Micro-foundations: Consumption. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Similar documents
Lecture 10: Two-Period Model

INTERMEDIATE MACROECONOMICS

Chapter 16 Consumption. 8 th and 9 th editions 4/29/2017. This chapter presents: Keynes s Conjectures

MACROECONOMICS II - CONSUMPTION

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018

Micro foundations, part 1. Modern theories of consumption

11/6/2013. Chapter 17: Consumption. Early empirical successes: Results from early studies. Keynes s conjectures. The Keynesian consumption function

The ratio of consumption to income, called the average propensity to consume, falls as income rises

Consumption-Savings Decisions and Credit Markets

Remember the dynamic equation for capital stock _K = F (K; T L) C K C = _ K + K = I

ECON385: A note on the Permanent Income Hypothesis (PIH). In this note, we will try to understand the permanent income hypothesis (PIH).

ECON 314: MACROECONOMICS II CONSUMPTION

EC 324: Macroeconomics (Advanced)

Macroeconomics. Lecture 5: Consumption. Hernán D. Seoane. Spring, 2016 MEDEG, UC3M UC3M

consumption = 2/3 GDP in US uctuations the aect booms and recessions 4.2 John Maynard Keynes - Consumption function

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Spring University of Notre Dame

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Fall University of Notre Dame

INDIVIDUAL CONSUMPTION and SAVINGS DECISIONS

Consumption, Saving, and Investment. Chapter 4. Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada

Topic 2: Consumption

A Real Intertemporal Model with Investment Copyright 2014 Pearson Education, Inc.

1. Suppose that instead of a lump sum tax the government introduced a proportional income tax such that:

Chapter 4. Consumption and Saving. Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada

Advanced Macroeconomics 6. Rational Expectations and Consumption

Problems. units of good b. Consumers consume a. The new budget line is depicted in the figure below. The economy continues to produce at point ( a1, b

Road Map. Does consumption theory accurately match the data? What theories of consumption seem to match the data?

Lecture 2 General Equilibrium Models: Finite Period Economies

ECNS 303 Ch. 16: Consumption

Questions for Review. CHAPTER 16 Understanding Consumer Behavior

Questions for Review. CHAPTER 17 Consumption

Lecture 12 Ricardian Equivalence Dynamic General Equilibrium. Noah Williams

IN THIS LECTURE, YOU WILL LEARN:

Macroeconomics II Consumption

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy

Credit Market Imperfections, Credit Frictions and Financial Crises. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Macroeconomics: Fluctuations and Growth

Problems. 1. Given information: (a) To calculate wealth, we compute:

Lecture 14 Consumption under Uncertainty Ricardian Equivalence & Social Security Dynamic General Equilibrium. Noah Williams

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

Rational Expectations and Consumption

Department of Economics Shanghai University of Finance and Economics Intermediate Macroeconomics

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

Intermediate Macroeconomics

Set 3. Intertemporal approach to the balance of payments

Appendix 4.A. A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved

ECON 314: MACROECONOMICS II CONSUMPTION AND CONSUMER EXPENDITURE

Consumption and Savings

1 Multiple Choice (30 points)

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy

FINANCE THEORY: Intertemporal. and Optimal Firm Investment Decisions. Eric Zivot Econ 422 Summer R.W.Parks/E. Zivot ECON 422:Fisher 1.

Problems. the net marginal product of capital, MP'

Intermediate Macroeconomics

ECONOMICS 2. Sponsored by a Grant TÁMOP /2/A/KMR Course Material Developed by Department of Economics,

Problem set 2. Filip Rozsypal November 23, 2011

Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work-Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization

Macroeconomics I Chapter 3. Consumption

ECON 314:MACROECONOMICS 2 CONSUMPTION AND CONSUMER EXPENDITURE

Macroeconomics, Cdn. 4e (Williamson) Chapter 1 Introduction

Problem set 1 ECON 4330

Macroeconomics: Policy, 31E23000

Intro to Economic analysis

Chapter 4. Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work-Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

MODULE 11. Small Open Economy Equilibrium IV: Fiscal Policy

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

ECON Micro Foundations

14.02 Principles of Macroeconomics Solutions to Problem Set # 2

Consumption and Savings (Continued)

14.05: SECTION HANDOUT #4 CONSUMPTION (AND SAVINGS) Fall 2005

ECON 3020 Intermediate Macroeconomics

Introduction. The Theory of Consumer Choice. In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:

Fiscal policy: Ricardian Equivalence, the e ects of government spending, and debt dynamics

Final Exam Solutions

Macroeconomics: Policy, 31E23000, Spring 2018

Chapter 10 Consumption and Savings

LECTURE 1 : THE INFINITE HORIZON REPRESENTATIVE AGENT. In the IS-LM model consumption is assumed to be a

Economics 325 Intermediate Macroeconomic Analysis Problem Set 1 Suggested Solutions Professor Sanjay Chugh Spring 2009

Intertemporal macroeconomics

Lecture 4A The Decentralized Economy I

Chapter 4: Consumption, Saving, and Investment

consumption. CHAPTER Consumption is the sole end and purpose of all production. Adam Smith

Choice. A. Optimal choice 1. move along the budget line until preferred set doesn t cross the budget set. Figure 5.1.

Business Cycles II: Theories

Notes on Obstfeld-Rogoff Ch.1

Consumption, Saving, and Investment. 1 Macroeconomics Lecture 3

Chapter 4: Consumption, Saving, and Investment

Question 5 : Franco Modigliani's answer to Simon Kuznets's puzzle regarding long-term constancy of the average propensity to consume is that : the ave

Consumption and Investment

Economics 1012A: Introduction to Macroeconomics FALL 2007 Dr. R. E. Mueller Third Midterm Examination November 15, 2007

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

FIRST PUBLIC EXAMINATION

Business Cycles II: Theories

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

CHAPTER 16. EXPECTATIONS, CONSUMPTION, AND INVESTMENT

Open Economy Macroeconomics: Theory, methods and applications

Chapter 4: Consumption, Saving, and Investment

Consumption, Saving and Investment

(Note: Please label your diagram clearly.) Answer: Denote by Q p and Q m the quantity of pizzas and movies respectively.

ADVANCED MODERN MACROECONOMICS

International Trade in Goods and Assets. 1. The economic activity of a small, open economy can affect the world prices.

Transcription:

Micro-foundations: Consumption Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko 1 / 74

Why Study Consumption? Consumption is the largest component of GDP (e.g., about 2/3 of GDP in the U.S.) 2 / 74

J. M. Keynes s Conjectures about the Consumption Function 1 0 MP C 1: out of each additional dollar, we spend MP C and save 1 MP C dollars. 2 The average propensity to consume, AP C = C Y, falls as income increases. I.e., richer people save a higher proportion of their incomes. 3 Consumption is not responsive to the real interest rate. 3 / 74

The Keynesian Consumption Function Summarizing, the Keynesian consumption function can be written as: C = C + c }{{} =MP C Y, C > 0, 0 < c < 1. AP C = C Y = C Y + c, where Y is (disposable=after-tax) income. 4 / 74

The Keynesian consumption function 5 / 74

Successes and Failures Successes Household data: 0 < MP C < 1, AP C is smaller for higher income households. Aggregate data (in-between the wars, when income was low): the ratio of C to Y was high; Y was the primary determinant of C. Failures Falling AP C+rising incomes during the WWII would lead to a secular stagnation a long depression in absence of changes in G or T. This prediction about falling AP C did not hold. S. Kuznets assembled consumption and income data C back to 1869. Y, i.e. the AP C was stable (no trend). 6 / 74

Reconciliation of successes and failures: two consumption functions for the short- and the long-runs 7 / 74

I. Fisher and the Intertemporal Choice In reality, consumption responds not only to changes in current income but also to changes in (expected) income from future periods. 8 / 74

A Two-Period Model: The Consumption-Savings Decision and Credit Markets 9 / 74

Topics 1 Consumer s consumption/savings decision responses of consumer to changes in income and interest rates. 2 Government budget deficits and the Ricardian Equivalence Theorem 10 / 74

A Consumer s Consumption/Savings Decision Decision involves a tradeoff between current and future consumption. Dynamic Decision: It has implications over more than one period of time. By saving, a consumer gives up consumption in exchange for assets in the present to consume more in the future. By borrowing, a consumer gains more current consumption sacrificing future consumption when the loan is repaid. (Borrowing is negative saving.) 11 / 74

The Consumer s Current-Period Budget Constraint Consumption (c) plus savings (s) in the current period must equal disposable income in the current period. Each consumer has real income y and pays lump-sum taxes t in the current period. c + s = y t (1) 12 / 74

The Consumer s Future-Period Budget Constraint In the future period, the consumer has disposable income y t and receives the interest and principal on his or her savings, which totals (1 + r)s. c = y t + (1 + r)s (2) 13 / 74

The Consumer s Lifetime Budget Constraint Solve (2) for s: s = c y + t 1 + r Substitute (3) in (1) obtaining lifetime budget constraint: c + c 1 + r = y t + y t 1 + r (3) (4) 14 / 74

Consumer s Lifetime Wealth The present value of lifetime disposable income is the quantity of resources that the consumer has available to spend on consumption, in present-value terms, over his or her lifetime. we(alth) = y t + y t 1 + r (5) 15 / 74

Consumer s Lifetime Budget Constraint Substitute (5) in (4): c + c 1 + r = we (6) c = (1 + r) c + we(1 + r) }{{}}{{} (7) slope intercept 16 / 74

Consumer s Lifetime Budget Constraint Consumer s Lifetime Budget Constraint The lifetime budget constraint defines the quantities of current 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. and future consumption the consumer can acquire, given current and future income and taxes, through borrowing and lending in the credit market. 8-1 17 / 74

Optimization If the preferences are represented by utility function U = U(c, c ), then the consumer chooses c and c that bring the highest utility index such that the budget constraint is exhausted. 18 / 74

A Consumer s Indifference Curves 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 19 / 74

Consumer Optimization Marginal condition that holds when the consumer is optimizing: MRS c,c = 1 + r (8) The marginal rate of substitution of current consumption for future consumption is equal to the relative price of current consumption in terms of future consumption. 20 / 74

Optimization The highest possible utility is achieved at the point (c, c ), where the slope of the indifference curve is equal to the slope of the budget constraint. 21 / 74

Optimization The indifference curve: any combination of c and c that bring the same utility index U. The slope of indifference curve is defined from: du = MU 1 dc + MU 2 dc, or 0 = MU 1 dc + MU 2 dc, i.e., The slope of the budget constraint: (1 + r). When consumer maximizes utility, on the margin, the benefit of adjusting his optimal bundle of (c, c ) should be zero. The period-1 cost of reducing consumption by dc is MU 1 dc, and the period-2 benefit of this reduction is MU 2 dc (1 + r). Thus, at the optimum: MU 1 dc = MU 2 dc (1 + r), or MU 1 MU 2 = (1 + r). 22 / 74

Figure 8.3 A Consumer Who Is a Lender A Consumer Who Is a Lender 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. The optimal consumption bundle for the consumer is at point A. The consumer is a lender, as the consumption bundle chosen implies positive savings, with E being the endowment point. 8-1 23 / 74

Figure 8.4 A Consumer Who Is a Borrower A Consumer Who Is a Borrower 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. The optimal consumption bundle for the consumer is at point A. Because current consumption exceeds current disposable income, saving is negative, and so the consumer is a borrower. 8-1 24 / 74

An Increase in Current Income for the Consumer Because current-period and future consumption are normal goods, consumption in both periods increases. Saving increases. The consumer acts to smooth consumption over time. 25 / 74

The Effects of an Increase in Current Income for a ffects of an Increase in Current Income Lender re 8.5 Lender rson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. An increase in current income increases lifetime wealth form we 1 to we 2, shifting the lifetime budget constraint to the right and leaving its slope unchanged, because the real interest rate does not change. Initially, the consumer chooses A, and he or she chooses B after current income increases. 8-1 26 / 74

Observed Consumption-Smoothing Behavior Aggregate consumption of nondurables and services is smooth relative to aggregate income, but the consumption of durables is more volatile than income. This is because durables consumption is economically more like investment than consumption. 27 / 74

Percentage Deviations from Trend in Consumption of Figure 8.6 Durables and Percentage RealDeviations GDP from Trend in Consumption of Durables and Real GDP 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. The consumption of durables is economically similar to investment expenditures, which is why consumer durables expenditure is more volatile than real GDP. 8-1 28 / 74

PercentageFigure Deviations 8.7 from Trend in Consumption of Percentage Deviations from Trend in Consumption Nondurables and Services and Real GDP. of Nondurables and Services and Real GDP 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. The consumption of nondurables and services is fairly close to a pure flow of consumption services. Consumption of nondurables and services is much smoother than real GDP, reflecting the motive of consumers to smooth consumption relative to income. 8-1 29 / 74

An Increase in Future Income for the Consumer Current and future consumption increase. Saving decreases. The consumer acts to smooth consumption over time. 30 / 74

re 8.8 crease in Future Income The Effects of an Increase in Future Income arson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. An increase in future income increases lifetime wealth form we 1 to we 2, shifting the lifetime budget constraint to the right and leaving its slope unchanged. The consumer initially chooses point A, and he or she chooses B after the budget constraint shifts. 8-1 31 / 74

Temporary and Permanent Increases in Income A consumer will tend to save most of a purely temporary income increase. As a permanent increase in income will have a larger effect on lifetime wealth than a temporary increase, there will be a larger effect on current consumption. 32 / 74

Temporary versus Permanent Increases in Income 8.9 A temporary increase in rary Versus Permanent Increases in Income income is an increase in current income, with the budget constraint shifting from AB to DE and the optimal consumption bundle changing form H to J. Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. When there is a permanent increase in income, current and future income both increase, and the budget constraint shifts from AB to F G, with the optimal consumption 8-1 bundle changing from H to K. 33 / 74

Figure 8.10 Stock Prices Stock Price andindex Consumption and the Consumption of Nondurables of and ServicesNondurables and Services 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Percentage deviations from trend in stock prices and consumption are positively correlated, although stock prices are much more volatile than consumption. 8-1 34 / 74

ScatterFigure Plot: 8.11 Consumption of Nondurables and Services Scatter Plot: Consumption of Nondurables and vs. Stock Price Index Services vs. Stock Price Index 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Positive correlation between stock prices and consumption. 8-1 35 / 74

An Increase in the Real Interest Rate An Increase in the Real Interest Rate 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. An increase in the real interest rate causes the lifetime budget constraint of the consumer to become steeper and to pivot around the endowment point E. 8-1 36 / 74

An Increase in the Market Real Interest Rate The relative price of future consumption goods in terms of current consumption goods decreases this has income and substitution effects for the consumer. It changes the slope of the budget constraint. Changes in the real interest rate are an important part of the mechanism by which shocks to the economy, fiscal policy, and monetary policy affect real activity. 37 / 74

se in the Real Interest Rate for a Lender An Increase in the Real Interest Rate for a Lender When the real interest rate increases for a lender, the substitution effect is the movement from A to D, and the income effect is the movement from D to B. Current consumption and saving may rise or fall, while future consumption increases. on-wesley. All rights reserved. 8-1 38 / 74

se in the Real Interest Rate for a Borrower An Increase in the Real Interest Rate for a Borrower When the real interest rate increases for a borrower, the substitution effect is the movement from A to D, and the income effect is the movement from D to B. Current consumption decreases while saving increases, and future consumption may rise or fall. on-wesley. All rights reserved. 8-1 39 / 74

Effects Real ofinterest an IncreaseRate in the Real for Interest a Lender Rate for a Lender 40 / 74

Effects Real of Interest an IncreaseRate in the Real for Interest a Borrower Rate for a Borrower 41 / 74

Example: Perfect Complements (1) With perfect complements, the ratio of future consumption to current consumption is constant. The consumer s budget constraint must hold: c = ac (9) c + c 1 + r = we (10) 42 / 74

Example: Perfect Complements (2) With perfect complements, we can solve explicitly for current and future consumption: c = c = we(1 + r) 1 + r + a awe(1 + r) 1 + r + a (11) (12) 43 / 74

Example: Perfect Complements (3) Substituting (5) in (11) and (12) c = (y t)(1 + r) + y t [ 1 + r + a (y t)(1 + r) + y c t ] = a 1 + r + a (13) (14) 44 / 74

Example with Perfect Complements Preferences Example with Perfect Complements Preferences The consumer desires current and future consumption in fixed 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. proportions, with c = ac. With indifference curves representing perfect complementarity between current and future consumption, the optimal consumption bundle is at point D on the lifetime budget constraint AB. 8-1 45 / 74

Government Budget Constraints (1) The government wishes to purchase G consumption goods, given exogenously. The aggregate quantity of taxes collected by the government is T. There are N consumers who each pay a current tax of t, so that T = Nt. The government can borrow by issuing bonds B, bearing the interest rate r. 46 / 74

Government Budget Constraints (2) The government s current-period budget constraint: G = T + B (15) The government s future-period budget constraint: G + (1 + r)b = T (16) 47 / 74

The Government t Present-Value Budget Constraint Solving (16) for B: Substitute (17) in (15): B = T G 1 + r (17) G + G 1 + r = T + T 1 + r (18) 48 / 74

Competitive Equilibrium The market in which the N consumers and the government interact is the credit market, they are effectively trading future consumption goods for current consumption goods. In a competitive equilibrium for this two-period economy, three conditions must hold: 1 Each consumer chooses first- and second-period consumption and savings optimally given the real interest rate r. 2 The government present-value budget constraint holds. 3 The credit market clears. 49 / 74

Credit Market Equilibrium Condition Total private savings is equal to the quantity of government bonds issued in the current period: S p = B (19) 50 / 74

Income-Expenditure Identity Credit market equilibrium implies that the income-expenditure identity holds: Y = C + G (20) 51 / 74

The Ricardian Equivalence Theorem (1) This theorem states that a change in the timing of taxes by the government is neutral. Neutral means that in equilibrium a change in current taxes, exactly offset in present-value terms by an equal and opposite change in future taxes, has no effect on the real interest rate or on the consumption of individual consumers. 52 / 74

The Ricardian Equivalence Theorem (2) Substitute T = Nt and T = Nt in (18): G + G 1 + r t + t 1 + r = Nt + Nt 1 + r = 1 ] [G + G N 1 + r (21) (22) Key equation: The consumer s lifetime tax burden is equal to the consumer s share of the present value of government spending the timing of taxation does not matter for the consumer. 53 / 74

The Ricardian Equivalence Theorem (3) Substitute (22) in (4): c + c 1 + r = y + y 1 + r 1 N ] [G + G 1 + r (23) Taxes do not matter in equilibrium for the consumer s lifetime wealth, just the present value of government spending. 54 / 74

Ricardian Equivalence with a Cut in Current Taxes for a Borrower re 8.16 dian Equivalence with a Cut in Current Taxes Borrower rson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. A current tax cut with a future increase in taxes leaves the consumer s lifetime budget constraint unchanged, and so the consumer s optimal consumption bundle remains at A. The endowment point shifts from E 1 to E 2, so that there is an increase in saving by the amount of the current tax cut. 8-1 55 / 74

Equivalence and Credit Market m Ricardian Equivalence and Credit Market Equilibrium With a decrease in current taxes, government debt increases form B 1 to B 2, and the credit supply curve shifts to the right by the same amount. The equilibrium real interest rate is unchanged, and private saving increases by an amount equal to the reduction in government saving. ison-wesley. All rights reserved. 8-1 56 / 74

Key assumptions behind the Ricardian equivalence Each individual shares equal burden of taxes Any debt issued is paid off during the lifetime of the people alive when the debt was issued Taxes are lump-sum Perfect credit markets (same interest rate for borrowing and lending, no limit on borrowing and lending subject to the lifetime budget constraint) 57 / 74

Government Deficits, Taxes, and Government Debt The government deficit exceeded 6% of GDP in 2009. Taxes have fallen due to the Bush tax cuts and the recession. The government debt to GDP ratio has risen to almost 80%. 58 / 74

Total Government Surplus as a Percentage of GDP 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 59 / 74

Taxes as a Percentage of GDP 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 60 / 74

Federal Government Debt as a Percentage of GDP 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 61 / 74

Question What happens if the U.S. runs government deficits of 5% to 10% of GDP forever? 62 / 74

Assumptions Suppose real GDP grows at its average rate, 3% per year, forever: Y t = Y 0 (1 + g) t Suppose the primary deficit (G+Transfers T) is a constant fraction of GDP forever: a Y 0 (1 + g) t (e.g., a= 5%, or 10%) Suppose the real interest rate, r, is 1% per year, forever. Debt at time t is: B t = (1 + r)b t 1 ay t = (1 + r)b t 1 a Y 0 (1 + g) t. 63 / 74

Debt to GDP ratio It can be shown that B t = (1 + r) B t 1 a Y t Y t = (1 + r) B t 1 Y t 1 Y t 1 Y t = 1 + r B t 1 a 1 + g Y t 1 a ( ) t+1 B 1 1+r t 1+g = a(1 + g) Y t g r a(1 + g) g r, for large t, and g > r. If, e.g., a = 5%, in the long run or 257.5%. B t 0.05(1 + 0.03) = 2.575, Y t 0.03 0.01 64 / 74

Conclusions Primary deficit of 5% of GDP forever implies: Debt/GDP ratio of 257.5% in the long run (more than 3 times current ratio of 80%), with 2.6% of GDP spent on interest payments on the government debt per year in the long run. Primary deficit of 10% of GDP forever implies: Debt/GDP ratio of 515% in the long run (more than 6 times the current ratio), with 5.2% of GDP spent on interest payments on the government debt. 65 / 74

Liquidity=credit Constraints If the consumer is a would-be-borrower but cannot borrow, i.e., is liquidity constrained, then this consumer s c will be equal to y (current consumption equals current income). Thus, for liquidity constrained consumers current consumption is determined by current income. 66 / 74

Consider first the problem without liquidity constraints. Then, (c, c ) should satisfy 2 equations. The Euler equation: and the budget constraint: MU 1 (c ) = (1 + r)mu 2 (c ), c + c 1 + r = y + y 1 + r. With liquidity (borrowing) constraints, c cannot be larger than y, that is, c y. If the unconstrained problem gives you c y, then we say the constraint is not binding consumer is a saver anyways. Otherwise, if c > y, the maximum this consumer can have in period 1 is y. Summarizing, c bc = min{c, y}; c bc = c if c bc = c, c bc = y otherwise. 67 / 74

68 / 74

Example Let the utility function be U(c, c ) = log(c) + β log(c ), where log is the natural logarithm. Let y = 40, y = 80, no taxes, r = 0.05, β = 0.90. First, assume that consumer is unconstrained. For this utility function, MU 1 = 1 c, and MU 2 = β 1 c. The Euler equation tells us that 1 c = β(1 + r) 1 c, or c = β(1 + r)c. Plug this result into the budget constraint to obtain, c + β(1+r)c 1+r = y + y [ ] 1+r, or c = 1 1+β y + y 1+r = 1 1.90 [40 + 80/(1.05)] 61. Thus, c = 0.90 (1.05) 61 57.8. If consumer is constrained this implies that c bc y, and c bc = min{61, 40} = 40. Also, c bc = y = 80. You can also show that the liquidity constrained consumer will be worse off. 69 / 74

The Life-Cycle Hypothesis Idea: want to smooth consumption over the life cycle. Thus, need to save during the working life to support consumption during retirement. Assume consumer prefers a smooth consumption path; will live T more years; will work for another R years; has wealth of W ; and will receive a sure income Y during the working years. The lifetime wealth is W + R Y. Then, C = (W + R Y )/T = W/T + (R/T ) Y = α W + β Y. Thus, C Y = α (W/Y ) + β. In the short run, for a fixed W, an increases in Y leads to a falling AP C; in the long run, W and Y grow together, and C/Y is stable. 70 / 74

Milton Friedman s Permanent Income Hypothesis Milton Friedman postulated the following model of consumption: Income : Y = Y T + Y P, Consumption : C = Y P. Y P is the permanent income (the component of income that persists over time); Y T is the transitory income (short-lived components of income such as bonuses, overtime, windfalls from lottery etc.) 71 / 74

The Permanent Income Hypothesis (PIH) Implications: Consumption changes by the magnitude of a change in permanent income. Transitory changes in income are predominantly saved. AP C = C Y. In the household studies, most of variation in Y P Y comes from the transitory variation in income. Thus, if Y > Y P, C < Y, and the AP C is falling. = Y P Y In the long time series, most of variation in Y comes from the variation in Y P, and so AP C will be stable. 72 / 74

Hall s Formulation of the PIH P IH: consumption depends on Y P, and therefore on expectations of the lifetime income. Consumption then responds only to the news (unexpected changes, or surprises ) about lifetime income. Robert Hall: if the P IH holds, and consumers form rational expectations, then changes in consumption are unpredictable. Importantly, under the P IH only unexpected changes in policy influence consumption. 73 / 74

Readings Mankiw and Scarth. Chapter 17 (Consumption), and Section 16-4 (Ricardian equivalence). Stephen Williamson. 2013. Macroeconomics. Fourth Canadian Edition. Chapter 9. 74 / 74