NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND THE KEYNESIAN CROSS. N. Gregory Mankiw. Working Paper No. 2386

Similar documents
Final Term Papers. Fall 2009 (Session 03a) ECO401. (Group is not responsible for any solved content) Subscribe to VU SMS Alert Service

Introducing nominal rigidities.

Economics II/Intermediate Macroeconomics (No. 5025) Prof. Dr. Gerhard Schwödiauer/ Prof. Dr. Joachim Weimann. Semester: Summer Semester 2003

David Romer, Advanced Macroeconomics (McGraw-Hill, New York, 1996) (hereafter AM).

A Note on Ramsey, Harrod-Domar, Solow, and a Closed Form

Gehrke: Macroeconomics Winter term 2012/13. Exercises

Symbiosis of Monetary and Fiscal Policies in a Monetary Union Λ by Avinash Dixit, Princeton University and Luisa Lambertini, UCLA First draft August 1

Mathematical Economics dr Wioletta Nowak. Lecture 1

Dynamic Macroeconomics

Economics II/Intermediate Macroeconomics (No. 5025) Prof. Dr. Gerhard Schwödiauer/ Prof. Dr. Joachim Weimann. Semester: Winter Semester 2002/03

Mathematical Economics Dr Wioletta Nowak, room 205 C

On Repeated Myopic Use of the Inverse Elasticity Pricing Rule

SIMON FRASER UNIVERSITY Department of Economics. Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory Spring PROBLEM SET 1 (Solutions) Y = C + I + G + NX

EC 324: Macroeconomics (Advanced)

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Inflation Persistence and Relative Contracting

Was The New Deal Contractionary? Appendix C:Proofs of Propositions (not intended for publication)

Business Fluctuations. Notes 05. Preface. IS Relation. LM Relation. The IS and the LM Together. Does the IS-LM Model Fit the Facts?

Business Cycles II: Theories

Savings, Investment and the Real Interest Rate in an Endogenous Growth Model

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

Chapter 12 Keynesian Models and the Phillips Curve

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

Introducing nominal rigidities. A static model.

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

(b) per capita consumption grows at the rate of 2%.

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 7: Externalities, the Marginal Cost of Public Funds, and Imperfect Competition

2. Aggregate Demand and Output in the Short Run: The Model of the Keynesian Cross

9 D/S of/for Labor. 9.1 Demand for Labor. Microeconomics I - Lecture #9, April 14, 2009

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Mathematical Economics

TOBB-ETU, Economics Department Macroeconomics II (ECON 532) Practice Problems III

INDIAN HILL EXEMPTED VILLAGE SCHOOL DISTRICT Social Studies Curriculum - May 2009 AP Economics

Economics Macroeconomic Theory. Spring Final Exam, Tuesday 6 May 2003

CFA Program Financial Accounting (Text Book) - Study Plan

Macroeconomics I, UPF Professor Antonio Ciccone SOLUTIONS PROBLEM SET 1

Keynesian Multipliers with Home Production

ECON 302 Fall 2009 Assignment #2 1

Chapter 12 Keynesian Models and the Phillips Curve

Exact microeconomic foundation for the Phillips curve under complete markets: A Keynesian view

Press Release - The Sveriges Riksbank (Bank of Sweden) Prize in Economics in Memory of Alfred Nobel

1 The Solow Growth Model

Environmental Levies and Distortionary Taxation: Pigou, Taxation, and Pollution

Foundations of Economics 5 th Edition, AP Edition 2011

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls

y = f(n) Production function (1) c = c(y) Consumption function (5) i = i(r) Investment function (6) = L(y, r) Money demand function (7)

Government Spending on Infrastructure in an Endogenous Growth Model with Finite Horizons

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis

1 Multiple Choice (30 points)

FIXED COSTS, THE BALANCED-BUDGET MULTIPLIER AND WELFARE

Economics 2202 (Section 05) Macroeconomic Theory 1. Syllabus Professor Sanjay Chugh Spring 2015

Equilibrium with Production and Endogenous Labor Supply

ECO 301 MACROECONOMIC THEORY UNIVERSITY OF MIAMI DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS FALL 2008 Instructor: Dr. S. Nuray Akin MIDTERM EXAM I

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy

Topic 2: Consumption

5. Government spending in the one period economy

Economics 2202 (Section 05) Macroeconomic Theory 1. Syllabus Professor Sanjay Chugh Fall 2014

14.02 Principles of Macroeconomics Solutions to Problem Set # 2

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

Chapter 3. National Income: Where it Comes from and Where it Goes

PART II CLASSICAL THEORY. Chapter 3: National Income: Where it Comes From and Where it Goes 1/51

Come and join us at WebLyceum

Foundations of Economics 5 th Edition, AP*Edition 2011

The Government and Fiscal Policy

VII. Short-Run Economic Fluctuations

Macro Models: an APP for Macroeconomic Models. User Manual 1.0

A 2 period dynamic general equilibrium model

Final Term Papers. Spring 2009 (Session 02b) ECO401. (Group is not responsible for any solved content) Subscribe to VU SMS Alert Service

2014/2015, week 6 The Ramsey model. Romer, Chapter 2.1 to 2.6

Econ / Summer 2005

Principles of Macroeconomics Lecture Notes L3-L4 (Production and the labor market.) Veronica Guerrieri

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CAN AN INCREASED BUDGET DEFICIT BE CONTRACTIONARY? Martin Feldstein. Working Paper No. l43)4

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2012

Final Exam - Economics 101 (Fall 2009) You will have 120 minutes to complete this exam. There are 105 points and 7 pages

INTRODUCTORY ECONOMICS

Economics 325 (Section 020*) Intermediate Macroeconomic Analysis 1. Syllabus Professor Sanjay Chugh Fall 2009

Introduction. Jean Imbs NYUAD 1 / 45

PRACTICE PAPER - 3 Dr. A. THANGAVEL WIN ACADEMY - KUMBAKONAM MACRO ECONOMICS PGTRB COACHING CENTRE

Monetary Economics. Lecture 11: monetary/fiscal interactions in the new Keynesian model, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014

Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy

SHUFE, Fall 2013 Intermediate Macroeconomics Professor Hui He. Homework 2 Suggested Answer. Due on October 17, Thursday

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

Working Paper No. 2032

Strategic Production Game 1

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

ASHORTCOURSEIN INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS WITH CALCULUS. allan

On Forchheimer s Model of Dominant Firm Price Leadership

Teaching Inflation Targeting: An Analysis for Intermediate Macro. Carl E. Walsh * September 2000

QUICK REVISION. CFA level 1

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

ECON 101 Spring 2014 Lecture 5-6 Notes. Comparative Statics and the Multiplier Suppose the consumption function is linear and it is given by:

Monetary and Fiscal Policies: Stabilization Policy

In this chapter, you will learn C H A P T E R National Income: Where it Comes From and Where it Goes CHAPTER 3

Economics 1012A: Introduction to Macroeconomics FALL 2007 Dr. R. E. Mueller Third Midterm Examination November 15, 2007

Working Paper No October 1981

A Real Intertemporal Model with Investment Copyright 2014 Pearson Education, Inc.

Transcription:

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND THE KEYNESIAN CROSS N. Gregory Mankiw Working Paper No. 2386 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 September 1987 I am grateful to David Romer and the participants in the NBER Summer Institute on Industrial Organization and Macroeconomics for helpful comments, and to the National Science Foundation and the Olin Foundation for financial support. The research reported here is part of the NBER's research program in Economic Fluctuations. Any opinions expressed are those of the author and not those of the National Bureau of Economic Research.

NBER Working Paper #2386 September 1987 Imperfect Competition and the Keynesian Cross ABSTRACT This paper presents a simple general equilibrium model in which the only non-wairasian feature is imperfect competition in the goods market. The model is shown to exhibit various Keynesian characteristics. In particular, as competition in the goods market becomes less perfect, the fiscal policy multipliers approach the values implied by the textbook Keynesian cross. N. Gregory Mankiw NBE R 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 (617)868-3900

I. INTRODUCTION Fiscal policy multipliers are central to Keynesian macroeconomics. In this paper I explore a possible microeconomic foundation for one fundamental theory of income determination, the "Keynesian cross." My model deviates from a Wairasian equilibrium model only by the assumption of imperfect competition in the goods market. I show that textbook fiscal policy multipliers arise as a limiting case.1 Under imperfect competition, firms are always eager to sell an additional unit of output, since price exceeds marginal cost. This profit margin creates the potential for the multiplier. An expansionary change in fiscal policy increases aggregate expenditure, which increases profits, which in turn increases expenditure, and so on. The theme that imperfect competition may be crucial to macroeconomic issues is increasingly prevalent. See, for example, the work of Weitzman [1982], Hart [1982], Solow [1984], Blanchard and Kiyotaki [1985], and Startz [1986]. The purpose of the model presented here is partly pedagogical. I therefore do not hesitate making strong (yet not implausible) assumptions about the economic structure: Cobb-Douglas utility, constant marginal cost, and constant mark-up pricing. There is no reason to suppose, however, that the sorts of effects highlighted here are specific to these assumptions. While the model is in some ways surprisingly similar to the standard Keynesian model, in other ways it differs greatly. In particular, it incorporates both an equilibrium labor market and a static environment. These features are chosen for simplicity rather than realism. The goal is not to provide a complete reformulation of Keynesian economics,

2-- but only to illustrate what sort of Keynesian results one can obtain with a small movement away from Walrasian equilibrium in the direction of imperfect competition. II. THE ECONOMY This section describes the economy. The following section discusses the economy's response to changes in fiscal policy. People All people are the same. The representative person maximizes a Cobb-Douglas utility function over consumption of the single produced good (C) and leisure (L): U = a log C + (1 a) log L. (1) Leisure is the nunieraire. If w is the endowment of time, then w-l is labor income. Total after tax income is (o L) + fl T, where 11 is profits and T is the lump-sum tax levied by the government. The individual's budget constraint is therefore PC = (w-l) + fl - T (2) PC + L = w + - 11 T, where P is the price of the consumption good. The Cobb Douglas utility function implies a constant share a of "full income" is devoted to consumption. That is, PC = a(w + fl - 1). (3) Equation (3) is the consumption function, and a is the marginal propensity to consume.

3- Government The revenue raised by the government is used for two purposes. An amount G is used to purchase the produced good, and W government workers are hired. The government budget constraint requires that government spending equals revenue. That is, T = G+W. Total expenditure on the produced good is Y = PC + G. (4) (5) Using equation (3) to substitute into equation (5), we find V = a(w + II - 1) + 6. (6) Expenditure therefore depends positively on profits and government purchases and negatively on taxes. Firms There are N firms producing the single good. The industry takes expenditure in the economy as given.2 That is, the industry demand function is unit elastic: Q = YIP where Q is total output. (7) The N firms have the same increasing returns to scale technology. The technology requires F units of overhead labor. After the plant is set up, one unit of output requires c Units of labor. The cost function of each firm is therefore TC(q) = F + cq, (8) where costs are measured in terms of the numeraire, leisure. The N firms play some oligopoly game, the details of which I do not need to specify. This game determines the profit margin

4- = (P - c)/p. (9) As an example, if the firms act as Cournot oligopolists, then ji = 1/N. More generally, a conjectural variation equilibrium allows all possibilites between Bertrand competition (ji = 0) and perfect collusion (gi - 1); in each case, ji depends only on N and the conjectural variation. I therefore take the profit margin i as given for any fixed number of firms N.3 Note the relation between output and expenditure: Q = E(1-s)/c] V. (10) For given values of the profit margin i and marginal cost c, expenditure on the produced good and output are proportional. Government workers W are not included in expenditure V or output Q; hence, these measures are analogous to industrial production rather than GNP. Total profits are revenue less costs: fl = PQ NF cq. (11) Using equations (7) and (9), aggregate profits can be expressed in terms in terms of expenditure V and the profit margin JA: 11 =.tv - NF. (12) Hence, higher aggregate expenditure implies higher aggregate profits. The Labor Market The above discussion centers on the goods market. Walras's Law ensures that the labor market clears if the above relations are satisfied. To see that this is true, note that labor supply is the time endowment less the demand for leisure: Labor Supply = w - (1 - a)(w + fl T) (13) = (1 - a)(1i T).

5- Labor demand is the sum of firms' demand, NF + cq, and government demand, W. Thus, Labor Demand = (NF + cq) + W, (14) = (V - H) + (T - = (a(w + 11 - T) + G - ii) + (1 - = aw (1 - a)(fl 1). Hence, goods market equilibrium (including the government budget constraint) implies that supply equals demand in the labor market as well. Summary The two key equations are (6) and (12): Y = a(w + IT - T) + 0, (6) fl = iy - NF. (12) Expenditure depends on profits and the fiscal policy variables, while profits depend on expenditure. III. FISCAL POLICY This section addresses the impact of fiscal policy. The analysis is short run in that the number of firms N and thus the profit margin gi are held fixed. The Balanced Budget Multiplier Consider first an equal increase in government purchases 0 and taxes T. Equations (6) and (12) imply that dot dt=dg - 1-a - 1 - (15) The multiplier thus depends on both the marginal propensity to consume a and the profit margin t. Under perfect competition (ji = 0), the balanced budget

-6- multiplier is 1-a. In the limiting case in which the revenue from the marginal unit goes entirely to profit (i = 1), the balanced budget multiplier is unity. The story that accompanies this multiplier is in many ways standard. Initially, the increase in government purchases of tg raises expenditure by tg, while the equal tax increase lowers private expenditure by ag. The net increase in expenditure is thus (1-a)tG, which raises profits by ji(1-a)tg. The increase in profits in turn raises expenditure by a(1-a)ag, which again raises profits, and so on. This multiplier process yields the infinite series, (1-a) + ai(1-a) + a2112(1_a) + a3j13(1 a) + which equals the balanced budget multiplier in equation (15). Imperfect competition plays a key role here, for if the profit margin were zero, the process would end after the initial increase in expenditure. The Tax Multiplier Consider now an increase in taxes T, holding constant the level of government purchases G. The government budget constraint (4) implies that the amount of labor purchased by the government W must increase by T. The extra labor income received by government employees exactly equals the extra taxes paid; on net, individuals give up their time but receive no additional income. This policy intervention is thus equivalent to a reduction in the endowment w of T. In standard analysis, tax increases are coupled with reductions -in government debt. Government debt serves the function of transferring

7- resources from future generations to the current generation. increase is an endowment reduction to the current generation. Hence, a tax In this sense, a tax increase in the static model of this paper is analogous to a debt-financed tax increase in intertemporal (finite horizon) models. Equations (6) and (12) imply that the tax multiplier is dv - -a dl - 1 - (16) Under perfect competition (ii = 0), the tax multiplier is a. As competition becomes less perfect (,i -+ 1), the tax multiplier approaches a/(1-a). Again, the multiplier process works through profits. The tax increase lowers expenditure, which lowers profits, which lowers expenditure, and so on. The Government Purchases Multiplier Consider now an increase in government purchases G, holding constant the level of taxes 1. In standard analysis, future generations pay for a debt-financed increase in purchases. Here, the increase in purchases is financed by a reduction in W. In both cases, there is no immediate impact on the current individuals' budget constraint (2). Equations (6) and (12) imply that the government purchases multiplier is dy - 1 dg - (17) Under perfect competition, dy/do is unity. As the profit margin approaches one, dy/dc approaches the standard Keynesian value of 1/(1-a). Figure 1 shows how to demonstrate the multiplier graphically. Expenditure V is a linear function of profits II, with a slope of the marginal propensity to consume a. Profits are also a linear function of expenditure;

-8- the slope of this line is In the limiting case in which gi = 1, this locus becomes the 450 line of the Keynesian cross. An increase in government purchases shifts the expenditure function upward by tg, which causes a multiplied increase in total expenditure. Welfare Analysis Here I examine the effect of fiscal policy on the welfare of the representative person, as judged by his utility function (1). Government purchases are assumed not to affect utility directly. A complete evaluation of fiscal policy would also take account of the benefit received from public expenditure. The analysis here is thus limited in scope. An individual's utility increases only if his budget set, as defined by equation (2), is expanded. Since relative prices are constant, profits less taxes, 11 1, are sufficient for utility. The impacts of the fiscal policy changes on II - T are PkflL)J - -(1 - i.) 18) dg!dt=dg lagi d(fl-t) 1 dt 1-au d(fl T) = dg (20) A balanced budget fiscal stimulus in general reduces welfare. In the limiting case in which gi = 1, however, a balanced budget increase has no impact on welfare. As the textbook Keynesian cross suggests, the increase in government purchases has no social cost. The increase in income (here, profits) exactly offsets the higher tax bill. Both increases in government purchases and reductions in taxes increase welfare. In standard analysis, increases in G or reductions in T are

financed by future generations. Here, these changes are financed by -9- reductions in government workers W. In neither case is it surprising that the welfare of current individuals increases. IV. CONCLUSION The model examined here is surprisingly similar to both Walrasian models of general equilibrium and Keynesian models of income determination. It deviates from a standard general equilibrium model only by the assumption of imperfect competition in the goods market. As competition in the goods market becomes less perfect, the fiscal policy multipliers approach the values implied by the Keynesian cross. The model could be usefully extended in several directions. First, the labor market might be made less classical. One could posit imperfect competition among workers, for example. Some of the rents generated by expansionary fiscal policy would therefore accrue as labor income. The multiplier would thus work through both labor income and firm profits.5 Second, the model could be made intertemporal. The impact of debt-financed fiscal policy obviously cannot be studied in a static model. That saving and inc'estment play an important role in standard Keynesian analysis also suggests extending this model to a dynamic setting.

-10- NOTES 1. For an exposition of the Keynes-ian cross, see Samuelson [1948) or almost any introductory text. 2. One might object that this assumption is not reasonable because expenditure depends on industry profits. The model could easily be amended, however, to include a continuum of industries; the demand curve of each industry would depend on aggregate profits. 3. One could also imagine that each firm produces a differentiated product. In this case, the profit margin ti depends on each firm's elasticity of demand, which could plausibly be assumed constant. 4. Note that the second line is always steeper than the first, since a < 1 < 1/p. 5. Alternatively, the labor market could be characterized by efficiency wages.

11 REFERENCES Blanchard, Olivier J., and Nobuhiro K-iyotaki, 1985, "Monopolistic Competition, Aggregate Demand Externalities, and the Real Effects of Nominal Money," NBER Working Paper No. 1770. Hart, Oliver, 1982, "A Model of Imperfect Competition with Keynesian Features," Quarterly Journal of Economics 87, 109-38. Samuelson, Paul A., 1948, "The Simple Mathematics of Income Determination," in Income, Employment and Policy, New York: W.W. Norton, reprinted in The Collected Scientific Papers of Paul A. Samuelson. Solow, Robert M., 1984, "Monopolistic Competition and the Multiplier," M.I.T. Startz, Richard, 1986, "Monopolistic Competition as a Foundation for Keynesian Macroeconomic Models," University of Washington. Weitzman, Martin L., 1982, "Increasing Returns and the Foundations of Unemployment Theory," Economic Journal 92, 787-804.

Figure 1 A New Keynesian Cross V (fl + NE) l-a I Yct(wfl-T)+ G ri