Chapter 8. Revenue recycling and environmental policy

Similar documents
GETTING TO AN EFFICIENT CARBON TAX How the Revenue Is Used Matters

June 19, I hope this information is helpful to you. The CBO staff contacts are Frank Sammartino and Terry Dinan. Sincerely,

Environmental taxation and the double dividend

Carbon Taxes, U.S. Fiscal Policy and Social Welfare

SIMON FRASER UNIVERSITY Department of Economics. Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory Spring PROBLEM SET 1 (Solutions) Y = C + I + G + NX

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

Macroeconomic impacts of limiting the tax deductibility of interest expenses of inbound companies

IS BRITISH COLUMBIA S CARBON TAX GOOD FOR HOUSEHOLD INCOME? WORKING PAPER

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Using a Carbon Tax to Meet U.S. International Climate Pledges

Dynamic Analysis at CBO

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

The Impact of a Pan- Canadian Carbon Pricing Levy on PBO s GDP Projection. Ottawa, Canada 22 May

AP Microeconomics Chapter 16 Outline

DISTRIBUTIONAL IMPLICATIONS OF A NATIONAL CO 2 TAX IN THE U.S. ACROSS INCOME CLASSES AND REGIONS: A MULTI-MODEL OVERVIEW

Problems. the net marginal product of capital, MP'

Options for Fiscal Consolidation in the United Kingdom

COM/ENV/EPOC/DAFFE/CFA(2001)90/FINAL

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy

OECD Policy Instruments for the Environment

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE CONFERENCE AGREEMENT FOR H.R. 1, THE TAX CUTS AND JOBS ACT

CONTRIBUTION TO THE REVISION OF THE ENERGY TAX DIRECTIVE

CHAPTER 2. A TOUR OF THE BOOK

Climate policy enhances efficiency: A macroeconomic portfolio effect

Project Evaluation and the Folk Principle when the Private Sector Lacks Perfect Foresight

Discounting the Benefits of Climate Change Policies Using Uncertain Rates

THEORETICAL TOOLS OF PUBLIC FINANCE

Carbon Revenue Recycling Opportunities and Challenges. By Elena Simonova and Rock Lefebvre

Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 7: Externalities, the Marginal Cost of Public Funds, and Imperfect Competition

The Exchange Rate and Canadian Inflation Targeting

Public Finance: The Economics of Taxation. The Economics of Taxation. Taxes: Basic Concepts

Environmental Policy in the Presence of an. Informal Sector

Cato Institute Policy Analysis No. 39: Indexation and the Inflation Tax

ECONOMIC SURVEY OF NEW ZEALAND 2007: TWO BROAD APPROACHES FOR TAX REFORM

Are Green Taxes a Good Way to Help Solve State Budget Deficits?

A Course in Environmental Economics: Theory, Policy, and Practice. Daniel J. Phaneuf and Till Requate

THE EFFECTS OF CARBON TAX POLICIES ON THE US ECONOMY AND THE WELFARE OF HOUSEHOLDS

Report ISBN: (PDF)

NET FISCAL INCIDENCE AT THE REGIONAL LEVEL : A COMPUTABLE GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM MODEL WITH VOTING. Saloua Sehili

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE TAX CUT AND JOBS ACT AS ORDERED REPORTED BY THE SENATE COMMITTEE ON FINANCE ON NOVEMBER 16, 2017

Halving Poverty in Russia by 2024: What will it take?

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS THE UNIVERSITY OF NEW BRUNSWICK FREDERICTON, CANADA

CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web

What does the Eurostat-OECD PPP Programme do? Why is GDP compared from the expenditure side? What are PPPs? Overview

Chapter 12: Design of the Tax System. Historical Context

Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 9: Dynamic Taxation II Optimal Capital Taxation

CHAPTER 16. EXPECTATIONS, CONSUMPTION, AND INVESTMENT

Report for Congress. Using Business Tax Cuts to Stimulate the Economy. Updated January 30, 2003

Energy Refund Program through State Human Service Agencies

Introduction to Green Tax & Budget Reform (GTBR)

Business Cycles II: Theories

Don Fullerton, University of Illinois Garth Heutel, UNC-Greensboro

ECON 1102: MACROECONOMICS 1 Chapter 1: Measuring Macroeconomic Performance, Output and Prices

A SECOND-BEST POLLUTION SOLUTION WITH SEPARATE TAXATION OF COMMODITIES AND EMISSIONS

The Future of Social Security

Problems. units of good b. Consumers consume a. The new budget line is depicted in the figure below. The economy continues to produce at point ( a1, b

Carbon Taxes, Inequality and Engel's Law - The Double Dividend of Redistribution

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE TAX REFORM ACT OF 2014

MAY Carbon taxation and fiscal consolidation: the potential of carbon pricing to reduce Europe s fiscal deficits

Macroeconomics. Part 1: Issues in Macroeconomics. Chapter 1: Measuring macroeconomic performance - output and prices

Compensation Rules for Climate Policy in the Electricity Sector

Macroeconomics Study Sheet

Thinking Through the Economic Consequences of Higher Taxes

To understand the drivers of poverty reduction,

Current tax law allows workers to opt out, either partially

The Theory of Taxation and Public Economics

EU ETS MARKET STABILITY RESERVE

The Economic Effects of a Wealth Tax in Germany

CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web

Dynamic Scoring of Tax Plans

Comparing Permit Allocation Options: The Main Points

A Computable General Equilibrium Model of Energy Taxation

Introductory Macroeconomics

Name (Please print) Assigned Seat. ECO202: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS FIRST MIDTERM EXAM SPRING 2010 Prof. Bill Even FORM 3.

APPENDIX A: FINANCIAL ASSUMPTIONS AND DISCOUNT RATE

Designing a FAIR CARBON TAX

14.41 Final Exam Jonathan Gruber. True/False/Uncertain (95% of credit based on explanation; 5 minutes each)

Notes Unless otherwise indicated, the years referred to in describing budget numbers are fiscal years, which run from October 1 to September 30 and ar

Carbon Tax and Equity

Comments on Jeffrey Frankel, Commodity Prices and Monetary Policy by Lars Svensson

FAQ - Environmental Pollution Tax Law in Viet Nam -

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TWO GENERALIZATIONS OF A DEPOSIT-REFUND SYSTEM. Don Fullerton Ann Wolverton

Public Sector Economics Test Questions Randall Holcombe Fall 2017

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Social Choice

17.2 U.S. Government Spending and Revenue Introduction. Chapter 17 The Government and the Macroeconomy. In 2008, federal spending

The Coalition s Record on Housing: Policy, Spending and Outcomes

Chapter 14. Introduction. Learning Objectives. Deficit Spending and The Public Debt. Explain how federal government budget deficits occur

EC441 Study Guide I Fall 2018 R. Congleton Public Economics WVU

Trade Policy: From efficiency to meeting social objectives

Firm Financing in Chile after the Tax Reform

2018 HSC Economics Marking Guidelines

Costs for the USA of Compliance with the Kyoto Protocol: a Critical Assessment of Official US estimates.

CRS Report for Congress

Oil Industry Tax and Deficit Issues

The CPI and the Cost of Living

Using Business Tax Cuts to Stimulate the Economy

University of Victoria. Economics 325 Public Economics SOLUTIONS

WikiLeaks Document Release

H.R American Clean Energy and Security Act of 2009

Micro-foundations: Consumption. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Transcription:

Chapter 8. Revenue recycling and environmental policy Recognizing that market-based environmental policies generate substantial revenues for any meaningful emissions reductions, assumptions must be made regarding their disposition. Taxes, like all prices, provide incentives to do some things and not others. In short, taxes can distort behavior. As examples, income and wealth taxes can reduce incentives for work, saving and investment, sales taxes on clothing but not on food can bias purchasing decisions, and taxes on gasoline, cigarettes and alcoholic beverages can discourage their use. Clearly, there are economic consequences associated with the level and structure of the nation s tax codes. Equally clearly, there are possible economic benefits from using the revenues raised under various climate change initiatives to reduce the burdens of other distorting taxes. There simply are better and worse ways to distribute the proceeds from climate change policies (e.g., Goulder (1994), Jorgenson et.al. (1996, 1998, 2000), Nordhaus (1994), Norland and Ninassi (1998), and Repetto and Austin (1997)). A fully private allocation plan for tradable permits distributes the permits to existing polluters. The market value of these permits accrues to shareholders and business owners. In IGEM households are the ultimate owners of the nation s private stock of capital. Given the model s aggregation to a representative consumer, a private allocation plan is equivalent to distributing permit revenues in lump-sum fashion. For lump-sum distributions the transfers are independent of taxpayer behavior and are non-distorting. Because of this, they are among the least attractive mechanisms available for re-introducing permit revenues into the economy. This chapter considers alternative permit ownership and revenue recycling schemes as part of an overall emissions reduction policy. In these alternative plans, permits or a portion of them are publicly rather than privately owned. They are auctioned by the U.S. government and the revenues are used either to reduce the marginal tax rate on labor income or to compensate the introduction of an economy-wide investment tax credit. The timing and magnitudes of emissions reductions are proportionally identical across the simulations; only the recycling plan is altered. Any remaining general equilibrium adjustments necessary to achieve revenue and-or deficit neutrality restore the level of government purchases through lump-sum transfers. We apply these recycling alternatives to three recent analyses of Congressional initiatives conducted for the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). These are the House Energy 8-1

and Commerce and Senate Finance Committees versions of the American Clean Energy and Security Act of 2009 (ACES) and the Lieberman-Warner Climate Security Act of 2008 (S.3036). In the ACES simulations, we only consider adjustments in the marginal tax rate on labor income. For the House version of the ACES Act, we vary the revenues being recycled covering four possible arrangements. In the first, all allowances not specifically allocated to various stakeholders are presumed auctioned. In the second, there are no allocations and 100% of the permit supply is auctioned. In the third, recycling is valued according to permit demand and not a portion or all of permit supply. While equivalent to a carbon tax, this arrangement also is equivalent to a cap-and-trade policy in which the U.S. government owns and controls the bank account or one in which a safety valve time path of allowances is triggered. Our final arrangement is one in which revenues are recycled so as to hold consumers harmless in terms of foregone consumption. For the Senate version of the ACES Act, we simulate two possibilities a recycling of revenues that follows the valuation of unallocated permit supply and one that follows the valuation of unallocated permit demand. In the S.3036 analysis, we examine the effects of both the marginal labor tax and the investment tax credit. We simulated the portion of allowances in each year that were designated in S.3036 for auction and revenue recycling. We also evaluated the 100% supply and 100% demand arrangements. To simplify comparisons, we summarize our findings in terms of economic welfare as measured by the equivalent variations in full wealth and full expenditure. The equivalent variation in full wealth is the present value of lifetime changes in household utility for full consumption (goods, services and leisure) valued at base case prices and interest rates. Alternatively, the equivalent variation in full expenditure is the present value of lifetime changes in household utility for consumption (goods and services only) valued at base case prices and interest rates. These are shown in Table 8.1. 8-2

Households fare measurably better in terms of full expenditure when the permit revenues are used to reduce marginal tax rates on labor income. They do increasingly well as more revenue is recycled; varying the arrangements from unallocated or designated supply to 100% supply and then to 100% demand is welfare-improving. The improvements are by thirds for the House initiatives and by halves or more for the Senate proposals. This pattern should be no 8-3

surprise. Following the cap, permit supply involves more significant revenues from generously front loading the auctions in the early years even at the lower prices. Following demand generates still greater revenues from the temporal shifting of near-term allocations to the later years when permit prices are much higher. Incomes and production are higher when the marginal tax rate on labor income is lowered. The distorting influence on energy and other prices from climate policy replaces an even greater distorting influence on the price of labor to producers and the income from work for consumers. Under this view, the emissions constraint raises prices to producers and consumers. Permit revenues are returned to households in the form of reductions in labor tax rates. Since a significant fraction of total household income arises from work, this plan increases the opportunity cost of choosing more leisure in terms of the goods and services that must be sacrificed to obtain it. Thus, households substitute toward consumption and away from leisure. Equivalently, they offer additional labor services at a reduced pre-tax rate of compensation. Gross compensation per employee need not be as high because tax rates now are lower. Producers absorb this additional, now lower-cost labor, restructuring inputs toward labor. Unit production costs and commodity prices are lower as the pre-tax labor cost declines. Reduced labor tax rates favor work and consumption because of lower costs and commodity prices and because of the substitution away from leisure. However, saving and investment also are favored. Saving is higher because the stimulus to consumption due to lower prices, combined with these lower prices, lags behind the stimulus to income from a greater labor supply. Investment is higher because of more saving and because the decline in commodity prices permits more capital goods to be purchased from each dollar of investment. Additional investment adds to capital availability so that the economy now has more labor and capital. Nevertheless, the capital-labor ratio declines due to increased labor. In terms of full wealth, as measured by good, services and leisure, households fare worse when the permit revenues are used to reduce marginal tax rates on labor income. In addition, they fare increasingly worse as more revenue is recycled. This seeming anomaly arises because real government purchases crowd out real consumption spending when deficit neutrality is targeted by restoring nominal government purchases. The lower labor tax results in lower prices economy-wide as the pre-tax reservation wage now is lower. Lower prices combined with base case nominal government expenditures mean that real government purchases rise largely at the 8-4

expense of real household purchases. Consumption cannot increase enough to offset the reduction in leisure due to the increase in labor supply and demand. This explains the welfare effects. If full consumption were re-defined to cover government as well as private consumption and leisure, revenue recycling with the labor tax would be unambiguously welfare- improving. As it stands, the crowding out by governments leads to a counter-intuitive, yet entirely logical, general equilibrium outcome. The seemingly perverse ordering in the welfare rankings disappears when deficit neutrality is targeted by restoring government purchases in real terms. The change in real government purchases is directionally the same and numerically comparable in the recast scenarios. However, consumption is no longer crowded out and revenue recycling is welfareimproving in terms of both full expenditure and full wealth. The slight gain in consumption is sufficient to compensate the reduction in leisure that follows from the increase in labor supply, thus, securing the offsetting improvement in full wealth. There is no theoretically correct choice for achieving deficit neutrality. This degree of freedom arises in IGEM because its numeraire price is the after-tax wage received by households, and not the GDP price deflator. The saving-investment balance in IGEM is expressed in nominal terms and it seems logical to deal with deficit neutrality in the budgetary sense. Moreover, achieving deficit neutrality by targeting nominal expenditures simultaneously results in revenue neutrality. However, it is equally true that government budgets envision a particular market basket of physical goods and services that should be maintained. Here deficit neutrality by targeting real purchases seems the logical choice, recognizing that revenue neutrality then must be sacrificed. In many of IGEM s policy analyses, there are no alternative recycling considerations beyond subsidies, rebates and lump sum redistributions. Under lump sum recycling and, indeed, the other recycling mechanisms, the nominal versus real targeting of government purchases has subtle effects and matters very little in terms of the macroeconomic and inter-industry effects of climate policy. The magnitudes of GDP, consumption, investment, and other changes are qualitatively identical and numerically quite similar. Indeed, the distinction matters significantly only for the welfare rankings in simulation runs involving adjustments in the marginal tax rate on labor income and only because it produces a theoretically anomalous outcome. 8-5

Recycling revenues through an economy-wide investment tax credit or through reductions in the tax rates on capital income or property is welfare improving in terms of both full wealth and full expenditure. This conclusion holds irrespective of whether deficit neutrality is achieved through the targeting of nominal or real government expenditures. At the lower levels of revenue and relative to lump sum redistributions, the benefits to full expenditure are comparable to those from labor tax recycling. However, for full wealth, there are greater benefits from the use of the capital instrument and these relative improvements over lump-sum recycling increase as the amounts of revenue being recycled increase. As before, climate change policy raises prices to producers and consumers. Any increases in government revenues here are returned to the private sector through the introduction of the tax credit. This reduces the rental price of capital services and raises the returns on saving and investment. Use of this instrument clearly favors capital formation over consumption although increases in the former enhance the possibilities for increases in the latter. The increased availability of capital helps insulate the economy from the adverse price effects of climate policy. This dampens but does not eliminate the dominant substitution of leisure for the consumption of goods and services. The increases in leisure for the investment tax credit lie generally between the larger ones from lump-sum recycling and the smaller ones from labor tax recycling. As capital substitutes for labor, increases in leisure and the additional consumption arising from increased capital availability contribute to the welfare gains or smaller losses associated with using capital instruments. While capital holds the superior edge in the present-value rankings of recycling mechanisms, there are important differences in timing that merit consideration. These are illustrated in Figure 8.1 which shows the effects on real household consumption arising from the various recycling combinations. Clearly, lump-sum recycling is an inferior choice. However, in comparing the labor and capital instruments, recycling with labor taxes secures an early advantage that diminishes over time becoming a disadvantage as the longer run benefits from investment tax credits materialize. Thus, it is in the intermediate-to-long-run sense that capital becomes the preferred instrument. 8-6

8-7