The Asset Pricing Model of Exchange Rate and its Test on Survey Data

Similar documents
Multi-Path General-to-Specific Modelling with OxMetrics

Journal of Economics and Financial Analysis, Vol:1, No:1 (2017) 1-13

Blame the Discount Factor No Matter What the Fundamentals Are

Predictability in finance

Optimal Window Selection for Forecasting in The Presence of Recent Structural Breaks

A Note on Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios

Chapter 6 Forecasting Volatility using Stochastic Volatility Model

A Comparative Study of Various Forecasting Techniques in Predicting. BSE S&P Sensex

A Non-Random Walk Down Wall Street

Combining State-Dependent Forecasts of Equity Risk Premium

Market Risk Prediction under Long Memory: When VaR is Higher than Expected

Modelling of Long-Term Risk

EKONOMIHÖGSKOLAN Lunds Universitet. The model confidence set choosing between models

Amath 546/Econ 589 Univariate GARCH Models

Forecasting Stock Index Futures Price Volatility: Linear vs. Nonlinear Models

Online Appendix to Grouped Coefficients to Reduce Bias in Heterogeneous Dynamic Panel Models with Small T

Modelling financial data with stochastic processes

Commodity Prices, Commodity Currencies, and Global Economic Developments

Chapter IV. Forecasting Daily and Weekly Stock Returns

Modelling Returns: the CER and the CAPM

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2010, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay Solutions to Final Exam

Indian Institute of Management Calcutta. Working Paper Series. WPS No. 797 March Implied Volatility and Predictability of GARCH Models

The Economics of Exchange Rates. Lucio Sarno and Mark P. Taylor with a foreword by Jeffrey A. Frankel

Modeling and Predictability of Exchange Rate Changes by the Extended Relative Nelson Siegel Class of Models

On modelling of electricity spot price

Testing for the martingale hypothesis in Asian stock prices: a wild bootstrap approach

Asymptotic Theory for Renewal Based High-Frequency Volatility Estimation

List of tables List of boxes List of screenshots Preface to the third edition Acknowledgements

Experience with the Weighted Bootstrap in Testing for Unobserved Heterogeneity in Exponential and Weibull Duration Models

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

The Economic and Social BOOTSTRAPPING Review, Vol. 31, No. THE 4, R/S October, STATISTIC 2000, pp

Forecasting Volatility of USD/MUR Exchange Rate using a GARCH (1,1) model with GED and Student s-t errors

Monte Carlo Simulations in the Teaching Process

Analyzing Oil Futures with a Dynamic Nelson-Siegel Model

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2009, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions

Modeling Federal Funds Rates: A Comparison of Four Methodologies

Estimating Demand Uncertainty Over Multi-Period Lead Times

State Switching in US Equity Index Returns based on SETAR Model with Kalman Filter Tracking

LONG MEMORY, VOLATILITY, RISK AND DISTRIBUTION

Unexpected volatility and intraday serial correlation

Multistage risk-averse asset allocation with transaction costs

Assicurazioni Generali: An Option Pricing Case with NAGARCH

Oesterreichische Nationalbank. Eurosystem. Workshops. Proceedings of OeNB Workshops. Macroeconomic Models and Forecasts for Austria

Exchange Rate Forecasting under Model Uncertainty

Forecasting Gasoline Prices Using Consumer Surveys

Monetary policy under uncertainty

ARCH and GARCH Models vs. Martingale Volatility of Finance Market Returns

Machine Learning for Multi-step Ahead Forecasting of Volatility Proxies

Exploring Financial Instability Through Agent-based Modeling Part 2: Time Series, Adaptation, and Survival

Course information FN3142 Quantitative finance

Forecasting Exchange Rates using an Optimal Portfolio Model with Time Varying Weights.

Omitted Variables Bias in Regime-Switching Models with Slope-Constrained Estimators: Evidence from Monte Carlo Simulations

Do core inflation measures help forecast inflation? Out-of-sample evidence from French data

Backtesting Trading Book Models

Portfolio Performance Measurement

Price manipulation in models of the order book

Evaluating Combined Forecasts for Realized Volatility Using Asymmetric Loss Functions

Forecasting Singapore economic growth with mixed-frequency data

Enlargement of filtration

Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis. () Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis 1 / 29

Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background

On accuracy of survey forecasts of US mortgage spread

EXAMINING THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN CORPORATE SOCIAL RESPONSIBILITY AND STOCK PRICE CRASH RISK OF COMPANIES LISTED IN TEHRAN STOCK EXCHANGE

Applied Econometrics and International Development. AEID.Vol. 5-3 (2005)

University of Pretoria Department of Economics Working Paper Series

GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application

Risk-Adjusted Futures and Intermeeting Moves

Lecture 5. Predictability. Traditional Views of Market Efficiency ( )

Sectoral Analysis of the Demand for Real Money Balances in Pakistan

Online Appendix for. Short-Run and Long-Run Consumption Risks, Dividend Processes, and Asset Returns

PERUVIAN ECONOMIC ASSOCIATION. Modelling and forecasting money demand: divide and conquer

High-Frequency Data Analysis and Market Microstructure [Tsay (2005), chapter 5]

Interest Rate Curves Calibration with Monte-Carlo Simulatio

Small Area Estimation of Poverty Indicators using Interval Censored Income Data

Modeling Credit Risk of Loan Portfolios in the Presence of Autocorrelation (Part 2)

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function?

Box-Cox Transforms for Realized Volatility

High Frequency Autocorrelation in the Returns of the SPY and the QQQ. Scott Davis* January 21, Abstract

Running head: IMPROVING REVENUE VOLATILITY ESTIMATES 1. Improving Revenue Volatility Estimates Using Time-Series Decomposition Methods

Forecasting Stock Return Volatility in the Presence of Structural Breaks

Exchange rate forecasting with Excel

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS YALE UNIVERSITY P.O. Box New Haven, CT

WORKING PAPER SERIES INFLATION FORECASTS, MONETARY POLICY AND UNEMPLOYMENT DYNAMICS EVIDENCE FROM THE US AND THE EURO AREA NO 725 / FEBRUARY 2007

The Random Walk Hypothesis in Emerging Stock Market-Evidence from Nonlinear Fourier Unit Root Test

Fast Convergence of Regress-later Series Estimators

Monetary Policy under Behavioral Expectations: Theory and Experiment

Does Commodity Price Index predict Canadian Inflation?

ARCH and GARCH models

A Simple Recursive Forecasting Model

Bloomberg. Portfolio Value-at-Risk. Sridhar Gollamudi & Bryan Weber. September 22, Version 1.0

Experience with the Weighted Bootstrap in Testing for Unobserved Heterogeneity in Exponential and Weibull Duration Models

Predictability/Trading strategies

Introductory Econometrics for Finance

Financial Econometrics Jeffrey R. Russell. Midterm 2014 Suggested Solutions. TA: B. B. Deng

Risky asset valuation and the efficient market hypothesis

EMPIRICAL DISTRIBUTIONS OF STOCK RETURNS: SCANDINAVIAN SECURITIES MARKETS, Felipe Aparicio and Javier Estrada * **

Choice Probabilities. Logit Choice Probabilities Derivation. Choice Probabilities. Basic Econometrics in Transportation.

Applied Macro Finance

Transcription:

Discussion of Anna Naszodi s paper: The Asset Pricing Model of Exchange Rate and its Test on Survey Data Discussant: Genaro Sucarrat Department of Economics Universidad Carlos III de Madrid http://www.eco.uc3m.es/sucarrat/index.html Warsawa, 4 November 2009

Objective of paper: To test the asset price model of exchange rates using survey data Essence of asset price approach: The price of a currency (the exchange rate) is a function of its expected change Test strategy used: Compare the asset price (AP) model with the random walk ( no change ) and with a linear model of the forecast horison ( trend model ) in two ways: 1. Section 3.2: Which model fits best to 3 months ahead survey forecast data? (AP and trend models are estimated using 12 and 24 months ahead forecasts) 2. Section 3.3: Which model predicts exchange rates best 3, 12 and 24 months ahead? (AP and trend models are estimated recursively)

Outline: Main comment 1: On section 3.2 (Which model fits the survey data best?) Main comment 2: On section 3.3 (Which model forecasts exchange rates best?) Main comment 3: An alternative approach to testing the asset pricing model Other comments Minor comments

Main comment 1: In terms of MAEs and RMSEs, table 1 suggests the AP forecasts are always closer to the 3 months ahead survey forecasts But is this also the case for the 12 and 24 months ahead forecasts? For example, does the random walk fit better at 12 and/or 24 horisons than the AP? It seems to me that it is straightforward to implement comparisons also at the 12 and 24 months horisons According to the tests in table 1 the AP model is significantly closer to the survey data than the random walk. But is the test framework appropriate? g t = gt A gt B is the difference in loss at t between model A and B, where g ( ) t is equal to ( x t,t+.25 ˆx ( ) t,t+.25 )2 in the RMSE case

Main comment 1 (cont.): H 0 : E(g t ) = 0 (equal fit) H 1 : E(g t ) 0 (the fit of A and B differ) Test statistic: t g t t (g t g) 2 t(1) where g is the sample average of {g t } Where does the test come from? What is its motivation? Why distributed (asymptotically?) as t(1) rather than, say, N(0, 1)?

Main comment 1 (cont.): At some point in section 3.2 the work of Clark and West (2006): Using out-of-sample mean squared prediction errors to test the martingale difference hypothesis, is cited, but the assumptions of their test are not satisfied. Alternatively, their test could maybe (at least approximately?) be valid if: g A t = ( x t,t+.25 ˆx A t,t+.25 )2, etc. { x t,t+.25 } is a zero-mean martingale difference sequence (stationarity, no trend) Loss function is squared error (Clark and West s test is not formulated in terms of absolute errors)

Main comment 1 (cont.): Since the forecasts are of the level s t of the exchange rate (rather than of the difference s t ), it seems likely that the {g t } are strongly autocorrelated The finite sample properties of the test statistic might be very poor. Simulate! From section 3.2 one gets the impression that the test of equal fit is two-sided. But since the objective is to test whether AP fits better, would it not be more appropriate to do a one-sided test? That is, H 1 : E(gt A gt B ) > 0, where A is the random walk (say) and B is the AP

Main comment 2: Where does the test statistic come from? What is its motivation? Why t(1) instead of N(0, 1)? At some point West (2006): Forecast Evaluation is cited, but this is a survey in a handbook so it is not clear which of the tests one has in mind Tables 2-7: The t-tests, which I interpret to mean test-statistics (asymptotically) distributed as t(1), are all in the interval (-5,5), and some of them (identified with an * ) are significant at 10%. But the associated critical values α 0.05 and α 0.95 for a t(1) variable are ±6.31. Error? Typo? Lack of clarity in exposition?

Main comment 2 (cont.): Interpretation of tables 2 to 7 on p. 13: The remarkable result is that the asset pricing model can beat the random walk for some pairs of exchange rates and forecast horizons. By contrast, I do not think tables 2 to 7 suggest the AP is significantly better than the random walk: 1. Out of 72 tests (66 tests if we exclude the aggregate tests), only 3 times does AP generate forecasts that are significantly better than the random walk at 5% or lower 2. By contrast, out of 72 tests the random walk is significantly better than AP 14 times at 5% or lower 3. Out of 72 tests the linear model is significantly better than the random walk 11 times at 5% or lower

Main comment 2 (cont.): 4. Out of 72 tests the survey forecasts perform significantly better than the random walk only once With these results in mind, I am surprised by the conclusion that, when AP beats the random walk, it is due to its better fit with survey-data. It is true that the survey data beat the random walk in the three instances where the AP model significantly outperforms the random walk. But so does the linear model. Is beating the random walk simply due to the random walk occasionally doing bad?

Main comment 3: Alternative framework? Axiom of empirical econometrics: s t+1 = E t ( s t+1 ) }{{} Explanation + ɛ }{{} t+1 Explanation error AP: E t ( s t+1 ) = 1 c (s t v t ) General model that nests the AP, the random walk, the linear model and other models/hypotheses: an error-correction model s t+1 = β 0 + β 1 s t + β 2 x t+1 + β 3 [s t v t ( x t,...)] + ɛ t+1, ɛ t+1 = σ t+1 z t+1, z t+1 IID(0, 1), σ 2 t+1 = h(arch, option prices,... )

Other comments: What is the source and nature of the exchange rate data series {S t }? Exchange rate data are often period averages, while professional forecasters typically give point forecast There might be an incompatibility issue between your exchange rate data series and the Consensus Economics data

Other comments (cont.): Linear model: E(s T It LM ) = s t + (T t)µ The forecasts of the linear model are ˆx t+.25y = s t +.25Y ˆµ (p. 9) But what is the value of ˆµ? Is it so close to zero that the linear model s forecasts for (most?) practical purposes equal the forecasts of the random walk? Related: We have that (T t) =.25Y. But what is the value of.25y? 0.25? As it is written,.25y could be interpreted as 0.25 year, say, 0.25 1999, etc., or 0.25 1, etc. Now, this would induce an exponentially increasing or decreasing trend in the forecasts

Minor comments: Continuous vs. discrete time 1. Footnote 5 on p. 5: Irregular data-sampling is cited as a motivation for the continuous time representation in section 2. But it is not clear from the description of the data that irregular sampling necessitates a continuous time formulation. Is this because the data are not explained well enough? Continuous vs. discrete time 2. Appendix A on p. 16: We demonstrate that the two models [the continuous time and discrete time] versions are identical. This is incorrect from a reduction theory point of view, see Sucarrat (2009b, 2009a, section 4.5). A discrete time model can be compatible (derivable) from more than one continuous time structure. So the assumption that the continuous and discrete time versions are identical is a (potentially) very restrictive assumption on the discrete time model

Minor comments (cont.): The title of subsection 3.2 is not very indicative of its content, I think. Suggestion: Change to, say, Which model fits the survey data best? Section 3.3: At which point t is the recursive estimation initiated? Footnote 7 on p. 7: The reference Bartolini and Giorgianni (2001) is missing from the bibliography list

Minor comments (cont.): P. 7: Most of the empirical studies in the exchange rate literature avoid to use survey data. Here are some references that might be of interest (some of these make use of data from Consensus Economics): R. MacDonald and I. Marsh (1999): Exchange Rate Modelling, Kluwer Academic Publishers R. MacDonald and I. Marsh (1997): On Fundamentals and Exchange Rates: A Casselian Perspective, Review of Economics and Statistics, 79 P. Hallwood, R. MacDonald and I. Marsh (1997): Crash! Expectational Aspects of the Departures of the United Kingdom and the United States From the Inter-war Gold Standard, Explorations in Economic History, 34 R. MacDonald and I. Marsh (1996): Foreign Exchange Forecasters are Heterogeneous: Confirmation and Consequences, Journal of International Money and Finance, 15 I. Marsh and D. Power (1996): A Note on the Performance of Exchange Rate Forecasters in a Portfolio Framework, Journal of Banking and Finance 20 R. MacDonald and I. Marsh (1996): Forecaster Heterogeneity: An Investigation of the Expectations of Foreign Exchange Forecasters, Economie et Prévision 125 R. MacDonald and I. Marsh (1994): Combining Exchange Rate Forecasts: What is the Optimal Consensus Measure?, Journal of Forecasting 13. Reprinted in Financial Forecasting Volume II: Interest Rates, Exchange Rates and Volatility, Eds R. Batchelor and P. Dua, Edward Elgar, 2003.

References: Clark, T. E. and K. D. West (2006). Using out-of-sample mean squared prediction errors to test the martingale difference hypothesis. Journal of Econometrics 135, 155 186. Sucarrat, G. (2009a). Econometric Reduction Theory and Philosophy. Forthcoming in the Journal of Economic Methodology. Working paper version: UC3M Working Paper 09-10 in the Economic Series. Available via http://hdl.handle.net/10016/3773. Sucarrat, G. (2009b). Forecast Evaluation of Explanatory Models of Financial Variability. Economics The Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal 3. Available via: http://www.economics-ejournal.org/economics/journalarticles/2009-8. West, K. D. (2006). Forecast evaluation. In G. Elliott, C. W. Granger, and A. Timmermann (Eds.), Handbook of Economic Forecasting, Volume 1. Amsterdam: Elsevier.