The accuracy of the escrowed dividend model on the value of European options on a stock paying discrete dividend

Similar documents
On the value of European options on a stock paying a discrete dividend at uncertain date

EFFICIENT MONTE CARLO ALGORITHM FOR PRICING BARRIER OPTIONS

The Black-Scholes Model

A Study on Numerical Solution of Black-Scholes Model

The Black-Scholes Model

Assignment - Exotic options

No ANALYTIC AMERICAN OPTION PRICING AND APPLICATIONS. By A. Sbuelz. July 2003 ISSN

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

Implied volatilities of American options with cash dividends: an application to Italian Derivatives Market (IDEM)

Richardson Extrapolation Techniques for the Pricing of American-style Options

Simulation Analysis of Option Buying

The Forward PDE for American Puts in the Dupire Model

The Impact of Volatility Estimates in Hedging Effectiveness

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Black Scholes Equation Luc Ashwin and Calum Keeley

Hedging the Smirk. David S. Bates. University of Iowa and the National Bureau of Economic Research. October 31, 2005

ANALYSIS OF THE BINOMIAL METHOD

Computational Finance Binomial Trees Analysis

Computational Finance. Computational Finance p. 1

Financial Derivatives Section 5

CONSTRUCTING NO-ARBITRAGE VOLATILITY CURVES IN LIQUID AND ILLIQUID COMMODITY MARKETS

Math Computational Finance Double barrier option pricing using Quasi Monte Carlo and Brownian Bridge methods

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015

Pricing of a European Call Option Under a Local Volatility Interbank Offered Rate Model

Option Pricing Formula for Fuzzy Financial Market

FINANCE 2011 TITLE: RISK AND SUSTAINABLE MANAGEMENT GROUP WORKING PAPER SERIES

UNIVERSITÀ DEGLI STUDI DI TORINO SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT AND ECONOMICS SIMULATION MODELS FOR ECONOMICS. Final Report. Stop-Loss Strategy

FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008

Fixed-Income Securities Lecture 5: Tools from Option Pricing

Advanced Corporate Finance. 5. Options (a refresher)

Department of Mathematics. Mathematics of Financial Derivatives

Stochastic Differential Equations in Finance and Monte Carlo Simulations

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Valuation of a New Class of Commodity-Linked Bonds with Partial Indexation Adjustments

Simple Formulas to Option Pricing and Hedging in the Black-Scholes Model

Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model. Chapter 13

Lecture 6: Option Pricing Using a One-step Binomial Tree. Thursday, September 12, 13

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Aspects of Financial Mathematics:

In general, the value of any asset is the present value of the expected cash flows on

Option Volatility & Arbitrage Opportunities

Appendix: Basics of Options and Option Pricing Option Payoffs

[AN INTRODUCTION TO THE BLACK-SCHOLES PDE MODEL]

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Credit Risk and Underlying Asset Risk *

Edgeworth Binomial Trees

4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs. Math6911 S08, HM Zhu

Module 10:Application of stochastic processes in areas like finance Lecture 36:Black-Scholes Model. Stochastic Differential Equation.

Factors in Implied Volatility Skew in Corn Futures Options

Global Financial Management. Option Contracts

CHAPTER 10 OPTION PRICING - II. Derivatives and Risk Management By Rajiv Srivastava. Copyright Oxford University Press

Option Pricing under Delay Geometric Brownian Motion with Regime Switching

Financial Risk Forecasting Chapter 6 Analytical value-at-risk for options and bonds

Probability Default in Black Scholes Formula: A Qualitative Study

Market interest-rate models

American Option Pricing Formula for Uncertain Financial Market

Randomness and Fractals

THE USE OF NUMERAIRES IN MULTI-DIMENSIONAL BLACK- SCHOLES PARTIAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS. Hyong-chol O *, Yong-hwa Ro **, Ning Wan*** 1.

Walter S.A. Schwaiger. Finance. A{6020 Innsbruck, Universitatsstrae 15. phone: fax:

Math Computational Finance Barrier option pricing using Finite Difference Methods (FDM)

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

Math Option pricing using Quasi Monte Carlo simulation

Option Pricing Model with Stepped Payoff

Appendix A Financial Calculations

Merton s Jump Diffusion Model. David Bonnemort, Yunhye Chu, Cory Steffen, Carl Tams

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Volatility of Asset Returns

ECON4510 Finance Theory Lecture 10

Pricing Implied Volatility

Pricing with a Smile. Bruno Dupire. Bloomberg

F A S C I C U L I M A T H E M A T I C I

A Note about the Black-Scholes Option Pricing Model under Time-Varying Conditions Yi-rong YING and Meng-meng BAI

An Adjusted Trinomial Lattice for Pricing Arithmetic Average Based Asian Option

AN IMPROVED BINOMIAL METHOD FOR PRICING ASIAN OPTIONS

Numerical Evaluation of Multivariate Contingent Claims

Optimal Portfolios under a Value at Risk Constraint

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

King s College London

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Asset-or-nothing digitals

The Yield Envelope: Price Ranges for Fixed Income Products

The Pennsylvania State University. The Graduate School. Department of Industrial Engineering AMERICAN-ASIAN OPTION PRICING BASED ON MONTE CARLO

Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation

The value of foresight

An accurate approximation formula for pricing European options with discrete dividend payments

1 Geometric Brownian motion

Portfolio Management Philip Morris has issued bonds that pay coupons annually with the following characteristics:

Mathematics in Finance

Local vs Non-local Forward Equations for Option Pricing

Notes for Lecture 5 (February 28)

The Binomial Model. Chapter 3

Hull, Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 9 th Edition

TEST OF BOUNDED LOG-NORMAL PROCESS FOR OPTIONS PRICING

Introduction. Tero Haahtela

Option Pricing. Simple Arbitrage Relations. Payoffs to Call and Put Options. Black-Scholes Model. Put-Call Parity. Implied Volatility

Option Hedging with Transaction Costs

FORECASTING AMERICAN STOCK OPTION PRICES 1

Beyond Black-Scholes: The Stochastic Volatility Option Pricing Model and Empirical Evidence from Thailand. Woraphon Wattanatorn 1

Zekuang Tan. January, 2018 Working Paper No

MFIN 7003 Module 2. Mathematical Techniques in Finance. Sessions B&C: Oct 12, 2015 Nov 28, 2015

Transcription:

A Work Project, presented as part of the requirements for the Award of a Master Degree in Finance from the NOVA - School of Business and Economics. Directed Research The accuracy of the escrowed dividend model on the value of European options on a stock paying discrete dividend Weiqing Wu Student Number: 769 A Project carried out on the finance course, under the supervision of: Prof. João Amaro de Matos 07 January 2015

Abstract This project characterizes the accuracy of the escrowed dividend model on the value of European options on a stock paying discrete dividend. A description of the escrowed dividend model is provided, and a comparison between this model and the benchmark model is realized. It is concluded that options on stocks with either low volatility, low dividend yield, low ex-dividend to maturity ratio or that are deep in or out of the money are reasonably priced with the escrowed dividend model. 2

Table of Contents Introduction... 4 Literature Review... 5 Discussion... 7 The model... 7 Comparison... 9 Intuitions of the results... 13 References... 19 Appendices... 20 3

Introduction The aim of this project is to characterize the accuracy of the escrowed dividend model. This model has been widely used to approximate the value of European options written on stocks paying discrete dividend. Although the model has been popular amongst practitioners, its accuracy has not been properly discussed. Derivatives play a very important role in the finance market. In particular, options are actively traded by financial institutions, or fund managers in the over-the counter market for hedging or speculation. Choosing the most appropriate pricing method is critical for option traders to succeed. Many option pricing models have been developed to value options. However, depending on the nature of each option, different valuation methods should be applied. For example, to value European options without dividend payment, the Black-Scholes (BS) model (1973) gives the correct value under the Black-Scholes context. Variants of the BS model have been developed to deal with options with different properties. But for European options with discrete dividend payment, apart from numerical models such as the Monte Carlo option model, it has had no exact mathematical representation for a long period of time. Although the escrowed dividend model has been commonly used to price European options with discrete dividend, it does not provide exact valuation. Valuation of options written on an underlying asset that pays a discrete dividend is relatively complex. Fortunately, an integral representation (Amaro de Matos, Dilão and Ferreira 2009) under the Black-Scholes assumptions was found to provide the exact value for 4

European options written on stock paying discrete dividend. This model has been used as the benchmark for pricing European options on discrete dividend-paying stocks. Due to the application and popularity of the escrowed dividend model, it is important to understand the general performance of the model. By comparing this model to the benchmark model, we characterize the range of parameters in which the approximation model works, providing results regarding the accuracy of the escrowed dividend model under the Black-Scholes assumptions. Literature Review In 1973, Black and Scholes presented a solution to the problem of European option valuation. The Black-Sholes formula is still popular in the financial world. Besides the assumption that the stock price follows a geometric Brownian motion, the absence of any discrete dividend is also a key for the validity of the closed form. Nonetheless, many underlying assets distribute dividends, a fact that violates the Black Scholes assumptions. Merton extended the application of Black Scholes s differential equation to options that pay continuous dividend yield or discrete dividend proportional to the stock price in the same year. However, assuming a continuous dividend rate for options on a single stock is usually unrealistic. So if the dividend payment during the option life is discrete, the extended formula is no longer suitable. Black (1975) was the first to propose an approach to estimate a European option written on a risky stock paying a single dividend, although indirectly, known as the escrowed dividend approach. The basic idea is to adjust the current stock price by 5

deducting the present value of future dividends, and the actual stock price is replaced in the BS formula. Many adjustments to the volatility have been studied. Chriss (1997) suggested a simple adjustment that increases the volatility relative to the escrowed dividend process. Unfortunately, the volatility is excessively increased if the dividend is paid out early in the option s lifetime, which generally overprices call options 1. Beneder and Vorst (2001) proposed another approximation, namely a timevarying weighted average of an adjusted and unadjusted variance. Haug, Haug and Lewis (2003) also made the volatility process more sophisticated by taking into account the timing of the dividend. Unsuccessfully, the authors concluded that this method performs poorly for multiple dividends stock options. The discrete dividend distribution problem has received a lot of attention, but its complexity also caused confusion. Despite many other different methods tried to solve the problem, none of them were able to present a closed form to value European options with discrete dividend payments. Amaro de Matos, Dilão and Ferreira (2009) proposed a closed-form integral representation and a computational method for the analytical solution of the problem leading to the exact value for such options under the original assumptions of the geometric Brownian motion. Their method is computationally faster than any other exact computational method available, including Monte-Carlo simulations. 1 See Haug (2007) 6

Discussion This chapter is divided into three sections. The first section explains the stochastic price process, the valuation process, the escrowed dividend model and the exact European option with discrete dividend valuation model. The second section compares the performance of the escrowed dividend model with the exact valuation model, allowing to characterize for which parameters regions the approximation works well. The last section explains the intuitions behind the results found in section two. The model This section starts by showing the stochastic process of the stock price. Let S t be the value of a stock at time t, and let T denote the time to maturity of the option on an underlying stock. As mentioned earlier, the stock price follows the geometric Brownian motion. When the underlying asset pays a cash dividend D at time τ, a jump of size D is expected: S t = { S t PV(D), S t, t < τ t τ ( 1) where S t represents the risky part of the price process and D is the riskless part of the price. After paying the dividend, no further dividend discount is necessary since only one dividend payment is expected until maturity. Wilmott (2000) stated that if the price jump due to the distribution of dividend is known a priori, no surprise is expected at time τ, implying that the value of the option should not suffer jumps on the ex-date. A European option s payoff is the maximum between zero and the difference between the stock price at maturity and the strike price specified initially in the contract. To benefit from the upside payoff of the option, a premium is required. Black and Scholes (1973) introduced a formula to calculate the theoretical price (premium) of a 7

European option under certain assumptions. Conditions such as no dividend distribution, no commissions, and constant risk-free rate and volatility are included, apart from the lognormal price distribution and efficient markets assumptions. While the original Black Scholes model does not allow for dividend payment, it was extended by Merton (1973) to include continuous dividend payments. However, for options written on a single stock, it is unrealistic to assume such a situation. The model in the next paragraph describes how to adapt the Black Scholes model to European option with discrete dividend payments. The escrowed dividend approach is a popular model amongst practitioners. It is a simple adjustment to the BS formula, where the stock price is replaced by the stock price minus the present value of expected dividend. Let S 0 denote the initial stock price, K the strike price, r the risk free rate of interest, σ the volatility and T the time to maturity, then the formula to value a European option on a stock with a known cash dividend that is assumed to be paid at time τ is: c = (S 0 De rτ )N(d 1 ) Ke rt N(d 2 ) ( 2 ) Ln(S0 De rτ )+(r+ σ2 K 2 where d 1 = )T and d σ T 2 = d 1 σ T. Despite its simplicity and vast application, it also has few shortcomings. Haug, Haug and Lewis (2003) criticised that the approach often undervalues call options, Because the stock price is lowered, the approach will typically lead to too little absolute price volatility in the period before the dividend is paid. Moreover, the authors also argued that Not only does this yield a poor approximation in certain circumstances, but it can open up arbitrage opportunities! Such problems have remained until the exact valuation model appeared. 8

Amaro de Matos, Dilão and Ferreira (2009) presented an integral representation for the value of European options on an asset paying a discrete dividend. The time-zero value of an option written on a stock in such condition is given by: V(S, 0) = e rτ σ 2πτ + V[S (y), τ]exp [ (x y)2 ] dy 2σ 2 τ ( 3 ) where x = lns + (r σ2 )T and S 2 is the value of the stock just before the dividend payment. Not only is the formula (3) derived, but functional upper and lower bounds for the integral representation are also constructed based on the convexity property of the solutions of the BS equation. These boundary functions are computationally faster and more efficient than any other exact computational method. Comparison In this section, the escrowed dividend approximation result is compared to the exact value for a call option on a stock paying a known discrete dividend at a predefined time. Both the escrowed dividend model and the exact valuation model are implemented in the Wolfram Mathematica programme. After running the programme, theoretical prices for the options are obtained and registered for the two models. The accuracy of the escrowed dividend method is measured as the absolute difference between the estimated value and the exact value: ε = c V(S, 0). ( 4 ) For simplicity, the upper bound of V(S, 0) is used as the exact value. In the definition of the relative error, the absolute error should be divided by the true value; since there are situations where the option value may be too small, the use of the 9

relative error would not be the most adequate choice to describe the accuracy of the escrowed dividend approach. The numerical example of an option s parameters is taken from the original paper where the integral representation is obtained. Not only can the correctness of the programme implemented be tested, but the comparison can also be carried out without compromising the goal. The parameters for the upper bound function of V(S, 0) are: σ = 0.20, r = 0.03, K = 100, D = 5, T = 1 and τ = 0.5. In all examples, time is measured in years, σ and r are expressed in annualized terms. The numerical approaches to partial derivatives are realized for each of the parameters. In practice, each parameter is changed slightly while all the others remain constant. All figures are presented in the appendix. We start by changing the stock price slightly while all the other variables are kept constant. In Figure 1, we compare the results for options with different underlying prices. One of the results is obtained by calculating the upper limit of the numerical integration, using the formula (3), and the other is from the escrowed dividend approach, using the formula (2). The figure shows that the approximated value deviates more from the exact value when the option is at the money, and the error decreases as the stock price moves away from the strike price. Similarly, in Table 1(next page), where the error for the option with different strike prices is presented, we can see that the error has its peak around the point K = 100, that is, when the option is at the money. As a second approach we analyse, what happens to the option value by changing the interest rate, all other parameters being kept constant and the error of the escrowed dividend approach decreases as the interest rate increases. Thus, the value estimated by 10

the escrowed dividend approach converges to the true value when the interest rate is high (See Figure 2). S=100 D=5 r=0.03 σ=0.20 τ=0.5 T=1 Strike Price V(S,0) c ε 70 27.497 27.450 0.047 75 23.069 22.990 0.079 80 18.946 18.830 0.115 85 15.218 15.067 0.151 90 11.953 11.774 0.179 95 9.183 8.987 0.195 100 6.906 6.707 0.199 105 5.089 4.898 0.191 110 3.680 3.506 0.174 115 2.614 2.463 0.151 120 1.828 1.701 0.126 125 1.259 1.157 0.102 130 0.856 0.775 0.080 Table 1: Strike price effect: the difference between the exact value V(S,0) and the escrowed dividend approximation c, when changing the strike price and keeping all the remaining variables constant. After conducting more comparisons, more interesting results were obtained. We noticed that, on the one hand, extending the time to maturity of the option would make the escrowed dividend estimate come closer to the true value. On the other hand, delaying the ex-dividend date would make the approximation approach diverge from the exact value. Thus, one can conclude that the earlier the dividend payment and the longer the option maturity, the better the approximation. With respect to the volatility, Figure 3 shows that the error increases along with the variable. Thus, options with low volatility are better valued by the approximation than options with high volatility. To conclude the comparison process when changing only one variable, the amount of dividend expected to be paid is studied. It is clear from Figure 4 that options written on stocks that pay a larger cash dividend are priced less 11

accurately than options written on stock that pays a small dividend amount, all other variables constant. In order to better understand how the escrowed dividend model approaches the true option value, a new set of more intuitive variables is considered. Further analysis was carried out on variables such as: the moneyness S, the ex-dividend date to time to K maturity ratio τ, the discrete dividend yield D, and the volatility. The interest rate is not T S considered directly in the analysis as its effect is fully embedded in the moneyness variable, since the interest rate enters the BS formula inversely to the strike price, discounting the present value of the strike price. For any fixed moneyness, options with low τ T ratio, low volatility and low dividend yield are reasonably well priced through the escrowed dividend approximation. Figure 5 shows the error induced when varying only the option s moneyness and τ ratio. T It shows that options with higher τ ratios are worse priced by the escrowed dividend T model. Also as mentioned earlier, options near to the money are the ones that suffer more deviation from its fair value when all the other variables are constant. This tendency is maintained even more if the ex-dividend date is set to be at the medium or end of life of the option. Figure 6 demonstrates the difference in the value of the option by changing merely the moneyness and the volatility level. It shows that options with higher volatility are less precisely estimated by the escrowed dividend model, and that any moneyness change has little if any impact on the valuation process when the stock price variability is high. Figure 7 shows the performance of the approximation when changing only the moneyness and the dividend yield. When the dividend yield does not exist, the 12

fair value of the option is correctly estimated by the approximation. As the dividend yield raises and the option gets more in the money, the divergence gets more significant. In Figure 8, when the volatility and the dividend yield are changed, the option s value is also differently estimated. If the volatility and the dividend yield are increased at the same time, the error is also increased. However, when the dividend yield is small, the error induced by increasing the volatility is much lower than it would be if the dividend yield were large (see Figure 9). Analogously, by changing the ex-dividend date to maturity ratio with the dividend yield, keeping all the other variables constant, one can conclude that the value of an option written on a stock that pays higher and later dividend has a larger error. In addition, the higher the dividend, the larger the error induced by delaying the dividend distribution (see Figure 10). For the example used in the comparison, the maximum error when changing the stock price or the interest rate is 0.20 units of currency. The same magnitude of error can be achieved either by setting the volatility equal to 0.02, or by setting the cash dividend equal to 5 units of currency, ceteris paribus. All in all, options under low volatility, low dividend yield, low ex-dividend to maturity ratio and not near the money conditions are priced with relative accuracy with the escrowed dividend model. In other words, it should be acceptable to use the escrowed dividend model if these conditions are met. Intuitions of the results Possible reasons for the findings are discussed in this section. We concluded that options near the money are not adequately priced by the escrowed dividend approximation. As the difference between the stock price and the strike price increases, the mispricing decreases. Moreover, options on a stock with lower volatility are better 13

estimated by the escrowed dividend approximation than options on stock with higher volatility. All this leads to suggest the following: The less uncertain the option s exercise is, the less the escrowed dividend approximation deviates from the exact valuation and the smaller the error is. When the stock price is significantly in the money, the probability of exercising the option written on such underlying asset is close to one and the error goes to zero. Analogously, when the stock price is considerably out of the money, the probability of exercising one such an option goes to zero and the error also tends to be negligible. In both circumstances, the option valuation is more deterministic. In contrast, if the stock price is close to the strike price, the uncertainty about exercising the option is very large 2, leading to a larger error. Another parameter that can lower the randomness underlying the valuation is the volatility. In the extreme case, when the volatility tends to zero, the only factor that affects the stock price evolution is the interest rate, making the option valuation deterministic. Graph 1 in the next page shows the price evolution of a stock under two distinct situations. In the first situation (blue line), there is no dividend payment. But in the other situation, dividend payment is assumed at an intermediate time, implying a jump of size D in the stock value to the red line. The stock has its price level of S 0 at time zero; in the absence of volatility and dividend payment, the stock price at maturity increases only by the interest rate r to S T = S 0 e rt. Likewise, in the case where the dividend is considered at time τ, the stock price at that point of time would be S τ = 2 The probability in such situation lied on the middle range, it is hard to say whereas the option would end up in or out of the money. 14

S 0 e rτ D right after the dividend payment. At maturity this stock would have incorporated more time value and it would be valued at S T = S τ e r(t τ). We now calculate the initial stock price under no dividend and zero volatility consistent with S T at maturity. By going backwards, the stock would be S 0 = S τ e rτ. After doing some maths 3, the initial stock value that satisfies the condition is S 0 =S 0 De rτ. Note that this initial value actually assimilates the adjustment of the stock price in the escrowed dividend model. Remember that in the approximation model, the underlying asset s initial price is reduced by the present value of future dividend. That said, the escrowed dividend model should give the exact value for European option paying discrete dividend in the absence of volatility, or in other words, when the option valuation is deterministic. S s T D s T s 0 s 0 s τ τ T t Graph 1: the stock price process in the absence of volatility across time. Another factor that decreases the error as it increases is the interest rate. As mentioned before, the higher the interest rate, the lower the present value of the strike price. In the extreme case when the interest rate tends to infinite, the present value of the 3 S 0 = S τ e rτ = [S 0 e rτ D]e rτ = S0 De rτ 15

strike price goes to zero, making the call value to approach the stock price 4. Hence, the effect of having a high interest rate is similar to the effect of low strike price, but at a smaller rate 5. Once the escrowed dividend model works better when the strike price is low, then it should also work with high interest rate. Besides the moneyness and the volatility, the timing and the value of the dividend payment also affect the estimation of the escrowed dividend model. The timing and the amount of the dividend paid have an impact on the option valuation. It is assumed that a certain amount of dividend would be paid for sure at a certain point of time τ. Options written on stocks paying a high dividend amount are not properly priced by the escrowed dividend model. In addition, the error is larger if the dividend is paid later in time. This fact has already been stressed (E. G. Haug 2007). It is not difficult to understand that when the cash dividend is small, the mispricing is small, since the approximation coincides with the Black-Scholes formula as D tends to zero. Thus, the smaller the dividend announced at time zero, the better the escrowed dividend approximation performs. Regarding the dividend payment time, the impact of paying the dividend at time τ can be smoothed over if the options expiration time is long enough, because the time value of the option is high enough to compensate the deviation caused at the ex-dividend date. That is, after the dividend payment, option is correctly estimated without any dividend distribution. An equivalent way to have the same result is by paying the dividend as early as possible during a fixed time to maturity, reducing uncertainty about the stock level at the time when dividends are paid. Therefore, the lower the ex-dividend date to time to maturity ratio, the better the escrowed dividend approximation results. 4 lim r N(d 1 ) = lim r N(d 2 ) = 1 lim c = lim [(S 0 De rτ ) Ke rt ] lim c = S 0 r r r 5 However, the same percentage change in the interest rate r-1has a much smaller effect on call values than a percentage change in the strike price, (C.Cox and Rubinstein 1985, 217) 16

Conclusion We analyse the performance of the escrowed dividend approximation for European options on a stock that pays a dividend D at time τ. The objective is to clarify for what range of the model parameters does the approach provide acceptable results. The larger the difference between the stock price and the strike price of the option, the better the approximation. That is, the option pricing approximation shows better result if the price of underlying asset is significantly deep in the money or deep out of the money. However, if the option is near the money, the escrowed dividend approach may not be the best choice to estimate the option value. The interest rate change may have an indirect impact on the option valuation through the present value of the strike price. Large interest rates yield better results for the escrowed dividend approximation as compared to low interest rates, all other variables constant. When the volatility is low, the premium estimated by the escrowed dividend approximation is very close to the exact valuation method. Since the variability of the stock price is low, the option valuation is more a deterministic rather than nondeterministic process. With respect to the option s time to maturity, we concluded that the longer the maturity, the more precise the escrowed dividend approximation. Another variable that influences the option pricing formula is the size of the cash dividend. The mispricing is shown to be larger the higher the dividend paid. As the escrowed dividend model reduces the stock price in the beginning of the life of the option by the present value of the dividend, paying a high dividend could reduce also the absolute price variability, which in turn decreases the value of the option, deviating from the exact value. Besides 17

the size, the dividend timing also influences the performance of the approximation approach. The later the dividend payment the larger the mispricing. Summing up, options on stocks with either low volatility, low dividend yield, low ex-dividend to maturity ratio or that are deep in or out of the money are reasonably priced with the escrowed dividend model. In other words, it should be acceptable to use the escrowed dividend model if some of these conditions are met. 18

References Amaro de Matos, João, Rui Dilão, and Bruno Ferreira. 2009. "On the value of European options on a stock paing a discrete dividend." Jounal of Modelling in Management 4 (3): 235-248. Beneder, Reimer, and Ton Vorst. 2001. "Options on Dividends Paying Stocks." Proceedings of the International Conference on Mathematical Finance. Shanghai. Black, Fischer, and Myron Scholes. 1973. "The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities." Journal of Political Economy 81: 637-654. Black, Fisher. 1975. "Fact and fantasy in the use of options." Financial Analytst Journal 31: 36-72. C.Cox, Jonh, and Mark Rubinstein. 1985. Options Markets. New Jersey: Prentice-Hall, Inc. Chriss, Neil A. 1997. Black-Scholes and Beyond: Option Pricing Models. New York: McGraw-Hill. Frishling, Volf. 2002. "A discrete question." Risk 15: 115-16. Haug, Espen Gaarder. 2007. The complete guide to Option Pricing Formulas. New York: McGraw-Hill. Haug, Espen, Jorgen Haug, and Alan Lewis. 2003. "Back to Basics: a new approach to the discrete dividend problem." Wilmott Magazie 37-47. Merton, Robert C. 1973. "Theory of Rational Option Pricing." The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 4: 141-183. Wilmott, Paul. 2000. On Quantitative Finance. Chichester: Jonh Wiley & Sons. 19

Absolute Error Absolute error Appendices Stock price effect 0.25 K=100; d=5; r=3%; σ=20%; T=1; τ= 0.5 0.2 0.15 0.1 0.05 0 5 15 25 35 45 55 65 75 85 95 105 115 125 135 145 155 165 175 185 195 Stock Price Figure 1: the performance of the escrowed dividend model when changing the stock price, ceteris paribus. Interest rate effect 0.25 S=100; K=100; r=3%; σ=20%; T=1; τ= 0.5 0.2 0.15 0.1 0.05 0 r 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70% 80% 90% Interest Rate Figure 2: The performance of the escrowed dividend model on interest rate changes, ceteris paribus. 20

Absolute Error Absolute Error Volatility effect 2 S=100; K=100; r=3%; d=5; T=1; τ= 0.5 1.5 1 0.5 0 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 Volatility Figure 3: the performance of the escrowed dividend model when changing only the volatility, ceteris paribus. Dividend effect 0.7 0.6 S=100; K=100; r=3%; σ=20%; T=1; τ= 0.5 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 Dividend Figure 4: the performance of the escrowed dividend model when changing only the dividend payment, ceteris paribus. 21

Volatility t/t ratio Moneyness vs τ/t ratio 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 0.83 0.87 0.91 0.95 1 1.05 Moneyness 1.11 1.18 0.8 0.55 0.3 0.05 1.25 0-0.1 0.1-0.2 0.2-0.3 0.3-0.4 Figure 5: the performance of the escrowed dividend model when changing moneyness and ex-dividend date time to the maturity ratio. (σ=0.20, DY=0.05, r=0.03) Moneyness vs Volatility 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 0.92 0.94 0.97 1 1.03 1.06 1.1 1.14 0.05 1.18 0.85 0.65 0.45 0.25 Moneyness 0-0.5 0.5-1 1-1.5 1.5-2 2-2.5 Figure 6: the performance of the escrowed dividend model when changing the moneyness and the volatility. (τ/t = 0.5, DY=0.05, r=0.03) 22

Volatlity Dividend yield Moneyness vs Dividend Yield 1.2 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 0.83 0.86 0.89 0.93 0.96 1.00 1.04 Moneyness 1.09 1.14 1.19 0.09 0.01 1.25 0.25 0.17 0-0.2 0.2-0.4 0.4-0.6 0.6-0.8 0.8-1 1-1.2 Figure 7: the performance of the escrowed dividend model when changing the moneyness and the dividend yield. (τ/t= 0.5, σ=0.20, r=0.03) Volatility vs Dividend Yield 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 0.01 0.04 0.07 0.1 0.13 0.16 0.19 0.22 Dividend yield 0.25 0.28 0.85 0.65 0.45 0.25 0.05 0-1 1-2 2-3 3-4 4-5 5-6 6-7 Figure 8: the performance of the escrowed dividend model when changing the volatlility and the dividend yield. (τ/t= 0.5, S/K=1, r=0.03) 23

t/t ratio Absolute Error t/t ratio Absolute Error Dividend Yield vs t/t ratio 1.2 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 0.01 0.04 0.07 0.1 0.13 0.16 0.19 0.22 Dividend Yield 0.25 0.28 0.85 0.65 0.45 0.25 0.05 0-0.2 0.2-0.4 0.4-0.6 0.6-0.8 0.8-1 1-1.2 Figure 9: the performance of the escrowed dividend model when changing the dividend yield and the exdividend date to maturity ratio. (σ=0.2, S/K=1, r=0.03) Volatility vs τ/t ratio 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 0.05 0.15 0.25 0.35 0.45 0.55 0.65 0.75 0.85 0.95 0.25 0.85 0.65 0.45 0.05 Volatility 0-0.5 0.5-1 1-1.5 1.5-2 2-2.5 Figure 10: the performance of the escrowed dividend model when changing the volatility and the exdividend ratio. (DY=0.05, S/K=1, r=0.03) 24