Criteria and Methods for Estimating the Impact of Mandates on the Number of Individuals Who Become Uninsured in Response to Premium Increases

Similar documents
The California Cost and Coverage Model: Analyses of the Financial Impacts of Benefit Mandates for the California Legislature

ESTIMATES OF SOURCES OF HEALTH INSURANCE IN CALIFORNIA FOR 2014

Individual Health Insurance Market

Impact of Individual Mandate Penalty Elimination and Other Market Factors on Coverage Nationally and in California

Issue Brief: Interaction between California State Benefit Mandates and the Affordable Care Act s Essential Health Benefits

Estimating the Change in Coverage in California with a Basic Health Program

UNIVERSAL HEALTHCARE COUNCIL 2013 OVERVIEW OF THE AFFORDABLE CARE ACT

HEALTH CARE REFORM Focus on Group Coverage Blue Cross and Blue Shield of Minnesota. All rights reserved.

Overview of the Federal Affordable Care Act (ACA)

An Evaluation of the Impact of Medicaid Expansion in New Hampshire

About two-thirds of americans who become uninsured do so when

COVERAGE AND ACCESS. Julie Sonier, Deputy Director State Health Access Data Assistance Center (SHADAC) at University of Minnesota

Quantifying Tax Credits for People Now Buying Insurance on Their Own

Overview of the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act (ACA) Steven Abramson, Marketing Manager Community Health Alliance of Pasadena

Medicare Policy RAISING THE AGE OF MEDICARE ELIGIBILITY. A Fresh Look Following Implementation of Health Reform JULY 2011

Health Care Spending Under Reform: Less Uncompensated Care and Lower Costs to Small Employers

Complying with Health Care Reform

OPTIONS TO IMPROVE AFFORDABILITY IN CALIFORNIA S INDIVIDUAL HEALTH INSURANCE MARKET COVERED CALIFORNIA WORKING DRAFT.

Summary On March 23, 2010, the President signed into law health reform legislation (the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act, PPACA, P.L

Diminishing Offer and Coverage Rates Among Private Sector Employees

Nongroup insurance, also referred to as individual insurance, covers

Health Care: Obama Officials Look Back at the ACA and the Path Forward

The Affordable Care Act and the Income Tax. By Greg Martinez December 2013

REPORT OF THE COUNCIL ON MEDICAL SERVICE

Factors Affecting Individual Premium Rates in 2014 for California

GENERAL INFORMATION BULLETIN

The Affordable Care Act: Next Steps In Implementation

Testimony of. Judith Feder, PhD. Before the. Committee on Oversight and Government Reform. U.S. House of Representatives.

In 2014 the Affordable Care Act (ACA)

Predicted Effects of the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act (ACA) on States. Peter Hussey, Ph.D.

The Affordable Care Act; 2014 and Beyond

Covered California Delivering on the Promise of Care. State of Reform Health Policy Conference Anne Price November 6, 2015

MYTHS & REALITIES OF HEALTH CARE REFORM

Important Consumer Considerations in Design of Pediatric Dental Benefits

OPTIONS TO IMPROVE AFFORDABILITY IN CALIFORNIA S INDIVIDUAL HEALTH INSURANCE MARKET COVERED CALIFORNIA WORKING DRAFT.

PROPOSALS TO INCREASE HEALTH CARE ACCESS IN HAWAI`I

Understanding Health Care Reform

The Affordable Care Act: A Summary on Healthcare Reform. The Wyoming Department of Insurance

The President s Health Reform Proposal: Impact on Access and Affordability in California

HEALTH TECHNICAL REPORT. An Analysis from RAND COMPARE

HEALTH TECHNICAL REPORT. An Analysis from RAND COMPARE

ASSESSING THE RESULTS

The Economic Downturn and Changes in Health Insurance Coverage, John Holahan & Arunabh Ghosh The Urban Institute September 2004

Women s Coverage, Access, and Affordability: Key Findings from the 2017 Kaiser Women s Health Survey

OVERVIEW OF THE AFFORDABLE CARE ACT. September 23, 2013

FREQUENTLY ASKED QUESTIONS (FAQ) ABOUT THE ACA:

Uninsurance Is Not Just a Minority Issue: White Americans Are a Large Share of the Growth from 2000 to 2010

m e d i c a i d Five Facts About the Uninsured

Health Insurance Coverage in 2014: Significant Progress, but Gaps Remain

Price Sensitivity in Health Care: Implications for Health Care Policy

The Impact of the Tax System on Health Insurance Coverage

Federal Subsidies for Health Insurance Coverage for People Under Age 65: Tables from CBO s September 2017 Projections

You are not required to do anything with this notice but it is recommended that you keep it with your other important legal documents.

The Impact of the ACA on Wisconsin's Health Insurance Market

Update on the Affordable Care Act. Kevin Shah, MD MBA. Review major elements of the affordable care act

Modeling Health Reform without the Mandate to Have Coverage. Staff Working Paper #14. John Sheils and Randall Haught

ISSUE BRIEF April 2012

HEALTH COVERAGE EXPANSION IN CALIFORNIA: WHAT CAN CONSUMERS AFFORD TO SPEND?

H.R American Health Care Act of 2017

Employer Obligations and Coverage Options under the Affordable Care Act in 2014/2015

The Cost of Failure to Enact Health Reform: Implications for States. Bowen Garrett, John Holahan, Lan Doan, and Irene Headen

The Facts Medicaid Access in Northeast Ohio. Answers to Frequently Asked Questions FAQ. The Center for Health Affairs

The Affordable Care Act: Seven Years Later

IOM Workshop The Impact of the Affordable Care Act on U.S. Preparedness Resources and Programs

Achieving Universal Coverage through Comprehensive Health Reform: The Vermont Experience

IMPLICATIONS OF THE AFFORDABLE CARE ACT FOR COUNTY EMPLOYERS

Affordable Care Act: Impact on the Indiana Market

Maryland Health Care Reform Simulation Model: Detailed Analysis and Methodology

State of California. Financial Feasibility of a. Basic Health Program. June 28, Prepared with funding from the California HealthCare Foundation

The creation of health insurance exchanges. How Choices In Exchange Design For States Could Affect Insurance Premiums And Levels Of Coverage

HEALTH WEALTH CAREER HEALTH REFORM FIVE YEARS IN

REPORT OF THE COUNCIL ON MEDICAL SERVICE. Effects of the Massachusetts Reform Effort and the Individual Mandate

HEALTH POLICY COLLOQUIUM BRIEF

How Would States Be Affected By Health Reform?

The Affordable Care Act: Opportunities to Influence Implementation

Deteriorating Health Insurance Coverage from 2000 to 2010: Coverage Takes the Biggest Hit in the South and Midwest

The Affordable Care Act (ACA) What are the Financial Impacts to your Business? Presented For: Dallas CPA Society May 8 th, 2013

What is the Employer s responsibility? Basically, eligible employers must offer affordable coverage to all eligible employees Or pay a penalty.

By Ann Hwang, Sara Rosenbaum, and Benjamin D. Sommers

INDIVIDUAL SHARED RESPONSIBILITY PROVISION

SENATE RELEASES DRAFT ACA REPLACEMENT BILL

The Affordable Care Act: Information for Wyoming Consumers

Potential Employer Penalties Under the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act (ACA)

The Affordable Care Act and Covered California. A Guide for Health Care Providers

STATE OF FLORIDA et al v. UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF HEALTH AND HUMAN SERVICES et al Doc. 83 Att. 3. Exhibit 2. Dockets.Justia.

Implementation of the Affordable Care Act in California

Health Care Reform. Navigating The Maze Of. What s Inside

The Affordable Care Act: A Summary on Healthcare Reform. The Wyoming Department of Insurance

S E P T E M B E R Comparing Federal Government Surveys that Count Uninsured People in America

Changes Proposed to the Affordable Care Act and Medicaid Could Cost the District $1 Billion or More Each Year

Summary of House Discussion Draft, February 10, 2017

You are not required to do anything with this notice but it is recommended that you keep it with your other important legal documents.

The Affordable Care Act (ACA)

THE AFFORDABLE CARE ACT: 2014 AND BEYOND

The ACA s Coverage Expansion in Michigan: Demographic Characteristics and Coverage Projections

Health Reform Legislation and Impact on the Indian Health System

HOW WILL UNINSURED CHILDREN BE AFFECTED BY HEALTH REFORM?

Prior Experience with the Nongroup Health Insurance Market: Implications for Enrollment under the Affordable Care Act

California Employer Health Benefits Survey

FINANCIAL CONSIDERATIONS FOR INDIVIDUALS, EMPLOYERS, AND THE LOCAL PUBLIC HEALTH SYSTEM

Transcription:

Criteria and Methods for Estimating the Impact of Mandates on the Number of Individuals Who Become Uninsured in Response to Premium Increases By the program s authorizing statute, 1 the California Health Benefits Review Program (CHBRP) is requested to report on the financial impacts of proposed legislation, including the extent to which mandating or repealing the proposed benefit or service would not diminish or eliminate access to currently available health care benefits or services ; and the extent to which costs resulting from lack of coverage or repeal of coverage are or would be shifted to other payers, including both public and private entities. Health insurance benefit mandates that increase premiums may increase the number of uninsured or the number of individuals eligible for public health insurance programs, because some individuals may not be able to afford to purchase insurance with higher premiums, and some employers may not be able to afford to offer such insurance. CHBRP examines whether a given benefit mandate impacts the number of uninsured. The implementation of the Affordable Care Act (ACA) 2 changes the impact of a given benefit mandate on insurance coverage. This is due to ACA requirements including the individual insurance mandate, the employer requirement to offer affordable coverage, Medicaid coverage expansion, and tax credits to help individuals purchase insurance coverage in the state or federal marketplaces (formerly known as exchanges ). The financial penalties for lack of compliance with the individual mandate and the employer requirement may reduce the number of individuals that forego purchasing coverage or employers who stop offering coverage. In addition, tax credits or subsidies are designed to improve the affordability of insurance coverage. Collectively, these aspects of the ACA have changed the market dynamics and the response of individuals and employers to premium increases. This paper describes: (1) the factors that underlie employer and individual reactions to premium increases; (2) the criteria that CHBRP uses to determine whether premium increases for a particular mandate would be substantial enough to impact the number of those enrolled in the employersponsored and individually purchased health insurance; and (3) the method used by CHBRP to produce these estimates. Factors That Affect Reactions to Premium Increases Increases in insurance premiums can generate reactions in the employer-sponsored and individual health insurance market that in turn affect the number of insured employees and individuals. In the employer-sponsored insurance (ESI) market (i.e., group market), premium increases can affect the: (1) offer rate, that is, the percentage of employers who offer health insurance to their employees; (2) 1 Available at: www.chbrp.org/documents/authorizing_statute.pdf. 2 The federal Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act (P.L.111-148) and the Health Care and Education Reconciliation Act (P.L 111-152) were enacted in March 2010. Together, these laws are referred to as the Affordable Care Act (ACA). March 16, 2015 www.chbrp.org Page 1 of 8

eligibility rate, that is, the percentage of employees in firms offering health insurance who are eligible for that benefit; and (3) take-up rate, that is, among employees in firms offering health insurance who are eligible, the percentage who decide to accept the employer s health insurance benefit. The impact of premium increases on rates of offer and take-up vary in employer-sponsored and individual markets for a number of reasons described further in the following sections. Employer-Sponsored Insurance Market Health insurance premiums in the group market have been increasing rapidly for most of this decade and exceeding the rate of inflation. For example, in 2011 group premiums rose by 8.1%, in 2012 by 6.4%, and in 2013 by 5.7% (CHCF, 2014). These ongoing premium increases suggest that premium increases attributable to a specific health benefit mandate are likely to be overshadowed by the secular trend of increasing premiums. The predicted statewide rate of premium increases in benefit mandate bills analyzed by CHBRP in 2014 ranged from 0.003% to 0.100%. 3 Overall, the number of uninsured Californians has declined post-aca due to the Medicaid expansion, guaranteed issue, age-rated health insurance coverage, and individual subsidies to help purchase coverage through Covered CA. In 2014, Medi-Cal enrolled 1.9 million individuals, newly eligible due to the ACA (Medina and Saporta, 2014). An additional 1.4 million were enrolled through Covered California in 2014, though some of these enrollees may have had other coverage previously (Covered California, 2015). These policy interventions could offset the impact of rising premiums on the number of uninsured. Employer Offer Rate Elasticity of demand is a way of gauging responsiveness to price changes. The greater the elasticity, the more responsive the employer would be to a given change in insurance prices. When the elasticity is less negative (or more inelastic), employers will be less sensitive to changes in price. Studies suggest that employers typically do not stop offering health insurance when premiums increase. Literature on employers incentives to offer insurance indicates a negative, albeit low, price elasticity of demand. Prior to the ACA, price elasticity among employers was generally in the range between 0.05 and 0.07, meaning that an increase of 1% in the price of insurance will reduce coverage by 0.05% to 0.07%. (Gruber and Lettau, 2004; Hadley, 2006; Marquis and Long, 1995; Royalty and Hagens, 2005). Studies focusing on the insurance behavior of small firms (or small groups) suggest that elasticity is more negative than for the health insurance market in general because small firms are more responsive to changes in the price of insurance (Blumberg et al., 1999; Feldman et al., 1997; Jensen and Gabel, 1992). The use of health benefits to attract the best workers is one explanation given for the reluctance of employers to discontinue group health benefits. The ACA requires 4 that employers with 50 or more full-time equivalent employees must offer affordable coverage or face a penalty. Thus, employers will have an additional incentive to continue offering coverage to avoid penalties. 3 All of CHBRP s analyses are available at: http://chbrp.org/completed_analyses/index.php. 4 ACA Section 1513. March 16, 2015 www.chbrp.org Page 2 of 8

Employee Eligibility Rate Research has demonstrated that rising health insurance premiums are associated with lower wage growth (Cutler and Madrian, 1998), decreased contribution to other benefits (Goldman et al., 2005), and changes in the composition of employment (Baicker and Chandra, 2005); that is, employers may respond to increased premiums by shifting employment to part-time employees with limited benefits in order to avoid increased health care costs. Because changes in employment are associated with only a small rise in uninsurance, eligibility rates are not considered a prime determinant in uninsurance (Hadley, 2006). Employee Take-Up Rate Much of the literature on the effects of premium increases on insurance coverage has dealt with the impact of employee out-of-pocket premium expenditures or net premiums (defined as the total premium minus the employer s share of the premium) on take-up rates (Polsky et al., 2005). These studies do not necessarily measure employer response to rising premiums, specifically, what portion of premium increases to pass onto employees. Instead, they focus on measuring the direct response of employees to increases in their out-of-pocket expenditures for premiums, which may occur because of higher premiums, or a higher share of premiums being passed on by the employer, or both. CHBRP, therefore, employs a simplifying assumption that the share of premiums paid by employers does not change in response to a specific mandate. Elasticity of demand is relevant for employees or individuals (as well as for employers) as a way of gauging responsiveness to price or premium changes. The more negative the elasticity, the more responsive the employee or individual would be to smaller changes in premiums. The less negative the elasticity (or more inelastic), the less sensitive employees would be to changes in price. Chernew and colleagues found a very low elasticity of demand of 0.033 among low-income workers in small firms (25 or fewer employees) when net premiums ranged between 0% to 25% of total premiums (Chernew et al., 1997). They stated that the low elasticity reflected the high probability of baseline participation (that is, most are likely to opt to take-up insurance in the first place). Cooper and Vistnes found that net premiums had a significant effect on employees who enrolled in single coverage, but not on those who enrolled in family coverage (Cooper and Vistnes, 2003). They did not calculate price elasticity, but conducted simulation modeling which indicated that a $500 increase in annual net premiums would produce a decline in take-up rates among employees electing single coverage ranging from 2.31% to 9.44%, depending on the proportion of low-wage employees in the firm. Although these studies examine the impact of net premiums on take-up rates, they fail to take into consideration other possible sources of insurance available to many employees. Abraham and Royalty (2005) and Cooper and Schone (1997) found that many workers who decline coverage from their employer are eligible for and obtain insurance through a spouse. Polsky and colleagues found that higher net premiums increase the probability of employees being uninsured for both family and single coverage, although the effect was greater for those enrolling in single coverage (Polsky et al., 2005). They estimate that reducing the net premium to zero from a starting point ranging from $17 to $24 per member per month (PMPM) would increase the percentage of insured employees with family coverage by 0.5% and with single coverage by 4.9%, for an overall total of 2.2%. However, these dynamics are likely to change after ACA implementation because employees would have an additional incentive to take up employer-sponsored coverage because of penalties for remaining uninsured. March 16, 2015 www.chbrp.org Page 3 of 8

Individual (Non-Group) Market In the non-group or individual market, premiums directly affect the take-up rate, because individuals personally pay for all the premium costs. However, the literature on price elasticity in the individual, non-group market is quite limited. This body of research also generally finds price elasticity to be less than 0.5. (Gruber and Lettau, 2004; Hadley, 2006; Marquis and Long, 1995; Royalty and Hagens, 2005). In contrast to the group market, premiums vary by individual and can vary substantially by insurer for the same individual. In addition, surveys of the non-group market generally do not include information on the actuarial value of policies (Cooper and Schone, 1997). Marquis and Long (1995) estimated elasticity ranging from 0.3 to 0.4, but this study predated a number of state regulations affecting underwriting practices. Marquis and colleagues estimated elasticity in the California non-group market for family coverage ranging from 0.2 to 0.4 (Marquis et al., 2004). Auerbach and Ohri (2006) found accounting for health status and the effect of state-level premium rating regulations produced a higher estimated elasticity of 0.59 for individuals purchasing single coverage, with greater elasticity for poorer individuals and less elasticity among those with poorer health. Hadley (2006) found that low-income individuals (those with family incomes up to 400 percent of the federal poverty level) are much more price sensitive than high-income individuals (-0.18 versus -0.03). ACA has changed the individual insurance market dynamics, because it requires that all individuals must purchase coverage or face a penalty. In addition, ACA requires that states ban individual underwriting and guarantees that insurers sell policies to individuals in the state s health insurance exchange or the non-exchange individual markets. Tax credits or subsidies are offered to individuals with incomes from 138% to 400% of the FPL and individual penalties starting from $695/person in 2016 or 2.5% of taxable income (whichever is higher) 5 are included to incentivize individuals to seek and purchase coverage (Healthcare.gov, 2015). In California, premiums can only be based upon age, region, coverage type, and the number of individuals in the policy. The non-exchange, grandfathered plans, and large employers can base premiums on tobacco use as well (KFF, 2015). The combination of these factors, therefore, is likely to reduce the impact of premium increases on individuals in this market. CHBRP Criteria and Methodology In past CHBRP cycles, CHBRP focused its analyses of mandate impacts on the number of uninsured on mandates impact on employee and individual take-up rates, and employed a simplifying assumption that offer and eligibility rates would remain the same. Furthermore, CHBRP employed a simplifying assumption that the impact of premium increases is the same in the largegroup, small-group, and individual markets. In past cycles, CHBRP used a 0.11 elasticity of demand for private health insurance, employing the simplifying assumption that the elasticity is the same across different types of markets. As of 2015 and because of the ACA, CHBRP has changed its methodology and will use the California Simulation of Insurance Markets (CalSIM) model to predict changes in insurance coverage, given a benefit mandate. CalSIM predicts changes in source of insurance coverage and the number of uninsured given changes in insurance premiums in each market segment (CalSIM, 2015). CalSIM starts with the price elasticity cited above and further models the behavior of employers (offer, eligibility), employees (take-up), and individuals (take-up) given the incentives (Medi-Cal 5 The individual penalty is adjusted to inflation after 2016. March 16, 2015 www.chbrp.org Page 4 of 8

eligibility, subsidies, penalties) promoted by the ACA. CalSIM predicts the impact of percentage changes in premiums on rates of coverage in several market segments, including Medi-Cal, employment-sponsored group, subsidy eligible individual, subsidy-ineligible individual markets, and subsequent change on the rates of uninsurance. Using the CalSIM 1.9.2 estimates for 2016, CHBRP will use the predicted increase in percentage of uninsured population with 1% increase in private health insurance premiums. CHBRP estimates that a 1% increase in private insurance premiums overall will lead to a 0.42 percentage point increase in the number of uninsured (about 10,000 more uninsured individuals) in California in 2016. Alternatively, a 1% increase in the ESI market only will lead to a 0.04 percentage point increase (about 1,000 more uninsured individuals in 2016). And, a 1% increase in the individual market only will lead to a 0.31 percentage point increase (about 8,000 more uninsured individuals in 2016). CHBRP has established a minimum threshold increase of 1.0% in PMPM premiums before it will produce estimates of a proposed mandate s impact on the number of uninsured. This is because of the challenges in accurately estimating the independent effect of premium increases on the number of insured. CHBRP will estimate the impact of the change in premium on the rates of uninsured in California using CalSIM when a proposed mandate has an impact of greater than 1.0% on PMPM ESI and individual insurance premiums overall or for an identifiable subgroup of the insured. CHBRP makes a number of simplifying assumptions when estimating the impact of increased premiums on coverage. CHBRP assumes a similar response to increases in the premium in the individual and small and large ESI market segments. Also, CHBRP assumes the same response to increases in premiums for populations with different incomes. Also, CHBRP assumes the same level of preference for the mandated benefit within a market segment. In other words, CHBRP does not distinguish between individuals who may choose to keep their coverage despite the increased premiums because they value the mandated benefit. CHBRP will estimate the impact of increase in premiums on specific population subgroups when possible, using California Health Interview Survey (CHIS) data. For example, if a mandate applies only to the adults ages 50 to 64 years with heart disease in the ESI market, CHBRP will use CHIS data to assess the size of this population and would use the appropriate elasticity of demand from Table 1 to estimate the number of persons who would drop coverage and the subset who are likely to enroll in public programs. March 16, 2015 www.chbrp.org Page 5 of 8

References Abraham JM, Royalty AB. Does having two earners in the household matter for understanding how well employer-based health insurance works? Medical Care Research and Review. 2005;62:167-186. Auerbach D, Ohri S. Price and the demand for nongroup health insurance. Inquiry. 2006;43:122-134. Baicker K, Chandra A. The Labor Market Effects Of Rising Health Insurance Premiums. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. 2005. Working Paper (W11160). Available at: www.nber.org/papers/w11160. Accessed February 7, 2007. Blumberg L, Nichols A, Liska D. Choosing Employment-Based Health Insurance Arrangements: An Application of the Health Insurance Reform Simulation Model. Washington, D.C.: Urban Institute;1999. California HealthCare Foundation (CHCF). California Employer Health Benefits Survey: Workers Feel the Pinch. January 2014. Available at: www.chcf.org/~/media/media%20library%20files/pdf/e/pdf%20employerhealthb enefits2014.pdf. Accessed February 10, 2015 California Simulation of Insurance Markets (CalSIM). California Simulation of Insurance Markets (CalSIM) Version 1.91: Methodology & Assumptions Update. January 29, 2015. Available at: http://healthpolicy.ucla.edu/publications/documents/pdf/2015/calsim1.91methods.pdf. Accessed February 5, 2015. Chernew M, Frick K, McLaughlin CG. The demand for health insurance coverage by low-income workers: can reduced premiums achieve full coverage? Health Services Research. 1997;32:453-470. Cooper PF, Schone BS. More offers, fewer takers for employment-based health insurance: 1987 and 1996. Health Affairs (Millwood). 1997;16:142-149. Cooper PF, Vistnes J. Workers decisions to take-up offered health insurance coverage: assessing the importance of out-of-pocket premium costs. Medical Care. 2003;41(7 suppl): III35-III43. Covered California. Individuals Enrolled From Oct. 1, 2013, Through March 31, 2014, With Subsidy Status, Across Region. Available at: http://www.coveredca.com/news/pdfs/regional-statsmarch/march_regionalenrollmenttables_forweb_ss.pdf. Accessed February 5, 2015. Cutler D, Madrian B. Labor market responses to rising health insurance cost. Rand Journal of Economics. 1998;29:509-530. Feldman R, Dowd B, Leitz S, Blewett LA. The effect of premiums on the small firm's decision to offer health insurance. Journal of Human Resources. 1997;32:635-658. March 16, 2015 www.chbrp.org Page 6 of 8

Glied S, Jack K. Macroeconomic Conditions, Health Care Costs, and the Distribution of Health Insurance. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. 2003. Working Paper (W10029). Available at: www.nber.org/papers/w10029. Accessed February 7, 2007. Goldman D, Sood N, Leibowitz A. Wages and Benefit Changes in Response to Rising Health Insurance Costs. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. 2005. Working Paper (W11063). Available at: www.nber.org/papers/w11063. Accessed February 7, 2007. Gruber J, Lettau M. How elastic is the firm's demand for health insurance? Journal of Public Economics, 2004; 88:1273 1293. Hadley J. The effects of recent employment changes and premium increases on adults' insurance coverage. Medical Care Research and Review. 2006;63:447-476. Healthcare.gov. The fee you pay if you don t have coverage. Available at: www.healthcare.gov/feesexemptions/fee-for-not-being-covered/. Accessed February 10, 2015 Jensen GA, Gabel JR. State mandated benefits and the small firms' decision to offer insurance. Journal of Regulatory Economics. 1992;4:379-404. Kaiser Family Foundation (KFF). Health Reform FAQs: Tobacco Surcharge for Premiums. Available at: http://kff.org/health-reform/faq/health-reform-frequently-askedquestions/#question-can-i-be-charged-higher-premiums-in-the-marketplace-if-i-smoke. Accessed February 10, 2015. Lewin Group. Cost and coverage analysis of nine proposals to expand health insurance coverage in California: final report prepared for The California Health and Human Services (CHHS) Agency. Appendix A: Uniform Methodology and Assumptions. Arlington, VA: The Lewin Group; 2002. Long SH, Marquis MH. Participation in a public insurance program: subsidies, crowd-out, and adverse selection. Inquiry. 2002;39:243-57. Marquis MS, Buntin MB, Escarce JJ, Kapur K, Yegian JM. Subsidies and the demand for individual health insurance in California. Health Services Research. 2004;39:1547-1570. Marquis MS, Long SH. Worker demand for health insurance in the non-group market. Journal of Health Economics. 1995;14:47-63. Medina J, Saporta C. Covered California s First Year: Strong Enrollment Numbers Mask Serious Gaps. 2014. Available at: http://greenlining.org/wp-content/uploads/2014/06/ihealth- Report-spreads.pdf. Accessed February 3, 2015. Polsky D, Stein R, Nicholson S, Bundorf MK. Employer health insurance offerings and employee enrollment decisions. Health Services Research. 2005;40(Pt 1):1259-1278. March 16, 2015 www.chbrp.org Page 7 of 8

Royalty AB, Hagens J. The effect of premiums on the decision to participate in health insurance and other fringe benefits offered by the employer: evidence from a real-world experiment. Journal of Health Economics. 2005;24:95-112. March 16, 2015 www.chbrp.org Page 8 of 8