On the Measurement of the Government Spending Multiplier in the United States An ARDL Cointegration Approach

Similar documents
Testing the Stability of Demand for Money in Tonga

Thi-Thanh Phan, Int. Eco. Res, 2016, v7i6, 39 48

An Empirical Study on the Determinants of Dollarization in Cambodia *

Structural Cointegration Analysis of Private and Public Investment

Using Exogenous Changes in Government Spending to estimate Fiscal Multiplier for Canada: Do we get more than we bargain for?

A multivariate analysis of savings, investment and growth in Nepal

AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF THE PUBLIC DEBT RELEVANCE TO THE ECONOMIC GROWTH OF THE USA

A Reply to Roberto Perotti s "Expectations and Fiscal Policy: An Empirical Investigation"

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

Cointegration, structural breaks and the demand for money in Bangladesh

Uncertainty and the Transmission of Fiscal Policy

ARE EXPORTS AND IMPORTS COINTEGRATED? EVIDENCE FROM NINE MENA COUNTRIES* HUSEIN, Jamal ** Abstract

An Examination of the Stability of Narrow Money Demand Function in Nigeria

Does oil price matter for Indian stock markets?

On the size of fiscal multipliers: A counterfactual analysis

ESTIMATING MONEY DEMAND FUNCTION OF BANGLADESH

Optimal Size of Government and Economic Growth in Malaysia: Empirical Evidence

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ARE GOVERNMENT SPENDING MULTIPLIERS GREATER DURING PERIODS OF SLACK? EVIDENCE FROM 20TH CENTURY HISTORICAL DATA

CHAPTER V RELATION BETWEEN FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENT AND ECONOMIC GROWTH DURING PRE AND POST LIBERALISATION PERIOD

Fiscal Multipliers in Good Times and Bad Times

A Threshold Multivariate Model to Explain Fiscal Multipliers with Government Debt

The Dynamics between Government Debt and Economic Growth in South Asia: A Time Series Approach

The effect of unemployment on economic growth in South Africa ( )

What determines government spending multipliers?

competition for a country s exports at the global scene. Thus, in this situation, a successful real devaluation 2 can improve and enhance export earni

Foreign direct investment and profit outflows: a causality analysis for the Brazilian economy. Abstract

The Demand for Money in Mexico i

The Dynamic Effects of Personal and Corporate Income Tax Changes in the United States

DYNAMIC FEEDBACK BETWEEN MONEY SUPPLY, EXCHANGE RATES AND INFLATION IN SRI LANKA

Government expenditure and Economic Growth in MENA Region

Government Spending Multipliers in Good Times and in Bad: Evidence from U.S. Historical Data

Does External Debt Increase Net Private Wealth? The Relative Impact of Domestic versus External Debt on the US Demand for Money

The Bilateral J-Curve: Sweden versus her 17 Major Trading Partners

Journal of Asian Business Strategy Volume 7, Issue 1(2017): 13-22

MACROECONOMIC DYNAMICS OF INCOME GROWTH: EVIDENCES FROM ARDL BOUND APPROACH, GMM AND DYNAMIC OLS ABSTRACT

Volume 29, Issue 3. Application of the monetary policy function to output fluctuations in Bangladesh

A Note on the Oil Price Trend and GARCH Shocks

The source of real and nominal exchange rate fluctuations in Thailand: Real shock or nominal shock

Response of Output Fluctuations in Costa Rica to Exchange Rate Movements and Global Economic Conditions and Policy Implications

ON THE LONG-TERM MACROECONOMIC EFFECTS OF SOCIAL SPENDING IN THE UNITED STATES (*) Alfredo Marvão Pereira The College of William and Mary

Government Consumption Spending Inhibits Economic Growth in the OECD Countries

Estimating Egypt s Potential Output: A Production Function Approach

Demand for Money in China with Currency Substitution: Evidence from the Recent Data

Long-run Stability of Demand for Money in China with Consideration of Bilateral Currency Substitution

Twin Deficits in the Lao PDR: An Empirical Study

Government Spending Shocks in Quarterly and Annual Time Series

Inflation and inflation uncertainty in Argentina,

LECTURE 5 The Effects of Fiscal Changes: Aggregate Evidence. September 19, 2018

Equity Price Dynamics Before and After the Introduction of the Euro: A Note*

The Effect of Technological Progress on Economic Growth

Oil Price Effects on Exchange Rate and Price Level: The Case of South Korea

Determinants of Stock Prices in Ghana

Impact of Total, Internal and External Government Debt on Interest Rate in Pakistan

RE-EXAMINE THE INTER-LINKAGE BETWEEN ECONOMIC GROWTH AND INFLATION:EVIDENCE FROM INDIA

The Demand for Money in China: Evidence from Half a Century

Dynamics of Twin Deficits in South Asian Countries

COINTEGRATION AND MARKET EFFICIENCY: AN APPLICATION TO THE CANADIAN TREASURY BILL MARKET. Soo-Bin Park* Carleton University, Ottawa, Canada K1S 5B6

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth Relationship in Nigeria

An Empirical Analysis on the Relationship between Health Care Expenditures and Economic Growth in the European Union Countries

Real Exchange Rate Volatility and US Exports: An ARDL Bounds Testing Approach. Glauco De Vita and Andrew Abbott 1

Asian Economic and Financial Review SOURCES OF EXCHANGE RATE FLUCTUATION IN VIETNAM: AN APPLICATION OF THE SVAR MODEL

Available online at ScienceDirect. Energy Procedia 75 (2015 )

Government Spending Shocks in Quarterly and Annual Time Series

Discussion of Corsetti, Meyer and Muller, What Determines Government Spending Multipliers?

Government Tax Revenue, Expenditure, and Debt in Sri Lanka : A Vector Autoregressive Model Analysis

The Relationship between Inflation, Inflation Uncertainty and Output Growth in India

MONEY DEMAND FUNCTION FOR PAKISTAN (DIVISIA APPROACH)

The impact of Taxation on Economic Growth in South Africa

Case Study: Predicting U.S. Saving Behavior after the 2008 Financial Crisis (proposed solution)

Dynamic Macroeconomics

INFORMATION EFFICIENCY HYPOTHESIS THE FINANCIAL VOLATILITY IN THE CZECH REPUBLIC CASE

Comparative analysis of monetary and fiscal Policy: a case study of Pakistan

Sectoral Analysis of the Demand for Real Money Balances in Pakistan

International journal of Science Commerce and Humanities Volume No 2 No 1 January 2014

How does an increase in government purchases affect the economy?

What is the effect of inflation on consumer spending behaviour in Ghana?

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY

Determinants of the Rate of Unemployment in Nigeria

A study on the long-run benefits of diversification in the stock markets of Greece, the UK and the US

Augmenting Okun s Law with Earnings and the Unemployment Puzzle of 2011

Monetary and Fiscal Policy Switching with Time-Varying Volatilities

Foreign and Public Investment and Economic Growth: The Case of Romania

Unemployment and Labour Force Participation in Italy

Can Retail Selling Prices of Petrol and Diesel Trigger Inflation in Malaysia?

Are saving and investment cointegrated? The case of Malaysia ( )

Determinants of Revenue Generation Capacity in the Economy of Pakistan

The Effects of Monetary and Fiscal Policy on the Stock Market in Nigeria

Government Spending Multipliers under the Zero Lower Bound: Evidence from Japan

DEFENSE SPENDING AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN AN OIL-RICH COUNTRY The Case of Saudi Arabia

MACROECONOMIC VARIABLES AND STOCK MARKET: EVIDENCE FROM IRAN

Multivariate Causal Estimates of Dividend Yields, Price Earning Ratio and Expected Stock Returns: Experience from Malaysia

Economics Bulletin, 2013, Vol. 33 No. 3 pp

PRIVATE AND GOVERNMENT INVESTMENT: A STUDY OF THREE OECD COUNTRIES. MEHDI S. MONADJEMI AND HYEONSEUNG HUH* University of New South Wales

Information Technology, Productivity, Value Added, and Inflation: An Empirical Study on the U.S. Economy,

Fixed investment, household consumption, and economic growth : a structural vector error correction model (SVECM) study of Malaysia

TESTING WAGNER S LAW FOR PAKISTAN:

What Determines the Long run Growth in Kenya?

A SEARCH FOR A STABLE LONG RUN MONEY DEMAND FUNCTION FOR THE US

Volume. 3, No. 2 July - December 2016 sijmb.iba-suk.edu.pk. Financing the Fiscal Deficit in Pakistan: Evidence on Ricardian Equivalence

A Note on the Solow Growth Model with a CES Production Function and Declining Population

Transcription:

MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive On the Measurement of the Government Spending Multiplier in the United States An ARDL Cointegration Approach Esmaeil Ebadi Department of Economics, Grand Valley State University 22 March 2018 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/85459/ MPRA Paper No. 85459, posted 25 March 2018 06:57 UTC

On the Measurement of the Government Spending Multiplier in the United States An ARDL Cointegration Approach Esmaeil Ebadi Department of Economics Grand Valley State University E-mail: ebadiesm@gvsu.edu March 2018 Abstract This paper applies annual data from 1962 to 2011 to investigate the long run relationship between government spending and Gross Domestic Product (GDP) based on Barro s (1990) government spending model. The common approach only considers defense government spending to estimate the multiplier to overcome the identification problem and endogeneity in isolating the effect of changes in government spending on GDP. I use the Autoregressive Distributed Lag (ARDL) approach to cointegration, which works despite having endogenous regressors to estimate the spending multiplier. The results confirm that government spending can be treated as a long-run forcing variable for the explanation of real GDP and the long-run multiplier is found to be 1.94. Key Words: Government Spending, Spending Multiplier, Cointegration, ARDL Approach JEL Classification: E62

1. Introduction At the onset of a recession the first macroeconomic policy which comes to a Keynesian economist s mind is to increase the purchasing power of consumers through demand management policies like greater government spending. This idea is based upon the assumption that the spending multiplier is greater than one (Barro and Redlick 2011). In other words, if government spending increases by one dollar, Gross Domestic Product (GDP) will increase by more than one dollar. Assuming that the multiplier is greater than one, government spending on public goods is free. When assuming a multiplier of approximately 1.5, not only is the spending of that one dollar on public goods free, but it can also produce more than one dollar in economic activity. The idea of classical economists (crowding-out effect) implies that given a multiplier of approximately 1.5, we should not consider reductions in the consumption of others or investment spending. The argument about the overall effect of government spending on GDP remains unsettled as there is no consensus among economists about the sign and size of it. Some argue that increasing government spending will boost total output through the crowding-in effect; however, opponents to this idea insist that government spending reduces overall economic activity through the crowding-out effect. These critics assert that Keynesian theory ignores the source of government spending (Mitchell 2005). If an increase in government expenditure is financed through borrowing, the consequence will be an increase in taxes to repay the debt in the future, thereby negating any stimulative effects on the economy (Ricardian Equivalence). Despite a lack of general consensus among economists about the size of the multiplier, there is a general understanding about the positive impacts of government spending on GDP growth. 1

Ramey (2011) assesses the likely range of the multiplier from 0.8 to 1.5 according to aggregate time series evidence. The range of the multiplier could be different based on different models and the assumed parameters. For example, Evans (1969) estimates the spending multiplier to be slightly above 2.0 based on the equations in the Wharton, Klein-Goldberger, and Brookings models. However, Barro (1981) illustrates the positive effect of defense purchases and he believes the effects of nondefense purchases are imprecisely determined. In fact, an endogeneity problem and lack of proper instruments for non-defense purchase make controlling its impact on GDP much too difficult to estimate. Therefore, he assumes defense purchases increase as an exogenous shock to overcome the endogeneity problem of non-defense purchases. Following Barro (1981), Hall (1986) focuses on non-defense purchases using military purchases as an instrument for government spending. He finds that an increase in Gross National Product (GNP) results in an increase in government spending. Rotemberg and Woodford (1992) take a similar view and focus on shocks as the residuals of a regression of military spending and conclude that the spending multiplier is 1.25. Including government purchases in a vector-autoregression (VAR) system and making identification assumptions concerning exogeneity and timing becomes a common approach in the literature. To overcome estimation bias due to omitted variables, Romer and Romer (2009) assume that omitted variables are orthogonal to the fiscal variables. The other assumption in conducting a VAR system is the variable ordering assumption. Typically, it is assumed that government spending moves first. Based on this assumption, a VAR model is sensitive to the ordering of variables in the system. However, this approach is not satisfactory for non-defense purchases (Barro, Redlick 2011). To exemplify, Hall (2009) applied a VAR model and he finds that the multiplier may be in the range of 0.7 to 1.0. 2

Likewise, Barro and Redlick (2011) illustrate that all estimates of the multiplier are significantly less than one, which implies a crowding-out effect. To correct the lack of timing in investigating the government spending effect, Ramey and Shapiro (1998) propose narrative evidence of anticipated military buildups in applying a VAR model. However, based on the findings of Edelberg, Eichenbaum, and Fisher (1999), Einchenaum and Fisher (2005), and Callavo (2005), there is no considerable difference between the reported spending multiplier considering timing indicators within a range 0.6 to 1.2. Also, we can consider the status of an economy by investigating the effect of government spending instead of estimating the average multiplier for a time horizon without considering recession or expansion. For example, Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012) apply a structural VAR (SVAR) model and estimate multiplier ranges of -0.3 to 0.8 in expansion and a range of 1.0 to 3.6 in recession. Regardless of the different identification assumptions and different variables, the drawback of using VAR models occurs when there is more than one cointegration relationship and the statistical approach to identification is not reliable (Pesaran and Shin 1999).Therefore a different approach is needed to overcome the identification problem and endogeneity of government spending that is particularly troubling in the existing literature to isolate the effect of changes in government purchases on economic activity (Barro and Redlick 2011). This paper attempts to solve the identification problem associated with government spending and also the endogeneity problem by using the Autoregressive Distributed Lag (ARDL) model proposed by Pesaran and Shin (1999), which works even in the presence of endogenous regressors. The ARDL procedure achieves an empirical advantage over other asymptotically efficient estimators such as DOLS, FMLS, and MLE because it is an optimal estimator 3

(Panopoulou and Pittis, 2004). I apply the ARDL approach to estimate the spending multiplier using a production function extracted from Barro s spending model (1990). The remainder of the paper is organized in the following way: Section II discusses data and an estimation strategy. Section III provides empirical results. Finally, section IV summarizes the conclusions of the study. 2. Data and Estimation Strategy I use annual real GDP data from 1962 to 2011, real capital stock, and real government spending, which are obtained from the Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED) database. Following Barro s government spending model (1990), I assume that the production function consists of private sector (capital) and public sector (government spending) in the Cobb-Douglas production format: Y = AK α G β (1) However, I do not make the assumption of constant returns to scale for the production function. Modifying the Cobb-Douglas production function by transforming the relationship to logarithmic form, I specify the regression as: ln RGDP t = c + αln RK t + βln RGE t + ε t (2) Where ln RGDP is the logarithm of real GDP, ln RK is the logarithm of real capital stock, ln RGE is the logarithm of real government spending, c is the constant term, and ε is the error term. I use the ARDL approach to investigate the long-run relationship among the variables. The main advantage of this testing and estimation strategy is that it can be applied regardless of having I(0) 4

or I(1) regressors (Pesaran et al. 2001). To avoid having variables that are I(2), I use the Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test and find that all variables are I(1). I proceed with ARDL as: ln RGDP t = α + n i = 1 β i ln RGDP t i + n i = 0 γ i ln RK t i + n i = 0 η i ln RGE t i + λ 1 ln RGDP t 1 + λ 2 ln RK t 1 + λ 3 ln RGE t 1 + μ t (3) The first part of the equation with parameters β i, γ i, and η i the shows short-run dynamics of the model. The second part illustrates the long-run relationship with parameters λ 1, λ 2, and λ 3. The null hypothesis of existing cointegration is: H 0 : λ 1= λ 2 = λ 3 =0 H 1 : λ 1 0, λ 2 0, λ 3 0 Pesaran and Shin (1999) propose a two-stage procedure, which works even when having endogenous regressors. The first stage is selecting the ARDL order using Schwartz Bayesian criterion (SBC) or Akaike Information Criterion (AIC), however, SBC performs slightly better. Then the ARDL model is estimated based on the optimum number of lags. The existence of cointegration can be investigated by conducting the bounds test. The F-test critical value tabulated by Pesaran (1997) and Pesaran et al. (2001) allows us to see if there is a long-run relationship among the variables. Estimating λ 3 as the elasticity of real GDP with respect to government spending allows us to calculate the spending multiplier. I use the arc elasticity formula to find the size of the fiscal multiplier as follows: d ln RGDP d ln RGE = drgdp drge * RGE Ave RGDP Ave 5

Having long-run elasticity and the ratio of the average real government spending and real GDP drgdp enables us to calculate the government spending multiplier ( ). drge The error correction model (ECM) can be estimated to see the speed of adjustment to long-run equilibrium due to short-run disturbance. I estimate the standard ECM as follows: ln RGDP t = α' + n i = 1 β' i ln RGDP t i + n i = 0 γ' i ln RK t i + n i = 0 η' i ln RGE t i + ω 1 ECM t 1 + ν t (4) 3. Empirical Results I use the ADF test to check that the variables are not I(2). The test confirms that the variables I have in the ARDL model are I(1). The ARDL bounds test approach for equilibrium long-run relationship among the variables is conducted by using the F-test. For two regressors the relevant critical value bounds at the 95 per cent level are 3.79 and 4.85. Since F ( ln RGDP ln RK, ln RGE )= 6.24, which is greater than the upper bound critical level, I reject the null hypothesis of no long-run relationship between ln RGDP, ln RK, and ln RGE regardless of the order of their integration. The challenging issue of causality from GDP to government spending could be addressed here clearly. Since F ( ln RGE ln RGDP, ln RK)= 0.07 and F ( ln RK ln RGDP, ln RGE)= 0.06 both fall well below the lower bound of the critical value band, the variables ln RGE (government spending) and ln RK (Capital Stock) can be treated as the long-run forcing variables for the explanation of ln RGDP (real GDP) (Pesaran and Pesaran 1997). Using long- run coefficient estimates, I replace lagged level variables with ECM t-1 and re-estimate the model at the same optimum lags. The negative and significant ECM t-1 coefficient supports 6

Table 1: Full-Information Estimate of Equation (3) Panel A: Short-Run Coefficient Estimates Lag Order 0 1 2 3 4 ln RGE 5.37-5.01 0.87 (26.52) (14.42) (4.15) ln RK 0.22 (6.38) Panel B: Long-Run Coefficient Estimates Constant ln RK ln RGE -9.00 0.85 0.45 (16.23) (12.10) (4.47) Panel C: Diagnostic Statistics F ECM t-1 LM RESET Normality Adj. R 2 6.24-0.15 0.95 1.40 1.27 0.94 (3.51) Plot of Cumulative Sum of Recursive Residuals 20 15 10 5 0-5 -10-15 -20 1962 1967 1972 1977 1982 1987 1992 1997 2002 2007 2011 The straight lines represent critical bounds at 5% significance level 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 Plot of Cumulative Sum of Squares of Recursive Residuals -0.5 1962 1967 1972 1977 1982 1987 1992 1997 2002 2007 2011 The straight lines represent critical bounds at 5% significance level Notes: a. Numbers inside parentheses are absolute value of t-ratio b. The upper bound critical value of the F test at the usual 5% level of significance is 4.85. This comes from Pesaran et al. (2001, Table CI-Case III, p. 300) c. LM is the Lagrange multiplier test for serial correlation. It has a χ 2 distribution with one degree of freedom. The critical value at 5% level of significance is 3.84. d. RESET is Ramsey s specification test. It has a χ 2 distribution with only one degree of freedom. The critical value at the 5% level of significance is 3.84. e. The normality test is based on test of skewness and kurtosis of residuals. It has the χ 2 distribution with only two degrees of freedom. The critical value at the 5% level of significance is 5.99. 7

adjustment toward equilibrium. The negative and significant coefficient of lagged errorcorrection term is another way of establishing cointegration. Also, I conduct three diagnostic tests. The Lagrange Multiplier (LM) confirms no serial correlation among the error terms, which means there is no omitted variable bias in the model (Pesaran et al, 2001, p.308). Ramsey s RESET test rejects the functional misspecification. Furthermore, normality holds for residuals. I apply CUSUM and CUSUMQ tests to the residuals of the estimated error-correction model to investigate the stability of estimated coefficients. Stability of the coefficients is confirmed by both the CUSUM and the CUSUMQ tests. The estimated error correction model has a very high goodness of fit, as reflected by 94% adjusted R 2. As can be seen from Table 1, the long-run elasticity of real GDP (RGDP) with respect to real government spending (RGE) is 0.45, which is significant. If I use this elasticity by RGEAve considering the arc elasticity formula ( 0.23 ), the long run multiplier is found to be RGDP = Ave 1.94. Although Ramey (2011) assesses the likely range of the multiplier is probably between 0.8 and 1.5 using common approaches, this estimation confirms his idea that the range of multiplier could be different based on different model construction and the assumed parameters. However, we should apply the optimal estimator to have a more accurate estimation of the multiplier as I did using the ARDL procedure. 4. Conclusion The paper contributes to the debate on the size of the spending multiplier. The main drawbacks of using the common approach in the literature, a VAR model, are the identification problem and the endogeneity troubling isolation of the effect of government spending changes on economic activity. In previous studies the focus was on defense purchases to overcome the endogeneity 8

problem. However, I consider the aggregate government spending (defense and nondefense) using Barro s (1990) government spending model. I apply the ARDL approach, which works despite having endogenous regressors to investigate the long run relationship between government spending and GDP. The results suggests that there exist a long-run relationship between Real GDP ( ln RGDP), Real Government Spending ( ln RGE), and Real Capital Stock (LnRK) and the variables ln RGE and LRK can be treated as the long-run forcing variables for the explanation of ln RGDP. After estimating the elasticity of real GDP with respect to real government spending I apply arc elasticity definition to find the multiplier, which is 1.94. This means that in the long run every one dollar increase in real government spending results in an increase of 1.94 dollars in real GDP. This estimation confirms that the range of the multiplier could be different based on different model construction and the assumed parameters (Ramey 2011). The main contribution of this paper is using the ARDL approach to overcome endogeneity problem. I show that there is just one causality direction from government spending to real GDP in the long-run by using an optimal estimator (ARDL). However, previous studies have not applied an optimal estimator and they focused on exogenous military spending to overcome endogeneity problem by using the VAR and SVAR models, which are not reliable (Pesaran and Shin, 1997). Therefore, I believe my estimation is more accurate and reliable than other time series approaches. 9

References Auerbach, Alan, and Yuriy Gorodnichenko. 2012. Measuring the Output Responses to Fiscal Policy. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 4(2): 1-27 Barro, Robert J. 1981. Output Effects of Government Purchases. Journal of Political Economy, 89(6): 1086 1121. Barro, Robert J. 1990. Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5): 103-125. Barro, Robert J., and Charles J. Redlick. 2011. Macroeconomic Effects from Government Purchases and Taxes. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 126(1): 51 102. Cavallo, Michele. 2005. Government Employment and the Dynamic Effects of Fiscal Policy Shocks. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper 2005-16. Edelberg, Wendy, Martin Eichenbaum, and Jonas D. M. Fisher. 1999. Understanding the Effects of a Shock to Government Purchases. Review of Economic Dynamics, 2(1): 166 206. Eichenbaum, Martin, and Jonas D. M. Fisher. 2005. Fiscal Policy in the Aftermath of 9/11. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 37(1): 1 22. Evans, Michael K. 1969. Reconstruction and Estimation of the Balanced Budget Multiplier. Review of Economics and Statistics,5 (1): 14 25. Hall, Robert E. 1986. The Role of Consumption in Economic Fluctuations. In The American Business Cycle: Continuity and Change, ed. Roger J. Gordon, 237 55. Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press. Hall, Robert E. 2009. By How Much Does GDP Rise If the Government Buys More Output? Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2: 183 231. Mitchell, D. J. (2005). The Impacct of Government Spending on Economic Growth. Execisive Summary Backgrounder Published by The Heritage Foundation 1831. Panopoulou, E and N. Pittis 2004. A Comparison of Autoregressive Distributed Lag and Dynamic OLS Cointegration Estimators in the Case of a Serially Correlated Cointegration Error. Econometrics Journal, 7, 585-617. Pesaran, M. H., and Pesaran, B. 1997. Microfit 4.0: Interactive Econometric Analysis. Oxford University Press: England. Pesaran, M. H., Shin, Y. 1999. An Autoregressive Distributed Lag Modeling Approach to Cointegration Analysis. Econometrics and Economic Theory in the 20 th Century: The Ragnar Frisch Centennial Symposium Cambridge University Press. 10

Pesaran, M. H., Shin, Y. and Smith, R. J. 2001. Bound Testing Approaches to the Analysis of the Level Relationship. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 16: 289-326. Ramey, Valerie A. 2011. Can Government Purchases Stimulate the Economy? Journal of Economic Literature, 49(3): 673-685. Ramey, Valerie A. 2011. Identifying Government Spending Shocks: It s All in the Timing. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 126(1): 1 50. Ramey, Valerie A., and Matthew D. Shapiro. 1998. Costly Capital Reallocation and the Effects of Government Spending. Carnegie Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 48: 145 94. Romer, C.D. and D.H. Romer. 2009. The Macroeconomic Effects of Tax Changes: Estimates Based on a New Measure of Fiscal Shocks. American Economic Review, 100(3): 763-801 Rotemberg, Julio J., and Michael Woodford. 1992. Oligopolistic Pricing and the Effects of Aggregate Demand on Economic Activity. Journal of Political Economy, 100(6): 1153 1207. 11