Alternate Specifications

Similar documents
Online Appendix Information Asymmetries in Consumer Credit Markets: Evidence from Payday Lending

Online Appendix. income and saving-consumption preferences in the context of dividend and interest income).

Online Appendix A: Verification of Employer Responses

Firm Manipulation and Take-up Rate of a 30 Percent. Temporary Corporate Income Tax Cut in Vietnam

The Persistent Effect of Temporary Affirmative Action: Online Appendix

Bargaining with Grandma: The Impact of the South African Pension on Household Decision Making

Health Status, Health Insurance, and Health Services Utilization: 2001

Problem Set on Earnings Announcements (219B, Spring 2007)

Applied Economics. Quasi-experiments: Instrumental Variables and Regresion Discontinuity. Department of Economics Universidad Carlos III de Madrid

School Attendance, Child Labour and Cash

Full Web Appendix: How Financial Incentives Induce Disability Insurance. Recipients to Return to Work. by Andreas Ravndal Kostøl and Magne Mogstad

Online Appendix for. Explaining Corporate Capital Structure: Product Markets, Leases, and Asset Similarity. Joshua D.

The Impact of a $15 Minimum Wage on Hunger in America

Online Appendix of. This appendix complements the evidence shown in the text. 1. Simulations

Online Appendix (Not For Publication)

THE EFFECT OF HEALTH INSURANCE ON HEALTH CARE SPENDING IN YOUNG ADULTS

Online Appendices for

Empirical Methods for Corporate Finance. Regression Discontinuity Design

Appendix A. Additional Results

Supplementary Appendix

HEALTH COVERAGE AMONG YEAR-OLDS in 2003

The current study builds on previous research to estimate the regional gap in

Online Appendix Long-Lasting Effects of Socialist Education

Regression Discontinuity and. the Price Effects of Stock Market Indexing

The Financial Burden of Medical Spending Among the Non-Elderly, 2010

Heterogeneity in Returns to Wealth and the Measurement of Wealth Inequality 1

Small Area Estimates Produced by the U.S. Federal Government: Methods and Issues

Using Differences in Knowledge Across Neighborhoods to Uncover the Impacts of the EITC on Earnings

The Retirement-Consumption Puzzle and the German Pension System - A Regression Discontinuity Approach

OHIO MEDICAID ASSESSMENT SURVEY 2012

The federal estate tax allows a deduction for every dollar

HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY*

For Online Publication Additional results

Medicaid: A Lower-Cost Approach to Serving a High-Cost Population

Risk Management and Rating Segmentation in Credit Markets

Web Appendix. Inequality and the Measurement of Residential Segregation by Income in American Neighborhoods Tara Watson

Online Appendix for: Consumption Reponses to In-Kind Transfers: Evidence from the Introduction of the Food Stamp Program

Effectiveness of macroprudential and capital flow measures in Asia and the Pacific 1

Anomalies under Jackknife Variance Estimation Incorporating Rao-Shao Adjustment in the Medical Expenditure Panel Survey - Insurance Component 1

Yannan Hu 1, Frank J. van Lenthe 1, Rasmus Hoffmann 1,2, Karen van Hedel 1,3 and Johan P. Mackenbach 1*

Paul Gompers EMCF 2009 March 5, 2009

KEY WORDS: Microsimulation, Validation, Health Care Reform, Expenditures

Population Economics Field Exam Spring This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator.

LECTURE: MEDICAID HILARY HOYNES UC DAVIS EC230 OUTLINE OF LECTURE: 1. Overview of Medicaid. 2. Medicaid expansions

The Runner-up Effect: Online Appendix

Bonus Impacts on Receipt of Unemployment Insurance

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns

The Impact of the Massachusetts Health Care Reform on Health Care Use Among Children

Online Appendix. Moral Hazard in Health Insurance: Do Dynamic Incentives Matter? by Aron-Dine, Einav, Finkelstein, and Cullen


Arkansas Works (formerly Health Care Independence Program Private Option )

How Will the Uninsured Be Affected by Health Reform?

Estimating Average and Local Average Treatment Effects of Education When Compulsory Schooling Laws Really Matter: Corrigendum.

Average Earnings and Long-Term Mortality: Evidence from Administrative Data

While real incomes in the lower and middle portions of the U.S. income distribution have

ASSET ALLOCATION AND ASSET LOCATION DECISIONS: EVIDENCE FROM THE SURVEY OF CONSUMER FINANCES

Transition Events in the Dynamics of Poverty

The effect of Medicaid on Children s Health: a Regression Discontinuity Approach

The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve

Input Tariffs, Speed of Contract Enforcement, and the Productivity of Firms in India

How Much Does Size Erode Mutual Fund Performance? A Regression Discontinuity Approach *

The Effects of State Policy Design Features on Take-up and Crowd-out Rates for the State Children s Health Insurance Program

Wealth Inequality Reading Summary by Danqing Yin, Oct 8, 2018

Additional Evidence and Replication Code for Analyzing the Effects of Minimum Wage Increases Enacted During the Great Recession

Public Employees as Politicians: Evidence from Close Elections

Bakke & Whited [JF 2012] Threshold Events and Identification: A Study of Cash Shortfalls Discussion by Fabian Brunner & Nicolas Boob

Unequal Burden of Retirement Reform: Evidence from Australia

The Effect of Unemployment on Household Composition and Doubling Up

Correcting for Survival Effects in Cross Section Wage Equations Using NBA Data

Trends. o The take-up rate (the A T A. workers. Both the. of workers covered by percent. in Between cent to 56.5 percent.

Private Equity Performance: What Do We Know?

Properties of the estimated five-factor model

Contemporaneous and Long-Term Effects of CHIP Eligibility Expansions on SSI Enrollment

Using Tax Deductions to Promote Lifelong Learning: Real and Shifting Responses

The Effect of New Mortgage-Underwriting Rule on Community (Smaller) Banks Mortgage Activity

Online Appendix to Bundorf, Levin and Mahoney Pricing and Welfare in Health Plan Choice

Aaron Sojourner & Jose Pacas December Abstract:

14.471: Fall 2012: Recitation 3: Labor Supply: Blundell, Duncan and Meghir EMA (1998)

Obesity, Disability, and Movement onto the DI Rolls

Final Exam, section 1. Thursday, May hour, 30 minutes

Policy Brief. protection?} Do the insured have adequate. The Impact of Health Reform on Underinsurance in Massachusetts:

Fiscal Incidence Analysis. B. Essama-Nssah World Bank Poverty Reduction Group Washinton D.C. June 03, 2008

May 9, Please put ONLY your ID number on the blue books. Three (3) points will be deducted for each time your name appears in a blue book.

Cash-on-hand in Developing Countries and the Value of Social Insurance: Evidence from Brazil

Import Competition and Household Debt

HOW WILL UNINSURED CHILDREN BE AFFECTED BY HEALTH REFORM?

Problem Set 5 Answers. ( ) 2. Yes, like temperature. See the plot of utility in the notes. Marginal utility should be positive.

Childhood Medicaid Coverage and Later Life Health Care Utilization * Laura R. Wherry, Sarah Miller, Robert Kaestner, Bruce D. Meyer.

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix

Does Investing in School Capital Infrastructure Improve Student Achievement?

Online Robustness Appendix to Are Household Surveys Like Tax Forms: Evidence from the Self Employed

Acemoglu, et al (2008) cast doubt on the robustness of the cross-country empirical relationship between income and democracy. They demonstrate that

Observations from the Interagency Technical Working Group on Developing a Supplemental Poverty Measure

Web Appendix for: Medicare Part D: Are Insurers Gaming the Low Income Subsidy Design? Francesco Decarolis (Boston University)

How Much Does Size Erode Mutual Fund Performance? A Regression Discontinuity Approach *

Volume 29, Issue 2. A note on finance, inflation, and economic growth

Indian Households Finance: An analysis of Stocks vs. Flows- Extended Abstract

Adjusting Poverty Thresholds When Area Prices Differ: Labor Market Evidence

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MEDICAID CROWD-OUT OF PRIVATE LONG-TERM CARE INSURANCE DEMAND: EVIDENCE FROM THE HEALTH AND RETIREMENT SURVEY

The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits

Transcription:

A Alternate Specifications As described in the text, roughly twenty percent of the sample was dropped because of a discrepancy between eligibility as determined by the AHRQ, and eligibility according to the thresholds collected from the TRIM3 database and Kaiser Family Foundation reports. We will document here that this makes no material difference to the analysis above, and in some cases, makes it stronger. The first concern about dropping these observations is that they might invalidate the RD design. If these dropped observations are disproportionately from either one side of the other of the discontinuity, and the discrepancy between the eligibility rules is tied to outcomes of interest, then the estimates could be an artifact of the data management. As is evident in Figures 8(a) and 8(b), this first condition does not hold. These figures plot the weights of the observations by distance from the imputed eligibility threshold. The first graph includes the observations with inconsistent measures of eligibility, while the second excludes them. Both graphs demonstrate a smooth distribution through the discontinuity, mitigating concerns about the validity of the RD. This is the same conclusion of the estimation and graphing suggested by McCrary (2008) used in the text. I also repeat the RD estimates of Equation (2) including the observations with inconsistent measure of eligibility. These point estimates can be found in Table 4, which also reports the point estimates for the preferred (baseline) specifications in Table 2. In the interest of brevity, I only report the point estimates for the regressions with a fifth-order polynomial in family income and distance from the eligibility threshold. In nearly all cases, the point estimates from the preferred specification are smaller in magnitude. This may reflect the 38

misspecification of the running variable. When the running variable is more noisily measured, the estimated control function G may be attenuated. This would leave more of the level differences in outcome between the eligible and ineligible due to differences in the running variable (e.g., the normality of demand for health care) to be assigned to the RD estimate. B Robustness Exercises A Higher-order Polynomial Fits and Clustering The regression coefficients presented above relied on first-order polynomials in the running variable. Table 5 reports the point estimates and the standard errors for key outcome variables using third- and fifth-order polynomials, as well as the preferred specification (first-order) and no controls for the running variable. All specifications include demographic controls. The general patterns hold. The insurance specifications provide further consistent evidence of parental crowd-out at the margin, with only a statistically-significant fraction of uptake of public insurance. The various polynomial specifications support the mixed results on spending by source and use, and the possible conseqeunces for preventive care. The t-statistics presented in the main tables of the paper accounted for the sampling methods used in collecting the MEPS household data. These were calculated using svy prefix commands in Stata. The data in the MEPS are also collected over a short, two-year panel, and I do not account for the potential dependence of errors within an individual over time. The svy prefix in Stata is not compatible with clustering beyond the survey s design. For the preferred specifications, I chose to focus on the inference using the survey design. Each 39

individual is only observed twice, and the variation exploited here is cross-sectional. Not accounting for the survey design inflates the t-statistics by at least a factor of 10. Given the geographic patterns reguarly observed in health-care data, this should not be surprising. Clustering by individual in lieu of accounting for the survey design is likewise problematic: the survey design induces correlation between individuals, and clustering by individual ignores that. To simulate clustering by individual, while still accounting for the survey design, I drop the second observation of an individual in the data, and re-run the regression specifications. The point-estimates and t-statistics, presented in Table 5 are similar, though the latter are typically smaller to their full-sample counterpart. The sample falls by a little less than half, as the AHRQ did not calculate eligibility measurements for one of the panel-years, and the panel sizes vary, as well. B Measurement Error of Eligibility As described in the text, roughly twenty percent of the sample was dropped because of a discrepancy between eligibility as determined by the AHRQ, and eligibility according to the thresholds collected from the TRIM3 database and Kaiser Family Foundation reports. We will document here that this makes no material difference to the analysis above, and in some cases, makes it stronger. The first concern about dropping these observations is that they might invalidate the RD design. If these dropped observations are disproportionately from either one side of the other of the discontinuity, and the discrepancy between the eligibility rules is tied to outcomes 40

of interest, then the estimates could be an artifact of the data management. As is evident in Figures 8(a) and 8(b), this first condition does not hold. These figures plot the weights of the observations by distance from the imputed eligibility threshold. The first graph includes the observations with inconsistent measures of eligibility, while the second excludes them. Both graphs demonstrate a smooth distribution through the discontinuity, mitigating concerns about the validity of the RD. This is the same conclusion of the estimation and graphing suggested by McCrary (2008) used in the text. I also repeat the RD estimates of Equation (2) including the observations with inconsistent measure of eligibility. These point estimates can be found in Table 4, which also reports the point estimates for the preferred (baseline) specifications in Table 2. In the interest of brevity, I only report the point estimates for the regressions with a fifth-order polynomial in family income and distance from the eligibility threshold. In nearly all cases, the point estimates from the preferred specification are smaller in magnitude. This may reflect the misspecification of the running variable. When the running variable is more noisily measured, the estimated control function G may be attenuated. This would leave more of the level differences in outcome between the eligible and ineligible due to differences in the running variable (e.g., the normality of demand for health care) to be assigned to the RD estimate. C Predetermined characteristics and Eligibility Beyond the bin size calculations already presented, I am able to provide further tests of eligibility manipulation. If there is precise manipulation of the forcing variable, and the forcing variable is correlated with a pre-determined characteristic, such as race, then there 41

will be a discontinuity in the racial composition of the bins near the eligibility threshold. The relationship between the forcing variable and the fraction of the bin that is African-American can be found in Figure 9. The fraction black is decreasing at an even rate as the forcing variable increases. The fitted estimate on the left-hand side of the threshold is less than that on the right-hand side. This would be consistent with manipulation of the forcing variable, though the fitted value at the threshold from either side is within the range of the bin averages on the other side of the threshold. The point estimates tend to be robust when controls for demographic information are included in main specifications above. Similarly, I construct two measures of expected out-of-pocket spending for a child if uninsured, as a function of age, race, state of residence and year of observation. I include age in months in a third-order polynomial; the other child information is indicated with dummy variables. Observed out-of-pocket spending is correlated with insurance status, which itself may be correlated with demographic measures. To the extent that those demographic measures are correlated with eligibility, expectations based upon those demographics may be biased. Thus, I attempt to mitigate the bias in two ways, both similar to the methods employed by Fang et al. (2008). First, I include an indicator variable for whether the child has any health insurance. When constructing the fitted variables, I set the insurance indicator to zero for all observations, to measure the expected out-of-pocket spending if uninsured. Alternatively, I regress out-of-pocket spending on the demographic variables only for children without insurance, and construct fitted values of that regression for the entire sample. Both methods attempt to resolve the same underlying problem in different ways; neither provides evidence of manipulation. The bin averages for these expected value, and the local linear fit, can also be seen in Figure 9. The local linear fits of each method predict 42

a discontinuity at the eligibility threshold of a different sign, and both are well within the usual ranges for bin averages on either side of the eligibility threshold. This is, again, consistent with the bin size calculations provided above. D Selection on Observables The identification strategy employed here can also be interpreted as selection on observables. The natural way to implement such an estimator is to include controls for the factors determining the child s eligibility family income as a fraction of Federal poverty guideline and state-year-child s age dummies. The support condition for the selection on observables estimation is related to the smoothness assumptions for the RD estimator. The distance controls are not required, because the state-year-child s age dummies control for the year-state-age variation in eligibility threshold. Table 4 presents the selection on observables estimates. There are 51 states 10 years 19 age groups = 9, 690 state-year-age dummies. This full model was not estimated, due to its computational burden. However, the point estimates for two alternate specifications are presented. The second includes child age (in years), state, and year fixed effects, but not their interactions. The second includes the state and year interactions. Both specifications yield point estimates that are larger than the preferred specification. This may not be surprising, as many states vastly increased the eligibility thresholds for public health insurance. Less stringent controls in the selection on observables can shed light on the validity of other identification techniques common in this literature. Researchers typically exploit across-state over-time variation in eligibility changes to estimate difference-in-difference to 43

identify the causal impact of eligibility. Modifications to the selection on observables test the validity of this strategy. For example, simulated eligibility estimates typically include year- and state-fixed effects, but not their interaction, as the state-year interactions are providing the source of the policy variation. If this variation is correlated with eligibility and health care outcomes, then excluding the state-year interactions will vary the point estimate of the eligibility indicator. A related test would exclude the state-year-age interactions, controlling only for age and state-year interactions. This would test the validity of exploiting within-state, across age group variations in policy. Both appear to overstate the impact of public health insurance eligibility. 44

locavg 800000 1000000 1200000 1400000 1600000.5 0.5 (a) All observations ec_tot 400000 600000 800000 1000000 1200000.5 0.5 (b) Consistent eligibility measures Figure 8: APPENDIX: Public health insurance eligibility and bin size (using weights). The first graph provides the number of observations in each bin for all observations, while the second graph does the same for only observations with a consistent measure of eligibility. 45

240 260 280 300 320 260 280 300 320 340 360 Local linear smoother Local linear smoother (a) Expected out-of-pocket spending, method 1 (b) Expected out-of-pocket spending, method 2 0.1.2.3.4 Local linear smoother (c) Fraction African American Figure 9: APPENDIX: Public health insurance eligibility for a child and the child s pre-determined characteristics. The bin average in the first graph expected out-of-pocket spending graph rely on a regression of out-of-pocket spending on demographics and an indicator variable for having any insurance. The second estimates the regression of out-of-pocket spending on demographics on the uninsured only, and then calculates the predicted values for the entire population. 46

.2.4.6.8 1.4.5.6.7.8.9 Five percent undersmoothed Five percent oversmoothed Ten percent undersmoothed Exactly smoothed Ten percent oversmoothed Five percent undersmoothed Five percent oversmoothed Ten percent undersmoothed Exactly smoothed Ten percent oversmoothed (a) Private insurance (b) Any insurance.4.5.6.7.8.4.5.6.7.8 Five percent undersmoothed Five percent oversmoothed Ten percent undersmoothed Exactly smoothed Ten percent oversmoothed Five percent undersmoothed Five percent oversmoothed Ten percent undersmoothed Exactly smoothed Ten percent oversmoothed (c) Pap smears (d) Breast exam Figure 10: APPENDIX: Public health insurance eligibility for a child and health insurance and health care outcome for the adult; with multiple adjustments to bandwith. 47

Polynomial order 0 1 3 5 First observation Insurance, by source or use Private -0.368*** -0.15*** -0.124*** -0.115*** -0.158*** (-43.07) (-8.42) (-4.64) (-3.81) (-10.37) Any -0.215*** -0.124*** -0.105*** -0.085*** -0.135*** (-28.16) (-7.59) (-4.19) (-2.94) (-9.04) Public 0.173*** 0.042*** 0.028*** 0.034** 0.036*** (21.75) (3.46) (2.11) (2.23) (3.51) Spending, by source or use Total -422.06* -292.73* -151.90-181.44-325.10*** (-1.75) (-1.91) (-1.07) (-1.12) (-2.09) Office-based -84.30*** -64.33** -83.72** -56.18-59.53* (-4.89) (-2.32) (-2.33) (-1.56) (-1.78) Out-of-pocket -42.78*** -41.22* -52.60* -39.63-49.21* (-3.92) (-1.92) (-1.89) (-1.11) (-1.70) Preventive care Flu shot -0.036-0.011-0.003 0.001-0.004 (-4.96) (-0.72) (-0.14) ( 0.03) (-0.24) BP check -0.074*** -0.046*** -0.029-0.016-0.029 (-7.62) (-2.96) (-1.33) (-0.58) (-1.46) Cholesterol check -0.079*** -0.043*** -0.006 0.027-0.018 (-8.51) (-2.51) (-0.26) ( 0.88) (-0.84) Pap smear -0.111*** -0.078*** -0.062** -0.053-0.08*** (-8.75) (-3.64) (-2.01) (-1.43) (-2.76) Breast exam -0.122*** -0.093*** -0.069** -0.072** -0.086*** (-9.93) (-4.33) (-2.35) (-2.04) (-3.29) Mammogram -0.075*** -0.057** -0.032-0.014-0.057* (-5.22) (-2.19) (-0.88) (-0.35) (-1.67) Annual exam -0.085*** -0.060*** -0.04*2 0.001-0.050** (-8.59) (-3.40) (-1.86) ( 0.02) (-2.19) Self-reported health Excellent or -0.136*** -0.078*** -0.064*** -0.087*** -0.058*** very good ( -14.57) (-5.46) (-3.09) (-3.33) (-3.07) Table 4: APPENDIX: The effects (and t-statistics) of a child s public health insurance eligibility on adult insurance outcomes, for alternate specifications, using linear probability models. The first four columns vary the order of the polynomial of the forcing variable. The final column reports the coefficients and t-statistics for the first observations of each adult. All specifications include demographic, state and year fixed effects. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1% 48

All observations Baseline Selection on Observables Elig. Effect N Elig. Effect N Elig. Effect N Elig. Effect N Insurance, by source or use Private -0.208*** 50,121-0.114*** 37,029-0.223*** 50,123-0.219*** 50,122 ( -23.93) (-3.80) ( -26.24) ( -25.81) Any -0.112*** 50,121-0.085*** 37,029-0.123*** 50,123-0.119*** 50,122 ( -15.25) (-2.93) ( -16.06) ( -16.11) Public 0.103*** 50,121 0.034** 37,029 0.116*** 50,123 0.114*** 50,122 (-14.54) (2.23) (15.49) (15.47) Spending, by source or use Total -240.73** 50,121-181.37 37,029 (-2.18) (-1.12) Office-based -56.18*** 50,121-56.71 37,029 (-3.30) (-1.57) Out of pocket -60.15*** 50,121-39.34 37,029 (-6.56) (-1.10) Preventive care Flu shot -0.019*** 34,036 0.001 25,714-0.017** 34,037-0.017** 34,039 (-3.03) (0.03) (-2.68) (-2.62) BP check -0.052*** 33,660-0.016 25,406-0.054*** 33,661-0.05*** 33,663 (-6.22) (-0.58) (-6.49) (-5.97) Cholesterol check -0.06*** 32,545 0.027 24,596-0.063*** 32,546-0.055*** 32,548 (-6.72) (0.87) (-6.91) (-6.07) Pap smear -0.087*** 18,654-0.053 14,215-0.097*** 18,653-0.098*** 18,653 (-7.69) (-1.41) (-8.59) (-8.70) Breast exam -0.09*** 18,651-0.071** 14,223-0.096*** 18,650-0.095*** 18,650 (-7.88) (-2.02) (-8.65) (-8.47) Mammogram -0.065*** 12,288-0.013 9,275-0.046*** 12,290-0.047*** 12,289 (-4.75) (-0.31) (-3.06) (-3.08) Annual exam -0.069*** 33,683 0.001 25,457-0.065*** 33,684-0.063*** 33,686 (-7.87) (0.02) (-7.63) (-7.29) Self-reported health Excellent or -0.112*** 50,121-0.087*** 37,024-0.115*** 50,123-0.117*** 50,122 Very good ( -13.58) (-3.33) ( -13.98) ( -14.58) Age FE x x x x State, year FE x x x x State x year FE x Table 5: APPENDIX: The effects (and t-statistics) of a child s public health insurance eligibility on adult insurance outcomes, for alternate specifications, using linear probability models. The first two columns of point estimates are for the entire sample, including observations with inconsistently measured eligibility, and the preferred sample, excluding such observations. The second pair of columns reports the coefficients and t-statistics for the selection on observables specifications, with varying controls. Sample size for each alternate specification is reported. The estimates are based on a regression with a fifth-order polynomial in family wage income as a fraction of the poverty guideline and, for the first two columns, distance to the eligibility threshold (denominated the same), along with demographic, state and year effects. The final column includes year-state fixed effects. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** 49 significant at 1%