Ten Questions on the OECD s DEMPE Concept and Its Role in Valuing Intangibles

Similar documents
An Evaluation of the OECD s Final Guidance on Application of the Transactional Profit Split Method

KPMG LLP 2001 M Street, NW Washington, D.C Comments on the Discussion Draft on Cost Contribution Arrangements

SUBSTANCE IS KING IN THE NEW WORLD ORDER TAX EXECUTIVES INSTITUTE, INC. MARCH 1, 2018

Tax Management. Using Internal Agreements to Price Intangibles Transfers

International Journal TM

OECD Release on Intangibles: Many Issues Unanswered

The discussion draft addresses BEPS Actions 8, 9, and 10, which concern the development of:

Revised Guidance on the Application of the Transactional Profit Split Method INCLUSIVE FRAMEWORK ON BEPS: ACTIONS 10

Electronic Commerce Tax Study Group (ECTSG)

Functions, Assets and Risk Analysis under Transfer Pricing

KPMG s general comments on the Discussion Draft are as follows:

Are the Final BEPS Reports on Actions 8-10 Effective Now? by Jason Osborn, Brian Kittle, and Kenneth Klein

Value chain perspectives and their increased importance under BEPS, tax policy and technological change

Taxing and Pricing of Intangibles. Alan Ross

Value Chain Planning post BEPS

OECD releases discussion draft under BEPS Actions 8-10 on risk, recharacterization, and special measures

Strategic Dispute Resolution in a Post-BEPS World

What s News in Tax Analysis That Matters from Washington National Tax

BEPS Action 8: Revisions to Chapter VIII of the Transfer Pricing Guidelines on Cost Contribution Arrangements (CCAs)

B.6. Cost Contribution Arrangements

Gene Ferraro, Mazars USA LLP New York, NY William D. James, BKD, LLP St. Louis, MO

Importance of Intangibles. TP Problems Related to Intangibles. Intangible Issues in Developing Countries

Leslie Van den Branden Partner De Witte-Viselé Associates Kaasmarkt 24 B Brussels (Wemmel) Belgium 1 October 2013

by Prita Subramanian, Kaitlyn Wiatrak, and Tara Adams, Washington National Tax *

Action 8 Assure that transfer pricing outcomes are in in line with value creation

Update of the General Guidelines for Applying the Arm s Length Principle a New Section D in Chapter I of the Guidelines

Intellectual property in the age of BEPS

REPORT. Identifying Relevant Intercompany Activities, Quantifying Measurable Benefits Under the Temporary U.S. Services Rules

Analysis of Intellectual Property Tax Planning Strategies of Multinationals and the Impact of the BEPS Project

Tax Planning International Review

Transfer Pricing in a Post -BEPS World

Intangibles in transfer pricing: A look at the new OECD guidance and Japanese regulations

Post-BEPS application of the arm s length principle: India charts a new course

B y now, most if not all of us have heard about the

OECD TP Guidelines July 2017 Brief synopsis

India revises Country Chapter comments in UN Practical Manual on Transfer Pricing Issues for Developing Countries

Note from the Coordinator of the Subcommittee on Tax Treatment of Services: Draft Article and Commentary on Technical Services.

International Journal TM

September 2, Re: USCIB Comment Letter on the OECD Discussion Draft on BEPS Actions 8-10 Revised Guidance on Profits Splits ( discussion draft )

Intellectual Property

Copenhagen Economics welcomes the opportunity to comment on the OECD s Discussion Draft on BEPS 8-10, Financial transactions, issued on 3 July 2018.

Directive Limits Challenges to Transfer Pricing Method Selection

Transfer Pricing: Theory & Practice

Engaging title in Green Descriptive element in Blue 2 lines if needed

REPORT. Transfer Pricing and Intragroup Cash Pooling

TRANSFER PRICING AND INTANGIBLES: SCOPE OF THE OECD PROJECT

T h e H a g u e February 17, 2009

July 27, Barbara Angus International Tax Counsel Department of the Treasury 1500 Pennsylvania Avenue, N.W. Washington, D.C.

April 30, Re: USCIB Comment Letter on the OECD discussion draft on BEPS Action 3: Strengthening CFC Rules. Dear Mr. Pross, General Comments

SCOPE OF THE FUTURE REVISION OF CHAPTER VII OF THE TRANSFER PRICING GUIDELINES ON SPECIAL CONSIDERATIONS FOR INTRA-GROUP SERVICES

In 2002 the arm s length principle was codified in the Netherlands by section 8b of the Corporate Income Tax Act (VPB) 1969.

Our commentary focuses on five main issues. Supplementary comments relating to specific paragraphs or issues are provided in the appendix.

International tax changes may have a major impact on multinational tech companies

BARSALOU LAWSON AVOCATS BARRISTERS & SOLICITORS

NATIONAL FOREIGN TRADE COUNCIL, INC.

OECD BEPS and EU Anti-Tax Avoidance Directive

The OECD s 3 Major Tax Initiatives

In October 2015, the G20 and the OECD approved and issued a series of. Transfer Pricing After BEPS: Where Are We and Where Should We Be Going

INSIGHT: Transfer Pricing of Financial Transactions

Post-BEPS Application of the Arm s Length Principle to Intangibles Structures

Global Tax Alert. OECD issues updated guidance under BEPS Action 8 on transfer pricing aspects of intangibles. Executive summary

For organizational clarity, we have replicated the OECD s questions in italic font. Our responses follow each inquiry.

Practical Implications of BEPS

Examining the impact of BEPS on the life sciences sector. Overview of select BEPS final reports and timing of implementation

International Journal TM

BEPS Implementation and Transfer Pricing. GWU IRS 29 th Annual Institute on Current Issues in International Taxation. December 15, 2016 Washington, DC

Comments on the United Nations Practical Manual on Transfer Pricing Countries for Developing Countries

KPMG Webcast: OECD Developments Transfer Pricing Aspects of Intangibles

TAX PLANNING INTERNATIONAL

OECD releases final BEPS package

UN Releases Practical Manual on Transfer Pricing for Developing Countries

Performing a BEPS Diagnostic

M ore than 18 months have passed since the new

Comments on the Discussion Draft on Transfer Pricing Comparability Data and Developing Countries

Intra-Group Services & Intangibles

USING INTERCOMPANY TRANSFER PRICE METHODS

BEPS Action 7 Additional Guidance on Attribution of Profits to Permanent Establishments

Under what circumstances, if any, should an entity other than the legal title holder be entitled to intangible related returns?

B.4. Intra-Group Services

Comments on Public Consultation Document Addressing the Tax Challenges of the Digitalisation of the Economy

VOLUME 18, NUMBER 1 >>> JANUARY 2016

September 14, Re: USCIB Comment Letter on the OECD Discussion Draft on BEPS Action 10 Revised Guidance on Profit Splits ( Discussion Draft )

Transfer Pricing Perspectives: The new normal: full TransParency. The post BEPS world in the automotive industry

Ref: BEPS CONFORMING CHANGES TO CHAPTER IX OF THE OECD TRANSFER PRICING GUIDELINES

Statement for the Record

Passive association. The new transfer pricing landscape A practical guide to the BEPS changes. Global Transfer Pricing November 2015

Tax Management International Forum

Comments on the Revised Discussion Draft on Transfer Pricing Aspects of Intangibles*

IP BOX TAX REGIMES. Rod Donnelly Thursday, September 14, 2017

China s SAT Issues Draft Guidance on Transfer Pricing Rules and BEPS Initiatives

PUBLIC COMMENTS RECEIVED ON THE DISCUSSION DRAFT ON THE ATTRIBUTION OF PROFITS TO PERMANENT ESTABLISHMENTS PART I (GENERAL CONSIDERATIONS) 1

32nd Annual Asia Pacific Tax Conference November 2016 JW Marriott Hotel Hong Kong

Transfer Pricing: The New Frontier Transfer Pricing Documentation in a Post-BEPS World: Evolution or Revolution? November 8, 2018

The Independent Auditor s Report on Other Historical Financial Information. The Independent Auditor s Report on Summary Audited Financial Statements

PENSION & BENEFITS! T he cross-border transfer of employees can have A BNA, INC. REPORTER

Transfer pricing of intangibles

Author: Natrada Ruangwuttitikul

KPMG LLP is a Delaware limited liability partnership, the U.S. member firm of KPMG International Cooperative ( KPMG International ), a Swiss entity.

Institute of Certified Public Accountants Transfer Pricing Workshop

BEAT s Impact on Transfer Pricing Alternative Dispute Resolution

Transcription:

Tax Management Transfer Pricing Report TM Reproduced with permission from Tax Management Transfer Pricing Report, Vol. 26, 06/01/2017. Copyright 2017 by The Bureau of National Affairs, Inc. (800-372-1033) http://www.bna.com Ten Questions on the OECD s DEMPE Concept and Its Role in Valuing Intangibles The author explores the DEMPE concept introduced by the OECD development, enhancement, maintenance, protection and exploitation of intangibles and its place in the broader framework for analyzing related-party transfers of intangibles. BY PRITA SUBRAMANIAN, KPMG LLP T he Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development first referred to the development, enhancement, maintenance, protection and exploitation of intangibles in guidance developed under Action 8, one of the transfer pricing items in its Action Plan on Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (BEPS). The acronym DEMPE seems to have taken off sometime after the release of the final BEPS reports in October 2015 and has since become part of the global transfer pricing lexicon for better or for worse. This article explores the concept of DEMPE and its context in the overall transfer pricing analysis through 10 questions. 1. What is the relevance of DEMPE? The OECD s BEPS Action Plan was foreshadowed by tax authorities concerns that multinational companies were artificially shifting income to low-tax jurisdictions Prita Subramanian is a principal in the economic and valuation services group of the Washington National Tax practice of KPMG LLP. She is based in the firm s Boston office. by transferring their valuable intangibles to affiliates in those jurisdictions. In these situations, the multinational often didn t have much operational activity in the low-tax jurisdiction but claimed to earn significant profits there by virtue of its intangibles ownership. One approach the OECD took to addressing this particular concern was to include specific operational requirements, which in its view mirror arm s-length behavior, for an entity to reap the economic benefits of owning intangibles. The starting premise of the OECD s approach is that all members of a multinational company should receive appropriate compensation that is, compensation consistent with the arm s-length standard for the functions they perform, the assets they use and the risks they assume in connection with the intangibles. The approach then presumes that important functions related to the development, enhancement, maintenance, protection, and exploitation DEMPE of an intangible contribute to the creation of the intangible s value. The OECD s approach, therefore, concludes that in order for the legal owner of an intangible to be entitled to the returns from the intangible, it must perform important DEMPE functions. Legal ownership alone doesn t generate a right to all (or indeed any) of the intangible return. In this way, the OECD s guidance on DEMPE is in- Copyright 2017 TAX MANAGEMENT INC., a subsidiary of The Bureau of National Affairs, Inc. ISSN 1063-2069

2 tended to prevent companies with no employees or with minimal operational activity from earning significant intangible-related returns. 2. What are some examples of important DEMPE functions? The nature of the important DEMPE functions in any specific case will depend on the facts and circumstances. For self-developed intangibles, or for self-developed or acquired intangibles that serve as a platform for further development activities, these important functions may include, among others, design and control of research and marketing programs, direction of and establishing priorities for creative undertakings, including determining the course of blue sky research, control over strategic decisions regarding intangible development programs, and management and control of budgets. For any intangible (that is, for either selfdeveloped or acquired intangibles) other important functions may also include significant decisions regarding defense and protection of intangibles, and ongoing quality control over functions performed by independent or associated enterprises that may have a material effect on the value of the intangible. For a fully developed and currently exploitable intangible purchased from a third party, the important functions may be the selection of the most appropriate intangible on the market, the analysis of its potential benefits to the multinational group, and the decision to take on the risk-bearing opportunity through purchasing the intangible. 3. Do the important functions related to an intangible have to relate to DEMPE? It is possible that an important function related to an intangible doesn t fit neatly into one of the DEMPE categories. For instance, when a fully developed intangible is acquired from a third party, as noted above, an important function related to the intangible could be the selection of the most appropriate intangible on the market based on an analysis of its potential benefits to the multinational group. This important function isn t easily categorized as development, enhancement, maintenance, protection, or exploitation, but nevertheless should be entitled to returns from the intangible. Thus, while, in general, the important functions related to intangibles are likely to fall readily into one or more of the DEMPE categories, it is up to the taxpayer to establish what the important functions related to an intangible are and whether those can be straight-jacketed into a DEMPE category. For ease of exposition and in keeping with the common parlance of transfer pricing, this article simply refers to the important functions related to an intangible as important DEMPE functions, or more simply, DEMPE functions. 4. How does DEMPE fit into the OECD s framework for analyzing transactions involving intangibles between associated enterprises? The OECD provides a six-step framework for analyzing transactions between associated enterprises involving intangibles, consistent with the framework for identifying the commercial or financial relations between associated enterprises provided in the OECD transfer pricing guidelines. Step 1. Identify the intangibles with specificity and the specific, economically significant risks associated with the DEMPE of the intangibles. Step 2. Identify the contractual arrangements between the associated enterprises related to the intangibles. Step 3. Identify the parties performing functions, using assets, and managing risks related to the DEMPE of the intangibles. Step 4. Confirm the consistency between the terms of the contractual arrangements and the conduct of the parties, and determine whether the party assuming risks related to the DEMPE of the intangibles controls those risks and has the financial capacity to assume those risks. Step 5. Delineate the actual controlled transactions related to the DEMPE of the intangibles given the steps above. Step 6. Determine arm s-length prices for the transactions consistent with each party s contributions of functions performed, assets used, and risks assumed, unless the accurately delineated transaction isn t recognized under the guidance of section D.2 of Chapter 1 of the OECD guidelines. Note that step 4 requires a comparison of the conduct of the parties with the contractual arrangements. Given the OECD s presumption that the entitlement to returns from an intangible requires the performance of important DEMPE functions, if an entity that doesn t perform such functions is contractually assigned ownership of the intangible, then the accurate delineation of the transaction in step 5 and the arm s-length pricing in step 6 will assign the economic benefits of the intangible away from this contractually identified owner of the intangible. 5. How does DEMPE for intangibles relate to the principles of Chapter 1 of the OECD guidelines? Chapter 1 of the OECD guidelines provides guidance on accurately delineating the actual transaction between related parties. An important facet of the accurate delineation of a transaction is identifying the parties assuming economically significant risks. Under the principles of Chapter 1, the party assuming an economically significant risk must have control over it and must have the financial capacity to assume it. An entity is considered to have control over a risk if it performs decision-making functions related to accepting or declining the risk-bearing opportunity and responding to the risk. When multiple parties exercise control over a specific risk, the contractual allocation of risk to one or more of those parties will be respected. As with intangibles, tax authorities have also expressed concern that multinationals were artificially shifting income to low-tax jurisdictions by shifting risks contractually to group companies in those jurisdictions with limited activity. The OECD s approach on allocation of risks is similarly intended to prevent companies with no employees or with minimal operational activity from earning significant risk-related returns. The guidance in Chapter 1 provides a framework for analyzing risk in a controlled transaction in order to accurately delineate the actual transaction with respect to that risk. As noted above, this framework is similar in structure to the six-step framework for analyzing trans- 6-1-17 Copyright 2017 TAX MANAGEMENT INC., a subsidiary of The Bureau of National Affairs, Inc. TMTR ISSN 1063-2069

3 actions between associated enterprises involving intangibles. Further, the OECD guidelines note that risk management and DEMPE shouldn t be thought of as necessarily encompassing different functions. Section D at paragraph 1.62 states, Risk management should not be thought of as necessarily encompassing a separate function, requiring separate remuneration, distinct from the performance of the activities that optimise profits. For example, the development of intangibles through development activities may involve mitigating risks relating to performing the development... through the performance of the development function itself. In other words, important DEMPE functions will generally encompass significant risk control functions related to an intangible. Under the principles of Chapter 1, DEMPE risks and the excess profits associated with those risks should be attributed to the entity controlling them that is, performing important DEMPE functions. To summarize, a reasonable interpretation of the guidance in Chapter 1 on risks and Chapter 6 on intangibles is that the two chapters prescribe the same principles for delineating the actual transaction between associated enterprises. An underlying principle of the two chapters is that only an entity performing key decisionmaking functions related to the key income generators for the multinational company be it risk assumption or the development of intangibles could earn the income related to those key income generators. If multiple entities perform these decision-making functions then contractual assignments of rights to one or more of those decision-making entities will be respected. (However, see the discussion below on possible sources of controversy.) 6. What role does funding play in the DEMPE framework? General economic theory indicates that economic activity requires both funding (or capital) and people who use that funding to create economic output. In particular, for risky economic undertakings, such as developing intangibles, funding is an important contributor to economic output. Further, the output of a firm is distributed between the providers of funding and the people working for the firm for their contributions to the firm s output. The OECD s presumption is that funding of the intangible in itself has little or no claim on the returns from the intangible, if that funding is not provided by an entity having people controlling that funding and making important decisions related to the DEMPE of the intangible: Where a party providing funding exercises control over the financial risk associated with the provision of funding, without the assumption of, including the control over, any other specific risk, it could generally only expect a risk-adjusted return on its funding, the OECD states in Section B of Chapter 6. Further, the summary to Chapter 6 of the OECD guidelines notes that funding of the development, enhancement, maintenance, protection or exploitation of an intangible by an entity that does not perform any of the important functions in relation to the intangible and does not exercise control over the financial risk will generate no more than a risk-free return. In this, the OECD appears to take a somewhat asymmetrical view of funding and decision-making functions. While funding without decision-makers associated with that funding gets little or no return, the guidance is less clear on whether an entity with important DEMPE functions, including control over DEMPE risks, but without funding can claim the returns from the intangible. The OECD guidance refers to the financial capacity to bear risks in numerous places as a necessary condition for assuming risks (which could include DEMPE risks) without providing a description of what that financial capacity looks like. According to Chapter 1 of the OECD guidelines, financial capacity to assume risk can be defined as access to funding to take on the risk or to lay off the risk, to pay for the risk mitigation functions and to bear the consequences of the risk if the risk materialises. But there is no explanation of what access to funding means. Is it the opportunity to raise funds or does it mean that the entity already has the funding or capital? The opportunity to raise funds can be very different before and after the realization of risk. An entity might have easy access to funding before the realization of a risk but if it doesn t actually obtain that funding and an adverse outcome of risk is realized, the access to funding could decline quickly. The presumption in the OECD guidance appears to be that funding per se is not necessary for an entity to earn the returns from an intangible (including the returns to DEMPE-related risks) but the access to funding is. There seems to be a further presumption that an entity with the decision-making functions related to the intangibles (including key risks related to the intangible) should have access to funding. Thus, the OECD guidance may appear to allow an entity with important DEMPE functions, including control over DEMPE risks, but without funding to claim the returns from the intangible. 7. How can DEMPE functions be identified? The exercise of identifying DEMPE functions will vary by company. An important common step in any evaluation of DEMPE functions will be a functional analysis, which can include interviewing relevant personnel in the multinational company, reviewing the group s management organizational structure, identifying the key intangibles used in the business, and reviewing the company s human resources data on employee locations, titles, and roles. Industry and other public sources can also provide useful information on important functions related to an intangible. 8. Does the guidance on DEMPE preclude the existence of contract R&D arrangements? No. Contract research and development arrangements can still be used. That is, R&D activities could still be outsourced to related parties. However, a key question is whether what has traditionally been considered a distinguishing feature of contract R&D namely, its lack of claim on intangible risks or residual returns from intangibles is still feasible. The OECD guidelines note that if the contractual arrangement between the associated enterprises is a contract R&D arrangement that is respected... remuneration for risk mitigation functions performed through the development activity would be incorporated into the arm s length services TAX MANAGEMENT TRANSFER PRICING REPORT ISSN 1063-2069 BNA TAX 6-1-17

4 payment. Neither the intangible risk itself, nor the residual income associated with such risk, would be allocated to the service provider. Under the guidance in Chapter 1, for the contract R&D arrangement to be respected and the contract R&D service provider not to be entitled to returns from the intangible, the contract R&D service provider either: s must not perform any important DEMPE functions (including control of DEMPE risks), or s if it does perform some of those functions, then there must be other entities performing important DEMPE functions (including controlling DEMPE risks) and there must be intercompany contracts assigning rights to the intangibles and associated risks to one or more of the other entities. (The section below discusses the ambiguity of OECD language on this point and potential sources of controversy.) Further, if the contract R&D provider doesn t perform DEMPE functions (including controlling DEMPE risks) then under the Chapter 6 guidance, it shouldn t be entitled to excess returns from the intangible. Thus, when R&D strategy and direction for an intangible is determined in one entity and contract R&D is performed in another, the OECD guidance would seem to say that the DEMPE (including risk-control) functions and therefore the intangible-related returns belong in the former entity. 9. What are likely to be some sources of controversy related to DEMPE? The language in the OECD guidelines is consensus language that is, no participant to the BEPS project objected to the revised guidelines. Therefore, tax authorities with potentially different points of view needed to agree on the language in the revised guidelines. The end result was that at least some of the language in the guidelines is amenable to differing interpretations, which is likely to be a source of controversy. For example, what one tax authority might consider an important DEMPE function, another might not. Similarly, tax authorities could have different views on what it means to exercise control over a risk such as how closely involved or senior the decision-makers need to be. If multiple entities perform DEMPE functions, a significant source of controversy is likely to be the entitlement of the different entities to the returns from the intangible for their DEMPE functions. One reasonable interpretation of the OECD guidelines, which tax authorities such as the U.S. may take, would be that in such a situation the contractual arrangement between the transacting parties should determine the entity entitled to the returns from the intangible, as discussed above. The OECD guidelines, however, don t explicitly state this in Chapter 6. In fact, language in the guidelines muddies the issue: The entitlement of any member of the MNE [multinational enterprise] group to profit or loss relating to differences between actual (ex post) and a proper estimation of anticipated (ex ante) profitability will depend on which entity or entities in the MNE group in fact assumes the risks as identified when delineating the actual transaction (see Section D.1 of Chapter I). It will also depend on the entity or entities which are performing the important functions as reflected in paragraph 6.56 or contributing to the control over the economically significant risks as established in paragraph 1.105, and for which it is determined that an arm s length remuneration of these functions would include a profit sharing element. [Emphasis added.] The term profit sharing element could be interpreted by some tax authorities as implying that important DEMPE functions should be entitled to returns from the intangible irrespective of contractual compensation terms. Another source of controversy could be the attribution of DEMPE risks to entities that control them but that aren t contractually allocated those risks. While an entity s tax authority might not contest attributing positive returns to the entity arising from the resolution of a specific risk that is not contractually assigned to it, the tax authority might contest attributing the negative outcome of the risk to it. See also the discussion below in the section on the U.S. view of DEMPE. 10. How does the U.S. view DEMPE? In public pronouncements, U.S. government officials have said that the regulations under section 482 are consistent with the revised OECD guidelines. However, as noted above, the ambiguous language in the guidelines can mask significant differences in interpretation between the U.S. and other tax authorities. For example, on the question of respect for contractual arrangements, the U.S. transfer pricing regulations respect contractual allocations of risk so long as they are consistent with the economic substance of the transaction. In considering the economic substance of the transaction, the following facts are relevant: s whether the taxpayer s conduct over time is consistent with the purported allocation of risk; s whether the taxpayer has the financial capacity to fund losses; and s the extent to which each controlled taxpayer exercises managerial or operational control over the business activities that directly influence the amount of income or loss realized (in arm s-length dealings, parties ordinarily bear a greater share of those risks over which they have relatively more control). The U.S. rules on risk allocation, therefore, look similar to the OECD guidance in principle. However, unlike the OECD guidelines, the regulations under tax code Section 482 don t prescribe the meaning of managerial or operational control. In practice, the Internal Revenue Service and U.S. Tax Court have generally respected contractual allocations of risk by the taxpayer. However, it is conceivable, and in fact is likely, that other tax authorities will interpret the same OECD guidance on risks to show much less respect for contractual allocations of risk by the taxpayer. Further, in the case of intangibles development, regulations Section 1.482-7, on cost-sharing arrangements, permit intangible-related returns to cost-sharing participants without regard to operational control over DEMPE functions. While the rules on economic substance in regulations Section 1.482-1 described above still apply to cost-sharing arrangements, the IRS has not in practice insisted on economic substance in a costsharing participant in the form of managerial or operational control equivalent to the DEMPE functions or 6-1-17 Copyright 2017 TAX MANAGEMENT INC., a subsidiary of The Bureau of National Affairs, Inc. TMTR ISSN 1063-2069

5 risk control functions of the OECD guidelines in order for it to be entitled to returns from the intangible under development. This article represents the views of the authors only, and does not necessarily represent the views or professional advice of KPMG LLP. The information contained herein is of a general nature and based on authorities that are subject to change. Applicability of the information to specific situations should be determined through consultation with the company s tax adviser. Sources for this article are listed at http://src.bna.com/pax. TAX MANAGEMENT TRANSFER PRICING REPORT ISSN 1063-2069 BNA TAX 6-1-17