.5685 Husband s Leisure (0.1173) (0.0521) (0.0666) (0.0492) (0.0440) g W,t 1.2338 1.0051 1.0065 1.0595 1.1624 Wife s Leisure (0.0913) (0.0682) (0.0246) (0.0343) (0.0518) KNAPP (2014) 40/12

BASELINE RESULTS Back Parameters based on type Preference Type Type 0 Type 1 Type 2 Type 3 Type 4 (Work,Spouse) (Out) (Low, Low) (High, Low) (Low, High) (High, High) a t 3.1480 2.8592 2.8193 2.9502 2.8736 Consumption (0.0924) (0.0085) (0.0096) (0.0102) (0.0082) d t 0.9072 0.8903 0.9242 0.9414 0.9013 Discount Rate (0.0205) (0.0079) (0.0095) (0.0089) (0.0083) g H,t 1.7676 1.5762 1.6042 1.7080 1.5685 Husband s Leisure (0.1173) (0.0521) (0.0666) (0.0492) (0.0440) g W,t 1.2338 1.0051 1.0065 1.0595 1.1624 Wife s Leisure (0.0913) (0.0682) (0.0246) (0.0343) (0.0518) KNAPP (2014) 40/12

BASELINE RESULTS Back Parameters based on type Preference Type Type 0 Type 1 Type 2 Type 3 Type 4 (Work,Spouse) (Out) (Low, Low) (High, Low) (Low, High) (High, High) a t 3.1480 2.8592 2.8193 2.9502 2.8736 Consumption (0.0924) (0.0085) (0.0096) (0.0102) (0.0082) d t 0.9072 0.8903 0.9242 0.9414 0.9013 Discount Rate (0.0205) (0.0079) (0.0095) (0.0089) (0.0083) g H,t 1.7676 1.5762 1.6042 1.7080 1.5685 Husband s Leisure (0.1173) (0.0521) (0.0666) (0.0492) (0.0440) g W,t 1.2338 1.0051 1.0065 1.0595 1.1624 Wife s Leisure (0.0913) (0.0682) (0.0246) (0.0343) (0.0518) KNAPP (2014) 40/12

BASELINE RESULTS Back Husband Wife Parameters based on type Preference Type Type 0 Type 1 Type 2 Type 3 Type 4 (Work,Spouse) (Out) (Low, Low) (High, Low) (Low, High) (High, High) b H,t(s) -18.8057-19.8134-19.9252 Leisure Weight (0.6725) (0.1032) (0.1237) b W,t(s) -19.7558-19.7589-20.2805 Leisure Weight (1.4704) (0.1018) (0.1207) b H,SP,t(s) -0.0910-0.0203-0.0201 Participation (0.8783) (0.0015) (0.0010) b H,SFT,t(s) -0.0661-0.1411-0.0817 Full-time work (0.7060) (0.0089) (0.0039) b W,SP,t(s) -0.0698-0.0055-0.0222 Participation (0.0023) (0.0005) (0.0014) b W,SFT,t(s) -0.0845-0.0857-0.1224 Full-time work (0.2974) (0.0071) (0.0042) KNAPP (2014) 41/12

BASELINE RESULTS Parameters common to all types Recall, Back b H,age 0.1852 k 297,050 Husband s Age-60 (0.0039) Bequest Shifter (3464.7198) b W,age 0.1904 q B 114,364 Wife s Age-60 (0.0046) Bequest intensity (2708.1382) b H,health 1.1037 Husband s Health (0.0262) b W,health 0.9233 c min 5,667 Wife s Health (0.0367) Consumption Floor (70.5925) D H,t = exp b H,t(s) + b H,age age H,t + b H,health health H,t +b H,SP,t(s) 1 [Wife works] + b H,SFT,t(s) 1 [Wife works full-time] KNAPP (2014) 42/12

BASELINE RESULTS Back Parameters common to all types b H,age 0.1852 k 297,050 Husband s Age-60 (0.0039) Bequest Shifter (3464.7198) b W,age 0.1904 q B 114,364 Wife s Age-60 (0.0046) Bequest intensity (2708.1382) b H,health 1.1037 Husband s Health (0.0262) b W,health 0.9233 c min 5,667 Wife s Health (0.0367) Consumption Floor (70.5925) I b i,age > 0 )As i ages, he or she substitutes towards more leisure I b i,health > 0 )If i falls into poor health, he or she substitutes towards more leisure KNAPP (2014) 42/12

BASELINE RESULTS Back Parameters common to all types b H,age 0.1852 k 297,050 Husband s Age-60 (0.0039) Bequest Shifter (3464.7198) b W,age 0.1904 q B 114,364 Wife s Age-60 (0.0046) Bequest intensity (2708.1382) b H,health 1.1037 Husband s Health (0.0262) b W,health 0.9233 c min 5,667 Wife s Health (0.0367) Consumption Floor (70.5925) c min is the consumption floor I $7,687 - annual value of 2012 SSI benefits discounted to 1992 $ I French and Jones (2011) = $4,380 I Households at all levels are sensitive to this parameter (Hubbard, Skinner, and Zeldes, 1995) KNAPP (2014) 42/12

BASELINE RESULTS Parameters common to all types Back b H,age 0.1852 k 297,050 Husband s Age-60 (0.0039) Bequest Shifter (3464.7198) b W,age 0.1904 q B 114,364 Wife s Age-60 (0.0046) Bequest intensity (2708.1382) b H,health 1.1037 Husband s Health (0.0262) b W,health 0.9233 c min 5,667 Wife s Health (0.0367) Consumption Floor (70.5925) q B, k can be hard to interpret I Individual s have a significant incentive to bequeath final assets I Marginal propensity to consume is only $0.02 out of last $1 I Similar to French and Jones, 2011 but the bequest motive is operational for people in the top two-thirds of the asset distribution KNAPP (2014) 42/12

PREFERENCE TYPES Back Households can take on 1 of five discrete preference types, based on I Preference for own leisure (High or Low) I Preference for joint leisure (High or Low) I If no one in the household worked the first period, then they are treated as part of a separate out group KNAPP (2014) 43/12

PREFERENCE TYPES Back I Regress individual labor force participation in post-1998 on I quartic in age, I individual health status (1992), I assets (1992), I earnings (1992), I health insurance status (1992), I the individual s AIME (1992), I defined benefit flow (if eligible - 1992), I marital status, and I a full set of interactions of these terms. KNAPP (2014) 44/12

PREFERENCE TYPES Back I Regress individual labor force participation in post-1998 on I three variables pertaining to the individual s preference for work: 1. Even if I didn t need the money, I would probably keep on working. (Agree or disagree) 2. When you think about the time when you and your husband or wife will retire, are you looking forward to it, are you uneasy about it, or what? 3. On a scale of 1 to 10, how much do you enjoy your job? KNAPP (2014) 44/12

PREFERENCE TYPES Back I Regress individual labor force participation in post-1998 on I Four more variables the pertain to the individual s preference for his or her spouse: 1. Generally speaking, would you say that the time you spend together with your husband or wife is extremely enjoyable, very enjoyable, somewhat enjoyable, or not too enjoyable? 2. When it comes to making major family decisions, who has the final say you or your husband or wife? 3. Some couples like to spend their free time doing things together, while others like to do different things in their free time. What about you and your husband or wife? (together, separate, or sometimes together and sometimes separate) 4. I am going to read you a list of things that some people say are good about retirement. For each one, please tell me if, for you, they are very important, moderately important, somewhat important, or not important at all. Having more time with husband or wife. KNAPP (2014) 44/12

PREFERENCE TYPES Back I Estimated separately for men and women. I For each individual, the work preference index is the sum of the work preference coefficients multiplied by their respective independent variables, I Similarly for the spouse preference index. I The household s work or spouse preference index is simply the equally weighted sum for each household member s respective preference indices. I The household preference indices are then converted into binary measures by partitioning them at each measures median. KNAPP (2014) 45/12

PREFERENCE TYPES Back Work preference index is I positively correlated with marriage, earnings, assets, AIME, defined-benefit pension flows I negatively correlated with health Spouse preference index is I positively correlated with assets and health, I negatively correlated with earnings and AIME KNAPP (2014) 46/12

RECURSIVE FORMULATION Back Households, h, maximize the present value of their discounted lifetime utility n V t (X t ) = max U (C h,t, L h,t ) + d t 1 s H t+1 1 s W t+1 b(a t+1 ) C t,l t,b t +d t 1 s H t+1 s W t+1 E [V t+1 (X t+1 X t, t, C t, B t, N t, wife survives)] +d t s H t+1 1 s W t+1 E [V t+1 (X t+1 X t, t, C t, B t, N t, husband survives)] o +d t s H t+1 sw t+1 E [V t+1 (X t+1 X t, t, C t, B t, N t, both survive)] subject to the budget constraint and the consumption floor. I d t is the discount factor is the probability of surviving to period t + 1 conditional on surviving to t Details I s i t+1 I b(a t+1 ) is a warm glow bequest (De Nardi, 2004) Details KNAPP (2014) 47/12

RECURSIVE FORMULATION Back Households, h, maximize the present value of their discounted lifetime utility n V t (X t ) = max U (C h,t, L h,t ) + d t 1 s H t+1 1 s W t+1 b(a t+1 ) C t,l t,b t +d t 1 s H t+1 s W t+1 E [V t+1 (X t+1 X t, t, C t, B t, N t, wife survives)] +d t s H t+1 1 s W t+1 E [V t+1 (X t+1 X t, t, C t, B t, N t, husband survives)] o +d t s H t+1 sw t+1 E [V t+1 (X t+1 X t, t, C t, B t, N t, both survive)] subject to the budget constraint and the consumption floor. I d t is the discount factor is the probability of surviving to period t + 1 conditional on surviving to t Details I s i t+1 I b(a t+1 ) is a warm glow bequest (De Nardi, 2004) Details KNAPP (2014) 47/12

RECURSIVE FORMULATION Back Households, h, maximize the present value of their discounted lifetime utility n V t (X t ) = max U (C h,t, L h,t ) + d t 1 s H t+1 1 s W t+1 b(a t+1 ) C t,l t,b t +d t 1 s H t+1 s W t+1 E [V t+1 (X t+1 X t, t, C t, B t, N t, wife survives)] +d t s H t+1 1 s W t+1 E [V t+1 (X t+1 X t, t, C t, B t, N t, husband survives)] o +d t s H t+1 sw t+1 E [V t+1 (X t+1 X t, t, C t, B t, N t, both survive)] subject to the budget constraint and the consumption floor. I d t is the discount factor is the probability of surviving to period t + 1 conditional on surviving to t Details I s i t+1 I b(a t+1 ) is a warm glow bequest (De Nardi, 2004) Details KNAPP (2014) 47/12

METHOD OF SIMULATED MOMENTS MSM Detail Back I match the following moments predicted by the model for ages 58-69: 1. Mean assets by tertile, for the first two thirds, (thirds age = 2 12 moments) 2. Share of households within each asset tertile by prefence type, (t thirds age = 5 2 12 moments) 3. Labor force participation by preference type, (t sex age = 5 2 12 moments) 4. Percent working full-time, ((t 1) sex age = 4 2 12 moments) - excludes out type which does not work in the first period 5. Labor force participation by health status, (health status sex age = 2 2 12 moments) for a total of 34 12 = 408 moments. KNAPP (2014) 48/12

METHOD OF SIMULATED MOMENTS MSM Detail Back I match the following moments predicted by the model for ages 58-69: 1. Mean assets by tertile, for the first two thirds, (thirds age = 2 12 moments) 2. Share of households within each asset tertile by prefence type, (t thirds age = 5 2 12 moments) 3. Labor force participation by preference type, (t sex age = 5 2 12 moments) 4. Percent working full-time, ((t 1) sex age = 4 2 12 moments) - excludes out type which does not work in the first period 5. Labor force participation by health status, (health status sex age = 2 2 12 moments) for a total of 34 12 = 408 moments. KNAPP (2014) 48/12

METHOD OF SIMULATED MOMENTS MSM Detail Back I match the following moments predicted by the model for ages 58-69: 1. Mean assets by tertile, for the first two thirds, (thirds age = 2 12 moments) 2. Share of households within each asset tertile by prefence type, (t thirds age = 5 2 12 moments) 3. Labor force participation by preference type, (t sex age = 5 2 12 moments) 4. Percent working full-time, ((t 1) sex age = 4 2 12 moments) - excludes out type which does not work in the first period 5. Labor force participation by health status, (health status sex age = 2 2 12 moments) for a total of 34 12 = 408 moments. KNAPP (2014) 48/12

METHOD OF SIMULATED MOMENTS MSM Detail Back I match the following moments predicted by the model for ages 58-69: 1. Mean assets by tertile, for the first two thirds, (thirds age = 2 12 moments) 2. Share of households within each asset tertile by prefence type, (t thirds age = 5 2 12 moments) 3. Labor force participation by preference type, (t sex age = 5 2 12 moments) 4. Percent working full-time, ((t 1) sex age = 4 2 12 moments) - excludes out type which does not work in the first period 5. Labor force participation by health status, (health status sex age = 2 2 12 moments) for a total of 34 12 = 408 moments. KNAPP (2014) 48/12

METHOD OF SIMULATED MOMENTS MSM Detail Back I match the following moments predicted by the model for ages 58-69: 1. Mean assets by tertile, for the first two thirds, (thirds age = 2 12 moments) 2. Share of households within each asset tertile by prefence type, (t thirds age = 5 2 12 moments) 3. Labor force participation by preference type, (t sex age = 5 2 12 moments) 4. Percent working full-time, ((t 1) sex age = 4 2 12 moments) - excludes out type which does not work in the first period 5. Labor force participation by health status, (health status sex age = 2 2 12 moments) for a total of 34 12 = 408 moments. KNAPP (2014) 48/12

METHOD OF SIMULATED MOMENTS MSM Detail Back I match the following moments predicted by the model for ages 58-69: 1. Mean assets by tertile, for the first two thirds, (thirds age = 2 12 moments) 2. Share of households within each asset tertile by prefence type, (t thirds age = 5 2 12 moments) 3. Labor force participation by preference type, (t sex age = 5 2 12 moments) 4. Percent working full-time, ((t 1) sex age = 4 2 12 moments) - excludes out type which does not work in the first period 5. Labor force participation by health status, (health status sex age = 2 2 12 moments) for a total of 34 12 = 408 moments. KNAPP (2014) 48/12

BASELINE RESULTS Detail Back Parameters based on type a t g (2.81, 3.15) H,t Consumption Husband s Leisure (1.65, 1.77) d t g (0.890, 0.942) W,t Discount Rate Wife s Leisure (1.00, 1.24) Recall, *all significant at 1% 1 g H,t U (C h,t, L H,t, L W,t ) = C1 a t h,t 1 + D H,tLH,t 1 + D W,tL 1 a t 1 g H,t 1 g W,t W,t 1 1 g W,t KNAPP (2014) 49/12

BASELINE RESULTS Detail Back Parameters based on type a t g (2.81, 3.15) H,t Consumption Husband s Leisure (1.65, 1.77) d t g (0.890, 0.942) W,t Discount Rate Wife s Leisure (1.00, 1.24) *all significant at 1% Constant Relative Risk Aversion coefficient (CRRA): a t 2 (2.81, 3.15) KNAPP (2014) 49/12

BASELINE RESULTS Detail Back Parameters based on type a t g (2.81, 3.15) H,t Consumption Husband s Leisure (1.65, 1.77) d t g (0.890, 0.942) W,t Discount Rate Wife s Leisure (1.00, 1.24) CRRA: a t 2 (2.81, 3.15) *all significant at 1% I Compared to close to 1 in most of the literature that does not include assets in moment matching I Compared to > 3 in macro literature on CRRA and French & Jones, 2011 KNAPP (2014) 49/12

BASELINE RESULTS Detail Back Husband Wife Parameters based on type Preference for Joint Leisure: Out Low High b H,SP,t(s) -0.0910-0.0203-0.0201 Participation (0.8783) (0.0015) (0.0010) b H,SFT,t(s) -0.0661-0.1411-0.0817 Full-time work (0.7060) (0.0089) (0.0039) b W,SP,t(s) -0.0698-0.0055-0.0222 Participation (0.0023) (0.0005) (0.0014) b W,SFT,t(s) -0.0845-0.0857-0.1224 Full-time work (0.2974) (0.0071) (0.0042) D H,t = exp b H,t(s) + b H,age age H,t + b H,health health H,t +b H,SP,t(s) 1 [Wife works] + b H,SFT,t(s) 1 [Wife works full-time] KNAPP (2014) 50/12

BASELINE RESULTS Detail Back Husband Wife Parameters based on type Preference for Joint Leisure: Out Low High b H,SP,t(s) -0.0910-0.0203-0.0201 Participation (0.8783) (0.0015) (0.0010) b H,SFT,t(s) -0.0661-0.1411-0.0817 Full-time work (0.7060) (0.0089) (0.0039) b W,SP,t(s) -0.0698-0.0055-0.0222 Participation (0.0023) (0.0005) (0.0014) b W,SFT,t(s) -0.0845-0.0857-0.1224 Full-time work (0.2974) (0.0071) (0.0042) b H,SP,t(s) < 0 )Spousal Leisure is complementary KNAPP (2014) 50/12

BASELINE RESULTS Detail Back Husband Wife Parameters based on type Preference for Joint Leisure: Out Low High b H,SP,t(s) -0.0910-0.0203-0.0201 Participation (0.8783) (0.0015) (0.0010) b H,SFT,t(s) -0.0661-0.1411-0.0817 Full-time work (0.7060) (0.0089) (0.0039) b W,SP,t(s) -0.0698-0.0055-0.0222 Participation (0.0023) (0.0005) (0.0014) b W,SFT,t(s) -0.0845-0.0857-0.1224 Full-time work (0.2974) (0.0071) (0.0042) Only comparison is Gustman & Steinmeier (2000,2004,2009): Strong complementary effects for wife s labor force participation on husband. No significant effect for wives. KNAPP (2014) 50/12

BASELINE RESULTS Detail Back Recall, Parameters common to all types b H,age 0.1852 b H,health 1.1037 Husband s Age-60 (0.0039) Husband s Health (0.0262) b W,age 0.1904 b W,health 0.9233 Wife s Age-60 (0.0046) Wife s Health (0.0367) D H,t = exp b H,t(s) + b H,age age H,t + b H,health health H,t +b H,SP,t(s) 1 [Wife works] + b H,SFT,t(s) 1 [Wife works full-time] KNAPP (2014) 51/12

BASELINE RESULTS Detail Back Parameters common to all types b H,age 0.1852 b H,health 1.1037 Husband s Age-60 (0.0039) Husband s Health (0.0262) b W,age 0.1904 b W,health 0.9233 Wife s Age-60 (0.0046) Wife s Health (0.0367) I b i,age > 0 )As i ages, he or she substitutes towards more leisure I b i,health > 0 )If i falls into poor health, he or she substitutes towards more leisure KNAPP (2014) 51/12

MODEL FIT Back I An over-identification test is rejected: I 5% level: 408.4 q ˆq, ĉ = 2552.6 I Tough test to beat (Gourinchas & Parker, 2002; French & Jones, 2011) I The model can capture many of the important details of the data: I Asset accumulation with age I Decline in Labor force participation with age I Capture spikes in male labor force exit at 62 & 65 I Capture significant benefit claiming at age 62 I Capture joint retirement spike KNAPP (2014) 52/12