MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 11 10/9/2013. Martingales and stopping times II

Similar documents
4 Martingales in Discrete-Time

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009

6. Martingales. = Zn. Think of Z n+1 as being a gambler s earnings after n+1 games. If the game if fair, then E [ Z n+1 Z n

Convergence. Any submartingale or supermartingale (Y, F) converges almost surely if it satisfies E Y n <. STAT2004 Martingale Convergence

Asymptotic results discrete time martingales and stochastic algorithms

1 IEOR 4701: Notes on Brownian Motion

Lecture 23: April 10

Last Time. Martingale inequalities Martingale convergence theorem Uniformly integrable martingales. Today s lecture: Sections 4.4.1, 5.

Advanced Probability and Applications (Part II)

An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus

An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus

FE 5204 Stochastic Differential Equations

Outline Brownian Process Continuity of Sample Paths Differentiability of Sample Paths Simulating Sample Paths Hitting times and Maximum

Lecture 19: March 20

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

Martingale Measure TA

S t d with probability (1 p), where

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

Brownian Motion. Richard Lockhart. Simon Fraser University. STAT 870 Summer 2011

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims

1 Rare event simulation and importance sampling

BROWNIAN MOTION II. D.Majumdar

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Probability without Measure!

Laws of probabilities in efficient markets

CONVERGENCE OF OPTION REWARDS FOR MARKOV TYPE PRICE PROCESSES MODULATED BY STOCHASTIC INDICES

The value of foresight

Drunken Birds, Brownian Motion, and Other Random Fun

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

X i = 124 MARTINGALES

1 Geometric Brownian motion

Homework Assignments

Non-semimartingales in finance

CONTINUOUS TIME PRICING AND TRADING: A REVIEW, WITH SOME EXTRA PIECES

Comparison of proof techniques in game-theoretic probability and measure-theoretic probability

Financial Mathematics. Spring Richard F. Bass Department of Mathematics University of Connecticut

Deterministic Income under a Stochastic Interest Rate

MTH The theory of martingales in discrete time Summary

18.440: Lecture 35 Martingales and the optional stopping theorem

Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus

Additional questions for chapter 3

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

Martingales. Will Perkins. March 18, 2013

Statistics and Their Distributions

Model-independent bounds for Asian options

Changes of the filtration and the default event risk premium

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

Model-independent bounds for Asian options

Hedging under Arbitrage

Stochastic Differential Equations in Finance and Monte Carlo Simulations

Arbitrages and pricing of stock options

PAPER 211 ADVANCED FINANCIAL MODELS

Module 10:Application of stochastic processes in areas like finance Lecture 36:Black-Scholes Model. Stochastic Differential Equation.

Math 6810 (Probability) Fall Lecture notes

MAT25 LECTURE 10 NOTES. = a b. > 0, there exists N N such that if n N, then a n a < ɛ

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models

Robust Pricing and Hedging of Options on Variance

Math-Stat-491-Fall2014-Notes-V

Sensitivity of American Option Prices with Different Strikes, Maturities and Volatilities

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING

PAPER 27 STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND APPLICATIONS

BROWNIAN MOTION Antonella Basso, Martina Nardon

Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models. Beatrice Acciaio

Introduction to Game-Theoretic Probability

Probability, Price, and the Central Limit Theorem. Glenn Shafer. Rutgers Business School February 18, 2002

Stochastic Modelling in Finance

Finite Additivity in Dubins-Savage Gambling and Stochastic Games. Bill Sudderth University of Minnesota

Outline of Lecture 1. Martin-Löf tests and martingales

On robust pricing and hedging and the resulting notions of weak arbitrage

Stochastic calculus Introduction I. Stochastic Finance. C. Azizieh VUB 1/91. C. Azizieh VUB Stochastic Finance

Value of Flexibility in Managing R&D Projects Revisited

Lecture Notes for Chapter 6. 1 Prototype model: a one-step binomial tree

Stochastic Calculus, Application of Real Analysis in Finance

Stochastic Calculus - An Introduction

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

A1: American Options in the Binomial Model

Lecture 7: Bayesian approach to MAB - Gittins index

6 Stopping times and the first passage

Lecture 14: Examples of Martingales and Azuma s Inequality. Concentration

Optimal Stopping. Nick Hay (presentation follows Thomas Ferguson s Optimal Stopping and Applications) November 6, 2008

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8

Brownian Motion, the Gaussian Lévy Process

3 Stock under the risk-neutral measure

Mathematical Finance in discrete time

Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable?

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

Prospect Theory, Partial Liquidation and the Disposition Effect

Theoretical Statistics. Lecture 3. Peter Bartlett

Exponential martingales and the UI martingale property

Remarks: 1. Often we shall be sloppy about specifying the ltration. In all of our examples there will be a Brownian motion around and it will be impli

MESURES DE RISQUE DYNAMIQUES DYNAMIC RISK MEASURES

1. For a special whole life insurance on (x), payable at the moment of death:

Optimal robust bounds for variance options and asymptotically extreme models

Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable?

Insurance against Market Crashes

Central Limit Theorem 11/08/2005

Economics has never been a science - and it is even less now than a few years ago. Paul Samuelson. Funeral by funeral, theory advances Paul Samuelson

Computable analysis of martingales and related measure-theoretic topics, with an emphasis on algorithmic randomness

Transcription:

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.65/15.070J Fall 013 Lecture 11 10/9/013 Martingales and stopping times II Content. 1. Second stopping theorem.. Doob-Kolmogorov inequality. 3. Applications of stopping theorems to hitting times of a Brownian motion. 1 Second stopping theorem In the previous lecture we established no gambling scheme can produce a positive gain in expectation if there is a limit on the number of rounds the game is played. We now establish a similar result assuming that there is a limit on the amount of wealth possessed by the player. Theorem 1. Suppose X n is a supermartingale that is uniformly bounded. That is X n M a.s., for some M. Suppose τ is a stopping time. Then E[X τ ] E[X 0 ]. If, in addition X n is a martingale, then E[X τ ] = E[X 0 ]. The gambling interpretation of this theorem is as follows: suppose we tried to use the double the stakes algorithm, which we know guarantees winning a dollar, when there are no restrictions. But now suppose that there is a limit on how negative we can go (for example the amount of debt allowed). Say this limit is M. Consider a modified process Y n = X n τ. Then from our description M Y n 1 < M. Also we remember from the previous lecture that Y n is a supermartingale. Thus it is a bounded supermartingale. Theorem 1 then tells us that E[Y τ ] = E[X τ ] E[X 0 ], namely the scheme does not work anymore. (Remember that without the restriction, the scheme produces wealth X τ = 1 with probability one. In particular, E[X τ ] = 1 > X 0 = 0). Proof of Theorem 1.. Observe, that E[ X τ ] M <. Consider Y n = X n τ. Then Y n converges to X τ a.s. as n. Since Y n M a.s., then 1

using the Bounded Convergence Theorem, lim n E[Y n ] = E[X τ ]. On the other hand, we established in Corollary 1 in the previous lecture, that Y n is a supermartingale. Therefore E[Y n ] E[Y 0 ] = E[X 0 ]. Combining, we obtain E[X τ ] E[X 0 ]. Doob-Kolmogorov inequality We now establish a technical but a very useful result, which is an analogue of Markov/Chebyshev s bounds on random variables. Theorem (Doob-Kolmogorov inequality). Suppose X n is a non-negative submartingale adapted to {F n } and E > 0. Then for every n N E[X ] n P( max X n E). E If X n is a martingale, then the non-negativity condition can be dropped. The convenience of this result is that we can bound the worst case deviation of a submartingale using its value at the end of time interval. Proof. Using Jensen s inequality we established that if X n is a martingale then X n is a submartingale. Since X n is non-negative, the second part follows from the first. To establish the first part, consider the events A = {max X m E} and B m = {max 1 i m1 X i E, X m > E}. Namely, A is the event that the submartingale never exceeds E and B m is the event that it does so at time m for the first time. We have Ω = A B m and the events A, B m are mutually exclusive. Then Note E[X ] = E[X 1{A}] + E[X 1{B m }] E[X 1{B m }]. n n n n E[X 1{B m }] = E[(X n X m + X m ) 1{B m }] n = E[(X n X m ) 1{B m }] + E[(X n X m )X m 1{B m }] + E[X 1{B m }] m The first of the summands is non-negative. The last is at least E P(B m ), since on the event B m we have X m > E. We now analyze the second term and

here we use the tower property: E[(X n X m )X m 1{B m }] = E[E[(X n X m )X m 1{B m } F m ]] = E[X m 1{B m }E[(X n X m ) F m ]] 0, where the second equality follows since 1{B m } F m and the last inequality follows since X n is a submartingale and X m 1{B m } E > 0 on ω B m and = 0 on ω / B m. We conclude that E[X ] E P(B m ) = E P( m B m ) = E P( max X m > E). n This concludes the proof. Corollary 1. Suppose X n is a martingale and p 1. Then for every E > 0 E[ X n p ] P( max X n E). Proof. The proof of the general case is more complicated, but when p we almost immediately obtain the result. Using conditional Jensen s inequality we know that X n is a submartingale, as is a convex function. It is also nonis convex increasing when p and x 0. Recall from p negative. Function x p the previous lecture that this implies X n is also a submartingale. Applying Theorem we obtain P( max X n E) = P( max X n E p p p E ) E[ X n p ] E p. Analogue of this corollary holds in continuous time when the process is continuous. We just state this result without proving it. Theorem 3. Suppose {X t } t R+ is a martingale which has a.s. continuous sample paths. Then for every p 1, T > 0, E > 0, E[ X T p ] P( sup X t E). 0 t T E p 3

3 Applications to hitting times of a Brownian motion We now use the martingale theory and optional stopping theorems to derive some properties of hitting times of a Brownian motion. Our setting is either a standard Brownian motion B(t) or a Brownian motion with drift B µ (t) = µt + σb(t). In both cases the starting value is assumed 0. We fix a < 0 < b and ask the question: what is the probability that B µ (t) hits a before b? For simplicity we use B instead of B µ, but mention that we talk about Brownian motion with drift. We define T a = inf{t : B µ (t) = a}, T b = inf{t : B µ (t) = b}, T ab = min(t a, T b ). In Lecture 6, Problem 1 we established that when B is standard, lim sup t B(t) = a.s. Thus T b < a.s. By symmetry, T a < a.s. Now we ask the question: what is the probability P(T ab = T a )? We will use the optional stopping theorems established before. The only issue is that we are now dealing with continuous time processes. The derivations of stopping theorems require more details (for example defining predictable sequences is trickier). We skip the details and just assume that optional stopping theorems apply in our case as well. The case of the standard Brownian motion is the simplest. Theorem 4. Let T a, T b, T ab be defined with respect to the standard Brownian motion B(t). Then b P(T ab = T a ) =. a + b Proof. Recall that B is a martingale. Observe that T ab defines a stopping time: the event {T ab t} B t (stopping T ab t is determined completely by the path of the Brownian motion up to time t). Therefore by Corollary 1 in the previous lecture, Y t B(t T ab ) is also a martingale. Note that it is a bounded martingale, since its absolute value is at most max( a, b ). Theorem 1 applied to Y t then implies that E[Y Tab ] = E[B(T ab )] = E[Y 0 ] = E[B(0)] = 0. On the other hand, when T ab = T a, we have B(T ab ) = B(T a ) = a and, conversely, when T ab = T b, we have B(T ab ) = B(T b ) = b. Therefore E[B(T ab )] = ap(t ab = T a ) + bp(t ab = T b ) = a P(T ab = T a ) + b P(T ab = T b ) Since P(T ab = T a )+P(T ab = T b ) = 1, then, combining with the fact E[B(T ab )] we obtain b a P(T ab = T a ) =, P(T ab = T b ) =. a + b a + b 4

We now consider the more difficult case, when the drift of the Brownian motion µ = 0. Specifically, assume µ < 0. Recall, that in this case lim t B(t) = a.s., so T ab T a < a.s. Again we want to compute P(T ab = T a ). 1 We fix drift µ < 0, variance σ > 0 and consider q(β) = µβ + σ β. Proposition 1. For every β, the process V (t) = e βb(t)q(β)t is a martingale. Proof. We first need to check that E[ V (t) ] <. We leave it as an exercise. We have for every 0 s < t β(b(t)b(s)) q(β)(ts) E[V (t) B s ] = E[e e e βb(s)q(β)s B s ] β(b(t)b(s)) q(β)(ts) βb(s)q(β)s = E[e ]e e q(β)(ts) E[e β(b(t)b(s)) ]V (s). = e where the second equality follows from the ind. increments property of the Brownian motion, and from the fact E[e βb(s)q(β)s B βb(s)q(β)s s ] = e. Since d B(t) B(s) = N(µ(t s), σ (t s)), then E[e β(b(t)b(s)) ] is the Laplace transform of this normal r.v. which is βµ(ts)+ 1 σ β (ts) q(β)(ts) e = e. Combining, we obtain that E[V (t) B s ] = V (s). Therefore V (t) is a martingale. Now that we know that V (t) is a martingale, we can try to apply the optional stopping theorem. For that we need to have a stopping time, and we will use T ab. We also need conditions for which the expected value at the stopping time is equal to the expected value at time zero. We use the following observation. Suppose β is such that q(β) 0. Then 0 V (t T ab ) e βb a.s. Indeed, the left side of the inequality follows trivially from non-negativity of V. For the righthand side, observe that for t T β a βb ) βb ab we have V (t) max(e, e = e, and the assertion follows. Thus V is a.s. a bounded martingale. Again we use Theorem 1 to conclude that We now set β = µ/σ. Then q(β) = 0. Note that E[V (T ab )] = V (0) = 1. (1) V (T µa ab )1{T ab = T a } = e σ 1{T ab = T a } V (T µb ab )1{T ab = T b } = e σ 1{T ab = T b } 5

The previous identity gives µa µb σ σ 1 = E[V (T ab )] = e P(T ab = T a ) + e P(T ab = T b ). From this and using µ < 0, we recover P(T ab = T b ) = µa µ a σ σ 1 e 1 e =. µb µa µ b µ a e σ e σ e σ e σ Compared with the driftless case, the probability of hitting b first is exponentially tilted. Now let us take a. The events A a = {T ab = T a } are monotone: A t a A a ' for a < a < 0. Therefore µ a [ ] 1 e σ P( µ b a<0 A a ) = lim P(A a ) = lim 1 = 1 e σ. µ b µ a a a e σ e σ But what is the event a<0 A a? Since Brownian motion has continuous paths, this event is exactly the event that the Brownian motion never hits the positive level b. That is the event sup t 0 B(t) < b. We conclude that when the drift µ of the Brownian motion is negative µ b σ P(sup B(t) b) = e. t 0 Recall, from Lecture 6, that we already established this fact directly from the properties of the Brownian motion the supremum of a Brownian motion with a negative drift has an exponential distribution with parameter µ /σ. 4 Additional reading materials Durrett [1] Chapter 4. Grimmett and Stirzaker [] Section 7.8. References [1] R. Durrett, Probability: theory and examples, Duxbury Press, second edition, 1996. [] G. R. Grimmett and D. R. Stirzaker, Probability and random processes, Oxford University Press, 005. 6

MIT OpenCourseWare http://ocw.mit.edu 15.070J / 6.65J Advanced Stochastic Processes Fall 013 For information about citing these materials or our Terms of Use, visit: http://ocw.mit.edu/terms.