Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Similar documents
The Black-Scholes Model

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

2 f. f t S 2. Delta measures the sensitivityof the portfolio value to changes in the price of the underlying

Practical Hedging: From Theory to Practice. OSU Financial Mathematics Seminar May 5, 2008

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Variance Derivatives and the Effect of Jumps on Them

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Pricing Variance Swaps under Stochastic Volatility Model with Regime Switching - Discrete Observations Case

The Black-Scholes Model

Towards a Theory of Volatility Trading. by Peter Carr. Morgan Stanley. and Dilip Madan. University of Maryland

The Black-Scholes Model

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

Dynamic Relative Valuation

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Definition Pricing Risk management Second generation barrier options. Barrier Options. Arfima Financial Solutions

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

Volatility Investing with Variance Swaps

An Overview of Volatility Derivatives and Recent Developments

Trading Volatility Using Options: a French Case

Module 10:Application of stochastic processes in areas like finance Lecture 36:Black-Scholes Model. Stochastic Differential Equation.

Calibration Lecture 4: LSV and Model Uncertainty

Option Pricing Models for European Options

7.1 Volatility Simile and Defects in the Black-Scholes Model

TEACHING NOTE 98-04: EXCHANGE OPTION PRICING

Simple Robust Hedging with Nearby Contracts

4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs. Math6911 S08, HM Zhu

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

Lecture 9: Practicalities in Using Black-Scholes. Sunday, September 23, 12

Optimal robust bounds for variance options and asymptotically extreme models

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015

Pricing Volatility Derivatives with General Risk Functions. Alejandro Balbás University Carlos III of Madrid

Pricing Barrier Options under Local Volatility

CONTINUOUS TIME PRICING AND TRADING: A REVIEW, WITH SOME EXTRA PIECES

Application of Stochastic Calculus to Price a Quanto Spread

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

Exploring Volatility Derivatives: New Advances in Modelling. Bruno Dupire Bloomberg L.P. NY

FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008

Credit Risk : Firm Value Model

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Monte Carlo Simulations

1 Introduction. 2 Old Methodology BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM DIVISION OF RESEARCH AND STATISTICS

Reading: You should read Hull chapter 12 and perhaps the very first part of chapter 13.

CEV Implied Volatility by VIX

Financial Markets & Risk

Valuation of Equity Derivatives

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

- 1 - **** d(lns) = (µ (1/2)σ 2 )dt + σdw t

A Brief Introduction to Stochastic Volatility Modeling

2.3 Mathematical Finance: Option pricing

Financial Derivatives Section 5

Derivative Securities Fall 2012 Final Exam Guidance Extended version includes full semester

Hedging. MATH 472 Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan

Locally risk-minimizing vs. -hedging in stochastic vola

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

Appendix A Financial Calculations

Bluff Your Way Through Black-Scholes

Utility Indifference Pricing and Dynamic Programming Algorithm

LIBOR models, multi-curve extensions, and the pricing of callable structured derivatives

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

The Black-Scholes Equation

The Uncertain Volatility Model

Risk Neutral Valuation

An Analytical Approximation for Pricing VWAP Options

A New Framework for Analyzing Volatility Risk and Premium Across Option Strikes and Expiries

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

Pricing Methods and Hedging Strategies for Volatility Derivatives

Completeness and Hedging. Tomas Björk

European call option with inflation-linked strike

Simple Robust Hedging with Nearby Contracts

Black-Scholes-Merton Model

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

The Binomial Model. Chapter 3

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

King s College London

The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations

Numerical schemes for SDEs

BIRKBECK (University of London) MSc EXAMINATION FOR INTERNAL STUDENTS MSc FINANCIAL ENGINEERING DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, MATHEMATICS AND STATIS- TICS

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Market risk measurement in practice

Arbitrage Bounds for Volatility Derivatives as Free Boundary Problem. Bruno Dupire Bloomberg L.P. NY

FINANCIAL OPTION ANALYSIS HANDOUTS

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

Mixing Di usion and Jump Processes

The stochastic calculus

Financial Engineering. Craig Pirrong Spring, 2006

King s College London

Option Pricing. 1 Introduction. Mrinal K. Ghosh

Lecture 6: Option Pricing Using a One-step Binomial Tree. Thursday, September 12, 13

1 Interest Based Instruments

MSC FINANCIAL ENGINEERING PRICING I, AUTUMN LECTURE 6: EXTENSIONS OF BLACK AND SCHOLES RAYMOND BRUMMELHUIS DEPARTMENT EMS BIRKBECK

Math 239 Homework 1 solutions

Fixed-Income Options

A Brief Review of Derivatives Pricing & Hedging

Lecture 11: Ito Calculus. Tuesday, October 23, 12

Dr. Maddah ENMG 625 Financial Eng g II 10/16/06

Optimal Hedging of Variance Derivatives. John Crosby. Centre for Economic and Financial Studies, Department of Economics, Glasgow University

Derivative Securities

Transcription:

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives 4.1 Volatility trading and replication of variance swaps 4.2 Volatility swaps 4.3 Pricing of discrete variance swaps 4.4 Options on discrete variance and volatility 4.5 Futures and options on VIX 4.6 Timer options 1

4.1 Volatility trading Characteristics of volatility Likely to grow when uncertainty and risk increase. Volatilities appear to revert to the mean. Volatility is often negatively correlated with stock or index level, and tends to stay high after large downward moves. Stock options are impure: they provide exposure to both direction of the stock price and its volatility. If one hedges the options according to Black-Scholes prescription, then she can remove the exposure to the stock price. Delta-hedging is at best inaccurate since volatility cannot be accurately estimated, stocks cannot be traded continuously, together with transaction costs and jumps. 2

Businesses that are implicitly short volatility (lose when volatility increases) Investors following active benchmarking strategies may require more frequent rebalancing and incur higher transaction expenses during volatile periods. Equity funds are probably short volatility due to the negative correlation between index level and volatility. Hedge funds that take positions on the spread between stocks of companies planning mergers will narrow. If volatility increases, the merger may become less likely and spread may widen. Volatility swaps are forward contracts on future realized stock volatility; and similarly, variance swaps on future variance (square of future volatility). They provide pure exposure to volatility and variance, respectively. 3

Replication of variance swaps - continuous model The fair strike of a variance swap (continuously monitored) is given by K var = E 0 [V R ] = E 0 ( 1 T 0 σ2 t dt Suppose the asset price process S t follows the following Brownian motion: ds t S t = r dt + σ t dw t, where W t is the standard Brownian motion and σ t is non-stochastic (though may be state dependent). We may rewrite the dynamics equation as follows: d ln S t = ( r σ2 t 2 ) dt + σ t dw t. ) 4

Subtracting the two, we obtain ds t S t d ln S t = σ2 t 2 dt The measure of the continuous realized variance is then given by V R = 1 T 0 σ2 t dt = 2 T ( 0 ds t S t ln S t S 0 ). The formula dictates the strategy that can be adopted to replicate the realized variance. We take 1 S t units of stock at time t paying $1, and enter a static short position at time 0 in a forward contract which at maturity has a payoff equals to the logarithm of the total return of on the stock ln S T, where S T is the total return over [0, T ]. S 0 S 0 5

This is a self-financing strategy Suppose the stock price goes up, the investor sells 1 S t units of stock 1 and buys units paying $1. The net amount S t+dt 1 is invested S t+dt S t in the riskfree asset. Over the same period, the forward value F t = E t [ ln S T S 0 ] of the log contract increases in value. The short position in the log contract offsets the gain on the long stock position. Recall since ln(1 + x) x. ln S t+dt S t S t+dt S t 1 6

The pricing issue is to find the fair strike of the variance swap. K var = E 0 [V R ] = 2 T E 0 = 2 T [ E 0 }{{} 0 r dt rt [ ] 0 ds t S t ln S T S 0 + E 0 [ ] 0 σ t dw t ] }{{} zero E 0 [ ln S ] T S 0 The expectation of the long stock position gives rt since the dollar value of the stock position is always $1. How to replicate the log contract using basic instruments of forward contracts, calls and puts? Technical result For any twice-differentiable function f: R R, and any S 0, we have f(s T ) = f(s ) + f (S )(S T S ) + + S f (K)(S T K) + dk. S. 0 f (K)(K S T ) + dk 7

Proof f(s T ) = S 0 f(k)δ(s T K) dk + = f(k)1 {ST <K} ] S + f(k)1 {ST K} S 0 ] S S f(k)δ(s T K) dk 0 f (K)1 {ST <K} dk S f (K)1 {ST K} dk = f(s )1 {ST <S } [ f (K)(K S T ) +] S 0 + S +f(s )1 {ST S } [ f (K)(S T K) +] S + = f(s ) + f (S )[(S T S ) + (S S T ) + ] + S 0 f (K)(K S T ) + dk + f(s T ) f(s ) = f (S )(S T S ) + + S S S f (K)(S T K) + dk. 0 f (K)(K S T ) + dk S f (K)(S T K) + dk 0 f (K)(K S T ) + dk f (K)(S T K) + dk 8

The log payoff ln S T S 0 can be rewritten as ln S T S 0 = ln S T S + ln S S 0, S is an arbitrage non-negative number. Applying the technical formula for f(s T ) = ln S T, we have ln S T ln S = S T S S S 0 1 K 2(K S T ) + 1 dk S K 2(S T K) + dk. Hold a long position in 1 S forward contracts with forward price S ; Short positions in 1 put options with strike K, K from 0 to K2 S ; short positions in 1 K 2 call options with strike K, K from S to. All contracts have the same maturity T. 9

Valuation of fair strike K var = 2 T Note that {rt E 0 [ ln S S 0 + S T S S S 0 1 ]} K 2(K S T ) + 1 dk S K 2(S T K) + dk. S 0 = e rt E 0 [S T ], C 0 (K) = e rt E 0 [(S T K) + ], P 0 (K) = e rt E 0 [(K S T ) + ]. We then have K var = 2 T [ rt + e rt S 0 ( ) S0 e rt 1 S ln S S 0 1 K 2P 0(K) dk + e rt ] 1 S K 2C 0(K) dk. The formula requires an infinite number of strikes in order to be exact, while the market provides only a finite number of options. 10

Profit and loss (P&L) if one hedges at the wrong volatility Assume that the futures price process is continuous and that the true vol is given by some unknown stochastic process σ t : df t F t = µ t dt + σ t dw t, t [0, T ]. Assume that a claim on the futures price is sold for an initial implied vol of σ i and that delta-hedging is conducted using the Black model delta evaluated at a constant hedge vol σ h. Applying Ito s lemma to V (F, t)e r(t t) : V (F T, T ) = V (F 0, 0)e rt + 0 F (F t, t) df t + 0 er(t t)1 2 V 2 F 2(F t, t) (df t ) 2 [ ] + er(t t) V 0 t (F t, t) rv (F t, t) dt. er(t t) V 11

Since the futures has stochastic volatility, (df t ) 2 = σt 2F t 2 so V (F T, T ) = V (F 0, 0)e rt + 0 [ T + er(t t) σ 2 t Ft 2 0 2 er(t t) V dt and F (F t, t) df t 2 V F 2(F t, t) + V t (F t, t) rv (F t, t) Suppose we have chosen our function V (F, t) to be the function V (F, t; σ h ) which solves the Black PDE: σh 2F 2 2 V 2 F 2(F, t; σ h) + V t (F, t; σ h) rv (F, t; σ h ) = 0, and the terminal condition: V (F, T ; σ h ) = f(f ). Substitution gives f(f T ) = V (F 0, 0; σ h )e rt + + 0 0 er(t t) [σ 2 t σ2 h ]F 2 t 2 er(t t) V F (F t, t; σ h ) df t 2 V F 2(F t, t; σ h ) dt. ] dt. 12

Adding V (F 0, 0; σ i )e rt to both sides and re-arranging, we obtain P &L T = [V (F 0, 0; σ t ) V (F 0, 0; σ h )]e rt + 0 er(t t)f 2 t 2 2 V F 2(F t, t; σ h )(σ 2 h σ2 t ) dt. In words, when we sell the claim for an implied vol of σ i initially, the total P&L from delta-hedging with constant vol σ h over (0, T ) is the future value of the difference in Black Scholes valuations plus half the accumulated dollar gamma weighted average of the difference between the hedge variance and the true variance. Note that the P&L vanishes if σ t = σ h = σ i. If 2 V F 2(F t, t; σ h ) 0 as is true for options, and if σ i = σ h < σ t for all t [0, T ], then you sold the claim for too low a vol and a loss results, regardless of the path. Conversely, if σ i > σ t for all t [0, T ], then delta-hedging at σ h = σ i guarantees a positive P&L. 13

In terms of stock price S 0, the P&L is given by P &L = [V (S 0, 0; σ i ) V (S 0, 0; σ h )]e rt + 0 er(t t) (σ 2 h σ2 t )S2 t 2 2 S 2V (S t, t; σ h ) dt. Let us linearize the first two terms in σ 2 around σ h. The P&L can be rewritten as P &L = T e rt (σt 2 σ2 h )S2 0 2 + 2 S 2V (S 0, t; σ h ) 0 er(t t) (σ 2 h σ2 t )S2 t 2 2 S 2V (S t, t; σ h ) dt. Define the volatility over the period 0 to T by σ, where σ is given by σ 2 = 1 T 0 σ2 t dt. 14

The P&L may be expressed as P &L = (σ 2 t σ 2 )T e rt S2 0 2 2 S 2V (S 0, T ; σ h ) 2 + ( σ 2 σh [e 2 )T rt S2 0 2 S 2V (S 0, T ; σ h ) 1 T + 0 ( σ 2 σ 2 t )er(t t)s2 t 2 2 S 2V (S t, T t; σ h ) dt. 0 er(t t)s2 t 2 2 ] S 2V (S t, T t; σ h ) dt Defining g t as g t = e r(t t)s2 t 2 then the P&L is thus equal to P &L = (σ 2 t σ 2 )T g 0 +( σ 2 σ 2 h )T [ 2 S 2V (S t, T t; σ h ) = er(t t) 2σ h σ V (S t, T t; σ h ), g 0 1 T 0 g t dt ] + ( σ 2 σt 2 )g t dt. 0 15

The P&L can be broken up into three components: [ P &L = (σt 2 σ 2 )T g }{{ 0 + ( σ 2 σ 2 } h )T g 0 1 ] T T g t dt + 0 1 } {{ } 2 0 ( σ 2 σ 2 t )g t dt }{{} 3. 1. The variance risk component or a variance swap exposure for a notional amount equal to T g 0 and a variance strike equal to the square of the option implied volatility. 2. The vega risk factor, which stems from the fact that the option is hedged at the implied volatility σ h instead of at the realized volatility σ. This term is indeed null if the trader is able to hedge at the realized but unknown volatility. 16

3. The Volatility path dependency risk or model risk factor that depends on the historical behavior of realized volatility. Under the Black & Scholes assumption, the instantaneous volatility σ t is constant and thus equal to the realized volatility between time t and T. However, should the volatility vary over time, ( σ 2 σt 2) will no longer be zero. As g t is a decreasing function of time to maturity, this term will be positive if instantaneous, or intraday, volatility rises during the life of the option. The term also depends on the true distribution of stock returns. Based on realistic simulations, the variance risk only represents 52% of the total P&L resulting from delta-hedging an option. As a result, delta-hedging options does not provide pure exposure to volatility, given that the P&L not only depends on variance risk but also on a vega risk which itself results from the face that risk cannot be hedged at the unknown future realized volatility and that volatility may not be constant over time. 17

Delta-hedging options yields further risk sources The above analysis was done without taking into account dividends and by assuming a constant interest rate. In practice, traders face the risk of unknown dividends being paid during the life of the option, while with interest rates liable to vary over time, the option vega may change if the interest rate changes. Furthermore, option s delta-hedging is impacted by transaction costs and liquidity issues. The above analysis does not take into account the fact that trading stocks is costly and that certain stocks and indices may lack liquidity. We need new derivatives instruments that enable investors to take a view on volatility without bearing any other risks. 18

4.2 Volatility swaps Even though variance swaps can be priced and replicated easily, they are still less actively traded compared to volatility swaps. First order approximation: or ( V R ) 2 (K s/d ) 2 2K s/d ( V R K s/d ) V R K s/d 1 [ VR (K s/d ) 2], K s/d = K var. 2K s/d To make K s/d < K var, consider the second order Taylor expansion of g(v R ) = V R around K var = E 0 [V R ], we have V R K var + 1 2 K var (V R K var ) 1 8(K var ) 3/2(V R K var ) 2. 19

20

Taking the expected values on both sides, we obtain K s/d = E 0 [ V R ] K var 1 8(K var ) 3/2 E 0[(V R K var ) 2 ] }{{} var 0 (V R ) }{{} convexity correction The convexity correction represents the mismatch between K s/d and Kvar. Under this approximation, we achieve K s/d < K var. The above formula does not give a straightforward formula for K s/d since the conditional variance of the realized variance has to be estimated. Broadie and Jain (2008) show that this convexity correction formula to approximate fair volatility strikes may not provide good estimates in jump-diffusion models. 21

4.3 Pricing of discrete variance swaps A discrete variance swap is a forward contract on the discrete realized variance of the price dynamics of the underlying security. The floating leg of the discrete variance swap is the discrete realized variance and is calculated using the second moment of log returns of the underlying asset. R t = ln ( Sti S ti 1 ), i = 1, 2,..., n. Here, 0 = t 0 < t 1 < < t n = T is a partition of the time interval [0, T ] into n equal segments of length t, i.e., t i = it/n for each i = 0, 1,..., n. 22

The discrete realized variance, V d (0, n, T ) can be written as: V d (0, n, T ) = 1 (n 1) t n i=1 R 2 i = ni=1 ( ln S t i S ti 1 ) 2 (n 1) t The floating leg of the discretely sampled realized variance, V c (0, T ), in the limit n. That is,. V c (0, T ) lim n V d (0, n, T ) = lim n n (n 1)T n i=1 R 2 i. 23

Heston stochastic volatility model In this section, we present an analysis of the linear rate of convergence of discrete variance strikes to continuous variance strikes with number of sampling dates under the Heston stochastic volatility (SV) model. The Heston model is given by ds t = rs t dt + v t S t (ρdw 1 t + 1 ρ 2 dw 2 t ) dv t = κ(θ v t )dt + σ v vt dw 1 t. The first equation gives the dynamics of the stock price S t and vt is the volatility. The second equation gives the evolution of the variance which follows a square root process: θ is the long run mean variance, κ represents the speed of mean reversion, and σ v is a parameter which determines the volatility of the variance process. The process Wt 1 and Wt 2 are independent standard Brownian motions under risk-neutral measure Q, and ρ represents the instantaneous correlation between the return process and the volatility process. 24

SV model: Continuous variance strike In the Heston stochastic volatility model, the fair continuous variance strike Kvar = E[V c(0, T )] is given by E ( 1 T 0 v s ds ) = θ + v 0 θ κt (1 e κt ). The fair continuous variance strike in the Heston stochastic volatility model is independent of the volatility of variance σ v. Similarly, the variance of the continuous realized variance, Var(V c (0, T )), can be obtained by calculating the second moment of the Laplace transform. var ( 1 T = σ2 v e 2κ(T t) t v s ds ) 2κ 3 T 2 {2[e 2κ(T t) 2e κ(t t) κ(t t) 1](v t θ) + [4e κ(t t) 3e 2κ(T t) + 2e 2κ(T t) κ(t t) 1]θ}. The variance of the continuous realized variance depends on the volatility of variance. 25

SV model: Discrete variance strike In the Heston stochastic volatility model, the expectation of the discrete realized variance and its continuous counterpart are related by where E 0 (V d (0, n, T )) = E 0 (V c (0, T )) + g(r, ρ, σ v, κ, θ, n), ( 1 ) [ g(r, ρ, σ v, κ, θ, n) = r2 T n 1 + 1 T E T v t dt 0 n 1 i=0 + E( t i+1 t i+1 t i t i (n 1) t n 1 i=0 E[ρ( t i+1 σ v (n 1) t 1 n 1 v t v s dtds) rt n 1 + ( 1 4 ρκ ) σ v t i vt dt)(v ti+1 v t i )]. ρκθt (n 1)σ v ] 26

Since g(r, ρ, σ v, κ, θ, n) = O ( 1 n ), the expectation of discrete realized variance converges to the expected continuous realized variance linearly with the sampling size (n = T/ t). That is, K var (n) = K var + g(r, ρ, σ v, κ, θ, n) and the discrete variance strike converges to the continuous variance strike linearly with t, where t = T/n. 27

4.6 Timer options A standard timer call option can be viewed as a call option with random maturity which depends on the time needed for a pre-specified variance budget to be fully consumed. A variance budget is calculated as the target volatility squared, multiplied by the target maturity. Mathematical definition Suppose the asset price is monitored at t j = j t, j = 0, 1,..., n. The annualized realized variance for the period [0, T ] is defined as σ 2 T = 1 (n 1) t n 1 i=0 ( ln S i+1 S i ) 2, T = n t. 28

The realized variance over time period [0, T ] is V T = n t σ T 2 n 1 i=0 The investor specifies a variance budget ( B = σ 2 0 T 0, ln S i+1 S i where T 0 is the estimated investment horizon and σ 0 is the forecast volatility during the investing period. The timer call with random maturity pays max(s tj k, 0) at the first time t j when the realized variance exceeds B. That is, k 1 ( t j = min k > 0, ln S ) 2 i+1 B S i. i=0 ) 2. 29

Option strategy without paying the volatility risk premium The price of a vanilla call option is determined by the level of implied volatility quoted in the market (as well as maturity and strike price). The level of impled volatility is often higher than the realized volatility (risk premium due to the uncertainty of future market direction). High implied volatility means call options are often overpriced. In the timer option, the investor only pays the real cost of the call and does not suffer from high implied volatility. The volatility target may be set to lower the cost of hedging, as the implied realized risk premia may be removed. 30

The first trade was in April 2007 on HSBC with a June expiry. The implied volatility on the plain vanilla call was slightly above 15%, but the client sets a target volatility level of 12%, a little higher than the prevailing realized volatility level of around 10%. The premium of the timer call has 20% discount compared to the vanilla call counterpart. The realized volatility has been around 9.5% since the inception of the trade. The maturity of the timer call is 60% longer than the original vanilla call. 31

Bullish view of the market Long a timer call, short a vanilla call. volatility are negatively correlated. Usually, stock price and The implied volatility in the market is too high currently, and subsequent realized volatility will be less than that implied in the market. By setting the volatility target to be below the current implied volatility level (cost of timer call would be less than the comparative vanilla call). If the stock shifts higher over the period, the tenor of the Timer Option would be longer; and a net credit would be received that captures the value due to the difference in Time Value of the two options. 32