Dynamic AD and Dynamic AS

Similar documents
Macroeconomics. Basic New Keynesian Model. Nicola Viegi. April 29, 2014

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Consumption and Savings (Continued)

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

Principles of Banking (III): Macroeconomics of Banking (1) Introduction

Monetary Economics. Lecture 11: monetary/fiscal interactions in the new Keynesian model, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014

EC 324: Macroeconomics (Advanced)

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018

ECON 815. A Basic New Keynesian Model II

Chapter 22. Modern Business Cycle Theory

Economics 502. Nominal Rigidities. Geoffrey Dunbar. UBC, Fall November 22, 2012

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

Monetary Economics Final Exam

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Technology shocks and Monetary Policy: Assessing the Fed s performance

The New Keynesian Model

Monetary Macroeconomics & Central Banking Lecture /

Chapter 22. Modern Business Cycle Theory

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Keynesian Matters Source:

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

The new Kenesian model

The Real Business Cycle Model

Macroeconomic Theory Lecture 7. October 23, 2014

Real Business Cycle Model

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

Macro II. John Hassler. Spring John Hassler () New Keynesian Model:1 04/17 1 / 10

The science of monetary policy

Dynamic Macroeconomics: Problem Set 2

Macroeconomics II. Lecture 07: AS, Inflation, and Unemployment. IES FSS (Summer 2017/2018)

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Spring University of Notre Dame

The Basic New Keynesian Model

Optimal Negative Interest Rates in the Liquidity Trap

ECON 314: MACROECONOMICS II CONSUMPTION

ADVANCED MODERN MACROECONOMICS

Monetary Policy. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Spring University of Notre Dame

2014/2015, week 6 The Ramsey model. Romer, Chapter 2.1 to 2.6

Notes VI - Models of Economic Fluctuations

1.3 Nominal rigidities

Slides III - Complete Markets

Topic 2: Consumption

A Real Intertemporal Model with Investment Copyright 2014 Pearson Education, Inc.

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY ECONOMICS NOTE 8b

004: Macroeconomic Theory

Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics. Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle

The Static Model. Consumer Assumptions on the preferences: Consumer. A description of the Model Economy

GOVERNMENT AND FISCAL POLICY IN JUNE 16, 2010 THE CONSUMPTION-SAVINGS MODEL (CONTINUED) ADYNAMIC MODEL OF THE GOVERNMENT

Solutions to Problem Set 1

1 A tax on capital income in a neoclassical growth model

Fluctuations. Shocks, Uncertainty, and the Consumption/Saving Choice

Sharing the Burden: Monetary and Fiscal Responses to a World Liquidity Trap David Cook and Michael B. Devereux

Solving The Perfect Foresight CRRA Consumption Model

GMM Estimation. 1 Introduction. 2 Consumption-CAPM

ECON 442:ECONOMIC THEORY II (MACRO) 8 1: W/C

Econ 3029 Advanced Macro. Lecture 2: The Liquidity Trap

Satya P. Das NIPFP) Open Economy Keynesian Macro: CGG (2001, 2002), Obstfeld-Rogoff Redux Model 1 / 18

ECON 6022B Problem Set 2 Suggested Solutions Fall 2011

6. The Aggregate Demand and Supply Model

Micro-foundations: Consumption. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Advanced Macroeconomics 6. Rational Expectations and Consumption

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

Macroeconomics Sequence, Block I. Introduction to Consumption Asset Pricing

14.05 Lecture Notes. Labor Supply

Part A: Answer Question A1 (required) and Question A2 or A3 (choice).

Gali Chapter 6 Sticky wages and prices

Alternative theories of the business cycle

TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES. Lucas Island Model

Monetary Macroeconomics Lecture 3. Mark Hayes

Textbook Media Press. CH 27 Taylor: Principles of Economics 3e 1

Aggregate Supply. Reading. On real wages, also see Basu and Taylor (1999), Journal of Economic. Mankiw, Macroeconomics: Chapters 9.4 and 13.1 and.

Charles Engel University of Wisconsin

Aggregate Supply. Dudley Cooke. Trinity College Dublin. Dudley Cooke (Trinity College Dublin) Aggregate Supply 1 / 38

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 11. The Smets-Wouters Model

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Fall University of Notre Dame

Imperfect Information and Market Segmentation Walsh Chapter 5

Chapter 4 Topics. Behavior of the representative consumer Behavior of the representative firm Pearson Education, Inc.

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

Introduction to DSGE Models

A 2 period dynamic general equilibrium model

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles March. Sciences Po

Capital Inflows in a Small Open Economy: Costa Rica. Jorge León

VII. Short-Run Economic Fluctuations

A Closed Economy One-Period Macroeconomic Model

Inflation, Output, and Nominal Money. Growth

Inflation & Welfare 1

Introduction The Story of Macroeconomics. September 2011

Asset purchase policy at the effective lower bound for interest rates

1 The empirical relationship and its demise (?)

Set 3. Intertemporal approach to the balance of payments

A Note on Ramsey, Harrod-Domar, Solow, and a Closed Form

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy Lecture 11: Zero Lower Bound and Unconventional Monetary Policy. Martin Blomhoff Holm

Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work-Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization

TOBB-ETU, Economics Department Macroeconomics II (ECON 532) Practice Problems III

Equilibrium with Production and Endogenous Labor Supply

004: Macroeconomic Theory

Economics 101. Lecture 8 - Intertemporal Choice and Uncertainty

ECON 3020 Intermediate Macroeconomics

Lecture Policy Ineffectiveness

Transcription:

Dynamic AD and Dynamic AS Pedro Serôdio July 21, 2016

Inadequacy of the IS curve The IS curve remains Keynesian in nature. It is static and not explicitly microfounded. An alternative, microfounded, Dynamic IS curve (DIS) has been developed, and is currently used in modern New Keynesian models.

Inadequacy of the IS curve The IS curve remains Keynesian in nature. It is static and not explicitly microfounded. An alternative, microfounded, Dynamic IS curve (DIS) has been developed, and is currently used in modern New Keynesian models. To be consistent with modern macro, the demand curve 1. must incorporate agents forward-looking behaviour 2. so, must be based on a dynamic (not just static) model 3. old IS-LM model has a Keynesian IS curve that embodies only static response of the level of investment today to the level of the real interest rate.

Inadequacy of the IS curve The IS curve remains Keynesian in nature. It is static and not explicitly microfounded. An alternative, microfounded, Dynamic IS curve (DIS) has been developed, and is currently used in modern New Keynesian models. To be consistent with modern macro, the demand curve 1. must incorporate agents forward-looking behaviour 2. so, must be based on a dynamic (not just static) model 3. old IS-LM model has a Keynesian IS curve that embodies only static response of the level of investment today to the level of the real interest rate. The New Keynesian dynamic IS (DIS) curve is the basis of all modern macro models.

Inadequacy of the IS curve The IS curve remains Keynesian in nature. It is static and not explicitly microfounded. An alternative, microfounded, Dynamic IS curve (DIS) has been developed, and is currently used in modern New Keynesian models. To be consistent with modern macro, the demand curve 1. must incorporate agents forward-looking behaviour 2. so, must be based on a dynamic (not just static) model 3. old IS-LM model has a Keynesian IS curve that embodies only static response of the level of investment today to the level of the real interest rate. The New Keynesian dynamic IS (DIS) curve is the basis of all modern macro models. It formalises the intertemporal-optimising insights we have verbally and diagrammatically incorporated into our basic IS-MP model: r current consumption via reallocation of spending over time.

Foundations of the dynamic IS schedule Because the DIS is such an important component of modern macro, it is worth understanding its formal derivation.

Foundations of the dynamic IS schedule Because the DIS is such an important component of modern macro, it is worth understanding its formal derivation. Deriving the DIS is fairly straightforward and helps clarify why modern New Keynesian macro emphasises consumption rather than the Keynesian investment channel in the monetary transmission mechanism.

Foundations of the dynamic IS schedule Because the DIS is such an important component of modern macro, it is worth understanding its formal derivation. Deriving the DIS is fairly straightforward and helps clarify why modern New Keynesian macro emphasises consumption rather than the Keynesian investment channel in the monetary transmission mechanism. We model consumers intertemporal optimisation using the normal budget constraint and indifference curves.

Foundations of the dynamic IS schedule Because the DIS is such an important component of modern macro, it is worth understanding its formal derivation. Deriving the DIS is fairly straightforward and helps clarify why modern New Keynesian macro emphasises consumption rather than the Keynesian investment channel in the monetary transmission mechanism. We model consumers intertemporal optimisation using the normal budget constraint and indifference curves. From these, we derive an IS curve in which current income depends on future income and the real interest rate.

Foundations of the dynamic IS schedule Because the DIS is such an important component of modern macro, it is worth understanding its formal derivation. Deriving the DIS is fairly straightforward and helps clarify why modern New Keynesian macro emphasises consumption rather than the Keynesian investment channel in the monetary transmission mechanism. We model consumers intertemporal optimisation using the normal budget constraint and indifference curves. From these, we derive an IS curve in which current income depends on future income and the real interest rate. Iterating the resulting recursive expression forward shows that in this dynamic model it is not just current income that matters, it is all future expected income (which embodies all future expected real interest rates).

Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply 2-period model, t = 1, 2. Initial wealth is W. C 2 C 1

Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply C 2 2-period model, t = 1, 2. Initial wealth is W. Consumption per period is C t, t = 1, 2. C 1

Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply C 2 2-period model, t = 1, 2. Initial wealth is W. Consumption per period is C t, t = 1, 2. Income per period is Y t, t = 1, 2. C 1

Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply C 2 2-period model, t = 1, 2. Initial wealth is W. Consumption per period is C t, t = 1, 2. Income per period is Y t, t = 1, 2. Real interest rate is r on savings from t 1 to t 2. According to the budget constraint, C 2 = (W + Y 1 C 1 )(1 + r) + Y 2 C 1

Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply C 2 2-period model, t = 1, 2. Initial wealth is W. Consumption per period is C t, t = 1, 2. Income per period is Y t, t = 1, 2. Real interest rate is r on savings from t 1 to t 2. According to the budget constraint, C 2 = (W + Y 1 C 1 )(1 + r) + Y 2 C 1 Slope of the budget constraint: MRT : dc 2 dc 1 = (1 + r)

Indifference curves Individual s discount factor is β. C 2 Ū C 1

Indifference curves C 2 Individual s discount factor is β. Utility, looking forward from period 1, is U = U(C 1 ) + βu(c 2 ). Ū C 1

Indifference curves C 2 Individual s discount factor is β. Utility, looking forward from period 1, is U = U(C 1 ) + βu(c 2 ). We can define the implicit function U = 0 and use the implicit function theorem to find: Ū C 1 C 2 = 1 U C 1 C 1 β U = MRS C 2 which is the slope of the indifference curve.

Optimisation C 2 In order to maximise utility, agents will equate the marginal rate of substitution (MRS) with the marginal rate of transformation (MRT), which yields: MRS = 1 β U C 1 U C 2 = (1 + r) = MRT C 2 Ū C 1 C 1

Optimisation C 2 In order to maximise utility, agents will equate the marginal rate of substitution (MRS) with the marginal rate of transformation (MRT), which yields: MRS = 1 β U C 1 U C 2 = (1 + r) = MRT C 2 C 1 Ū C 1 This gives rise to the Euler equation for consumption, an expression that characterises the optimal path of consumption over time: U C 1 = (1 + r)βu C 2

Deriving the dynamic IS Assume a particular form for the utility function that implies: U = C σ, where σ is known as the (constant) coefficient of relative risk aversion (CRRA) (implies an isoelastic, or constant elasticity of substitution (CES), utility function).

Deriving the dynamic IS Assume a particular form for the utility function that implies: U = C σ, where σ is known as the (constant) coefficient of relative risk aversion (CRRA) (implies an isoelastic, or constant elasticity of substitution (CES), utility function). Using this functional form and linearising along the long run values, we get: σc t = r σc e t+1 + r t.

Deriving the dynamic IS Assume a particular form for the utility function that implies: U = C σ, where σ is known as the (constant) coefficient of relative risk aversion (CRRA) (implies an isoelastic, or constant elasticity of substitution (CES), utility function). Using this functional form and linearising along the long run values, we get: σc t = r σc e t+1 + r t. We can use the fact that the income-expenditure equation implies: y t = c t + i t + g t (in log terms) and replace that into the expression for consumption. In the New Keynesian model, investment is a function of the capital stock and, consequently, responds to changes to the real interest rate (just like the standard IS). Here, we make the assumption that investment simply replaces depleted stock, so that it is always constant.

Deriving the dynamic IS That means we can write the dynamic IS schedule as: σ(y t g t i t ) = r σ(y e t+1 g e t+1 i e t+1) + r t. y t = g t + y e t+1 g e t+1 1 σ (r t r)

Deriving the dynamic IS That means we can write the dynamic IS schedule as: σ(y t g t i t ) = r σ(y e t+1 g e t+1 i e t+1) + r t. y t = g t + y e t+1 g e t+1 1 σ (r t r) This equation again implies a negative relationship between output and the real interest rate, just like the standard IS schedule.

Deriving the dynamic IS To summarise, so far: A New Keynesian dynamic IS (DIS) curve can be derived from a simple microeconomic model of an intertemporally optimising representative consumer with rational expectations.

Deriving the dynamic IS To summarise, so far: A New Keynesian dynamic IS (DIS) curve can be derived from a simple microeconomic model of an intertemporally optimising representative consumer with rational expectations. Basically, the DIS says that the output gap depends on expectations of future output gaps and today s real interest rate.

Deriving the dynamic IS To summarise, so far: A New Keynesian dynamic IS (DIS) curve can be derived from a simple microeconomic model of an intertemporally optimising representative consumer with rational expectations. Basically, the DIS says that the output gap depends on expectations of future output gaps and today s real interest rate. The big difference is the forward-looking nature of DIS. Expectations matter, and policy can operate through their manipulation.

Deriving the dynamic AD We can use the monetary policy rule we used in the IS-MP model to characterise the conduct of monetary policy in the New Keynesian model.

Deriving the dynamic AD We can use the monetary policy rule we used in the IS-MP model to characterise the conduct of monetary policy in the New Keynesian model. Doing so allows us to derive a relationship between inflation and output similar to the one derived in previous models.

Deriving the dynamic AD We can use the monetary policy rule we used in the IS-MP model to characterise the conduct of monetary policy in the New Keynesian model. Doing so allows us to derive a relationship between inflation and output similar to the one derived in previous models. The two equilibrium conditions are: y t ȳ = g t + (y e t+1 ȳ) g e t+1 1 σ (r t r) r t = r + φ π (π t π T ) + φ y (y t ȳ)

Deriving the dynamic AD We can use the monetary policy rule we used in the IS-MP model to characterise the conduct of monetary policy in the New Keynesian model. Doing so allows us to derive a relationship between inflation and output similar to the one derived in previous models. The two equilibrium conditions are: y t ȳ = g t + (y e t+1 ȳ) g e t+1 1 σ (r t r) r t = r + φ π (π t π T ) + φ y (y t ȳ) While the expression for output is: yt 1 [ ] = σ(g t + yt+1 e g e σ + φ t+1) φ π (π π T ) + φ y ȳ y Note that there is a negative relationship between inflation and output, as in the IS-MP model discussed before.

Dynamic AS We saw in the preceding section how the Phillips curve allowed us to derive an upward sloping aggregate supply schedule.

Dynamic AS We saw in the preceding section how the Phillips curve allowed us to derive an upward sloping aggregate supply schedule. In standard New Keynesian models prices, rather than wages, are assumed to be sticky due to a variety of possible reasons.

Dynamic AS We saw in the preceding section how the Phillips curve allowed us to derive an upward sloping aggregate supply schedule. In standard New Keynesian models prices, rather than wages, are assumed to be sticky due to a variety of possible reasons. Menu costs: the increase in profits from changing prices is small for any given firm but, due to aggregate demand externalities, this cost can be much larger for the economy as a whole. Firms don t change prices frequently. (problem: if all firms are the same, they will all either adjust or not adjust so, every period, prices are either infinitely flexible or completely fixed)

Dynamic AS Information asymmetries I: firms receive incomplete information regarding whether prices reflect demand for their own product or an increase in the general price level. They will respond by changing prices somewhat, but not enough to prevent all of the additional demand, and will therefore increase production too.

Dynamic AS Information asymmetries I: firms receive incomplete information regarding whether prices reflect demand for their own product or an increase in the general price level. They will respond by changing prices somewhat, but not enough to prevent all of the additional demand, and will therefore increase production too. Information asymmetries II: firms do not receive a signal to adjust their prices and, therefore, keep them constant for a number of periods.

Dynamic AS The latter case is by far the most common in the literature.

Dynamic AS The latter case is by far the most common in the literature. Because only some firms update their price, the general price will reflect that fact: some firms will change prices to reflect economic conditions while other firms simply keep last period s prices constant. This implies: p t = θp t + (1 θ)p t 1 where θ is the fraction of firms changing their price and p is the optimal price.

Dynamic AS The latter case is by far the most common in the literature. Because only some firms update their price, the general price will reflect that fact: some firms will change prices to reflect economic conditions while other firms simply keep last period s prices constant. This implies: p t = θp t + (1 θ)p t 1 where θ is the fraction of firms changing their price and p is the optimal price. The problem of finding the optimal price, p, is very complex, but it can be shown that, in combination with the expression above, that leads to the so-called New Keynesian Phillips Curve: π t = βπ e t+1 + κ(y t ȳ)

We can combine the new Phillips curve with the dynamic IS schedule to complete the DAD-DAS model. π t = βπt+1 e + κ(y t ȳ) yt 1 [ ] = σ(g t + yt+1 e g e σ + φ t+1) φ π (π π T ) + φ y ȳ y

We can combine the new Phillips curve with the dynamic IS schedule to complete the DAD-DAS model. π t = βπt+1 e + κ(y t ȳ) 1 [ ] y t = σ(g t + yt+1 e g e σ + φ t+1) φ π (π π T ) + φ y ȳ y

We can combine the new Phillips curve with the dynamic IS schedule to complete the DAD-DAS model. π t = βπt+1 e + κ(y t ȳ) 1 [ ] y t = σ(g t + yt+1 e g e σ + φ t+1) φ π (π π T ) + φ y ȳ y This model has a representation in (y, π) space that is exactly identical to the IS-MP model described above.

We can combine the new Phillips curve with the dynamic IS schedule to complete the DAD-DAS model. π t = βπt+1 e + κ(y t ȳ) 1 [ ] y t = σ(g t + yt+1 e g e σ + φ t+1) φ π (π π T ) + φ y ȳ y This model has a representation in (y, π) space that is exactly identical to the IS-MP model described above. Why is it a more useful model than any of those that we discussed previously? In short, because this version of the model allows us to think about the impact of expectations on macroeconomic variables, and how policy makers can attempt to manage these in order to achieve their policy goals (e.g., forward guidance).

Equilibrium r MP 1 r 1 r MP 0 DIS 0 DIS 1 Let s examine the impact of a policy where the central bank announces that it intends to raise its inflation target. ȳ y π LRAS DAS 1 DAS 0 π T 1 π T ȳ DAD 0 DAD 1 y

Equilibrium r MP 1 MP 0 r 1 r Let s examine the impact of a policy where the central bank announces that it intends to raise its inflation target. π ȳ LRAS DIS 1 DIS 0 y DAS 1 DAS 0 If the announcement is believed (and even if the central bank does not adjust their policy rule), then DIS shifts out to DIS 1. π T 1 π T DAD 1 DAD 0 y ȳ

Equilibrium r MP 1 MP 0 r 1 r Let s examine the impact of a policy where the central bank announces that it intends to raise its inflation target. π ȳ LRAS DIS 1 DIS 0 y DAS 1 DAS 0 If the announcement is believed (and even if the central bank does not adjust their policy rule), then DIS shifts out to DIS 1. π T 1 π T DAD 1 DAD 0 This leads to a shift in DAD to DAD 1 and DAS to DAS 1. Inflation is higher even though the central bank has not actually changed policy. y ȳ