On the investment}uncertainty relationship in a real options model

Similar documents
Optimal timing problems in environmental economics

Valuation of Exit Strategy under Decaying Abandonment Value

On the Real Option Value of Scientific Uncertainty for Public Policies. Justus Wesseler

Agency Cost of Debt Overhang with Optimal Investment Timing and Size

A Bayesian Approach to Real Options:

Impressum ( 5 TMG) Herausgeber: Fakultät für Wirtschaftswissenschaft Der Dekan. Verantwortlich für diese Ausgabe:

WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS. No 449. Pursuing the Wrong Options? Adjustment Costs and the Relationship between Uncertainty and Capital Accumulation

Leaving EMU: a real options perspective

Examining RADR as a Valuation Method in Capital Budgeting

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Internet Appendix to Idiosyncratic Cash Flows and Systematic Risk

Agency Costs of Equity and Accounting Conservatism: A Real Options Approach

The Application of Real Options to Capital Budgeting

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

Equilibrium Asset Returns

A Dynamic Model of Repositioning

Can Borrowing Costs Explain the Consumption Hump?

Aggregate Implications of Lumpy Adjustment

Investment, Capacity Choice and Outsourcing under Uncertainty

Uncertainty and the Dynamics of R&D*

American Option Pricing Formula for Uncertain Financial Market

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate

Chapter 8. Alternative Theories of Endogenous Growth. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

A Note on Competitive Investment under Uncertainty. Robert S. Pindyck. MIT-CEPR WP August 1991

WORKING PAPER. The Option Value of Delay in Health Technology Assessment (2006/06) CENTRE FOR APPLIED ECONOMIC RESEARCH. By S. Eckermann and A.

Annex: Alternative approaches to corporate taxation Ec426 Lecture 8 Taxation and companies 1

Smooth pasting as rate of return equalisation: A note

Mixing Di usion and Jump Processes

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

Real Options and Game Theory in Incomplete Markets

High Volatility Medium Volatility /24/85 12/18/86

An Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model

Combining Real Options and game theory in incomplete markets.

The investment game in incomplete markets.

The stochastic calculus

arxiv: v2 [q-fin.pr] 23 Nov 2017

Documento de Trabajo. ISSN (edición impresa) ISSN (edición electrónica)

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Resolution of a Financial Puzzle

RealOptionsModelswithNon-LinearDynamics

Asset Pricing Theory PhD course at The Einaudi Institute for Economics and Finance

Lookback Options under the CEV Process: a Correction Phelim P. Boyle,Yisong S. Tian and Junichi Imai Abstract Boyle and Tian(1999) developed a trinomi

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Practical example of an Economic Scenario Generator

Mathematics in Finance

Monte Carlo Simulation of Stochastic Processes

An Equilibrium Model of the Term Structure of Interest Rates

SAMPLE STANDARD DEVIATION(s) CHART UNDER THE ASSUMPTION OF MODERATENESS AND ITS PERFORMANCE ANALYSIS

4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs. Math6911 S08, HM Zhu

Walter S.A. Schwaiger. Finance. A{6020 Innsbruck, Universitatsstrae 15. phone: fax:

Taxes and Commuting. David R. Agrawal, University of Kentucky William H. Hoyt, University of Kentucky. Nürnberg Research Seminar

Convertible Subordinated Debt Financing and Optimal Investment Timing

FURTHER ASPECTS OF GAMBLING WITH THE KELLY CRITERION. We consider two aspects of gambling with the Kelly criterion. First, we show that for

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions

CMBS Default: A First Passage Time Approach

The investment game in incomplete markets

Deterministic Income under a Stochastic Interest Rate

The Optimal Timing for the Construction of an International Airport: a Real Options Approach with Multiple Stochastic Factors and Shocks

Dr. Maddah ENMG 625 Financial Eng g II 10/16/06

A neoclassical model of the Phillips curve relation

Growth Options and Optimal Default under Liquidity Constraints: The Role of Corporate Cash Balances

Fee versus royalty licensing in a Cournot duopoly model

Crude Oil Industry Dynamics: A Leader/Follower Game between the OPEC Cartel and Non-OPEC Producers. Jostein Tvedt * DnB Markets, Economic Research

Asset Pricing Theory PhD course The Einaudi Institute for Economics and Finance

Switching mortgages: a real options perspective

The Interest Parity Theory

Central counterparty (CCP) resolution The right move at the right time.

Stock Loan Valuation Under Brownian-Motion Based and Markov Chain Stock Models

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

OPTIMAL TIMING FOR INVESTMENT DECISIONS

Credit Risk and Underlying Asset Risk *

Monetary Fiscal Policy Interactions under Implementable Monetary Policy Rules

Exchange Rate Uncertainty and Optimal Participation in International Trade

ECONOMIC POLICY UNCERTAINTY AND SMALL BUSINESS DECISIONS

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

RISK MANAGEMENT IN PUBLIC-PRIVATE PARTNERSHIP ROAD PROJECTS USING THE REAL OPTIONS THEORY

Prof. Glenn W. Boyle. University of Otago. Graeme A. Guthrie University of Canterbury

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities

Topic 1: Basic Concepts in Finance. Slides

TIØ 1: Financial Engineering in Energy Markets

Markowitz portfolio theory

Incorporating Managerial Cash-Flow Estimates and Risk Aversion to Value Real Options Projects. The Fields Institute for Mathematical Sciences

Derivation Of The Capital Asset Pricing Model Part I - A Single Source Of Uncertainty

Optimal rebalancing of portfolios with transaction costs assuming constant risk aversion

A Re-examination of Economic Growth, Tax Policy, and Distributive Politics

Economic Risk and Decision Analysis for Oil and Gas Industry CE School of Engineering and Technology Asian Institute of Technology

Savings, Investment and the Real Interest Rate in an Endogenous Growth Model

Intertemporally Dependent Preferences and the Volatility of Consumption and Wealth

General Equilibrium Approach to Evaluate Real Option Value of Reserved Environments

Information Processing and Limited Liability

Reservation Rate, Risk and Equilibrium Credit Rationing

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2008

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations

LECTURES ON REAL OPTIONS: PART III SOME APPLICATIONS AND EXTENSIONS

Luca Taschini. 6th Bachelier World Congress Toronto, June 25, 2010

Altering the terms of executive stock options

Optimal Capital Structure, Endogenous Bankruptcy, and the Term Structure of Credit Spreads

Value of Flexibility in Managing R&D Projects Revisited

Transcription:

Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 24 (2000) 219}225 On the investment}uncertainty relationship in a real options model Sudipto Sarkar* Department of Finance, College of Business Administration, University of Houston, Houston, TX 77204-6282, USA Received 1 February 1998; accepted 1 January 1999 Abstract It appears to be widely accepted in the real options literature that an increase in uncertainty should have an inhibiting e!ect on investment. Our article demonstrates that the notion of a negative uncertainty}investment relationship is not always correct. We show that in certain situations, an increase in uncertainty can actually increase the probability of investing, and thereby have a positive impact on investment. 2000 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. JEL classixcation: C6; E2 Keywords: Investment; Uncertainty; Stochastic process 1. Introduction The relationship between uncertainty and investment has been of interest to economists for a long time. The issue has been addressed in various ways in the literature, as discussed by Caballero (1991). This article is limited to one such approach: the `real optionsa approach to investment decisions, pioneered by McDonald and Siegel (1986), Dixit (1989), Pindyck (1988), Dixit and Pindyck (1994), etc. * Now at: Department of Finance, Edwin L. Cox School of Business, Southern Methodist University, P.O. Box 75033, Dallas, TX 75275-0333, USA. 0165-1889/00/$ - see front matter 2000 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. PII: S 0 1 6 5-1 8 8 9 ( 9 9 ) 0 0 0 0 5-6

220 S. Sarkar / Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 24 (2000) 219}225 In this `real optionsa approach, the investment opportunity is viewed as an (American) option to invest, which must be exercised optimally. The exercise policy determines the investment in new projects. This policy is frequently (for an in"nite-horizon setting) of the form: invest if the level of earnings (or NPV of project), say x, exceeds some critical value x*. This critical value x*, of course, depends on the parameters of the economy, particularly important being the level of uncertainty or the volatility of the project being considered. In terms of option theory, the investment rule can be equivalently stated as follows: invest when the value of the project exceeds its cost by an amount equal to the option value of waiting to invest. In the "nancial options literature, it has been shown that a higher level of uncertainty increases option value, and this leads to a more distant critical value for option exercise (for American options). Consistent with this intuition, the real options literature also predicts a negative relationship between uncertainty and investment, since greater uncertainty increases the value of the option to wait. One "nds repeated references to the negative investment}uncertainty relationship in the literature. Some examples are: `2this leads to the important implication that an increase in uncertainty raises the option value and thereby discourages new investmenta (Mauer and Ott, 1995, p. 582); `2the recent literature on irreversible investment has shown that increase in uncertainty lowers investmenta (Caballero, 1991, p. 279); and `2based on previous "ndings by researchers of an inverse relationship between uncertainty and investmenta (Metcalf and Hassett, 1995, p. 1472). Thus the general prediction of the real options literature is that a higher level of uncertainty will have a negative e!ect on investment. In order to gauge the overall e!ect of uncertainty on investment, one can look at the probability that investment will take place (i.e., the critical trigger value will be reached) within a speci"ed time period. An increase (decrease) in this probability implies a positive (negative) e!ect on investment. In this article, therefore, we study the uncertainty}investment relationship by examining the e!ect of higher volatility on this probability measure. 2. The model We use a canonical real options model of investment, along the lines of McDonald and Siegel (1986) or Dixit and Pindyck (1994), (Chapter 5), with two di!erences: (i) the state variable is earnings rather than "rm value, and (ii) systematic risk is explicitly taken into account. The "rm is considering an in"nite-horizon investment project which generates a random net cash #ow (or earnings) stream of $x per unit time. The earnings stream follows the stochastic lognormal process below: dx "μ x dt#σx dz, (1)

S. Sarkar / Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 24 (2000) 219}225 221 where μ is the expected growth rate of the cash #ow stream, σ the standard deviation of the growth rate, and dz the increment of a standard Weiner process. The level of uncertainty of the project (or of the earnings process) is measured by the volatility term σ. The project can be accepted at any time; when it is accepted, the "rm can implement the project instantaneously at a cost of $1 (this is just a normalization; there is no loss of generality in assuming a unit investment cost). The risk-free interest rate is a constant r. The correlation of the project with the market portfolio is ρ (i.e., dz dz "ρ dt), and the market price of risk is λ (de"ned in Merton, 1973). In the above setting, the postponable project can be viewed as an (American) option to invest, which should be exercised optimally, i.e., when exercising the option generates a higher payo! than holding it. The "rm's investment decision is therefore equivalent to an optimal stopping problem: at what point is it optimal to implement the project? Alternatively, what is the optimal exercise policy for the American option to invest? In an in"nite-horizon setting, this translates into some critical value of earnings (say, x*) such that the "rm should implement the project as soon as x reaches or exceeds this critical trigger level. 3. The critical investment trigger With the above speci"cations, it can be shown (proof available from the author on request) that the project value (in capital budgeting terms, the NPV of the project when accepted) is given by Project value" x!1. (2) r#λρσ!μ The value of the option to invest (i.e., value of project prior to acceptance), F(x), follows an ordinary di!erential equation of the form speci"ed in McDonald and Siegel (1986) or Dixit and Pindyck (1994), (Chapter 5). Along with the appropriate boundary conditions (value matching and smooth pasting), the solution is given by (proof available from the author on request): where F(x)"Ax, (3) α" 1 2! μ!λρσ σ # 1 2! μ!λρσ σ # 2r σ (4)

222 S. Sarkar / Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 24 (2000) 219}225 and A" (x*) 1 (r#λρσ!μ) α. (5) In Eq. (5), x* is the optimal stopping boundary; that is, the optimal investment rule is to invest when x rises to x*. The boundary x* is given by: x*" α (r#λρσ!μ). (6) α!1 For the investment decision, the important result is Eq. (6), which gives us a closed-form expression for the optimal or critical investment trigger x*. Intuitively, it is obvious that a higher level of uncertainty will increase the critical trigger level x* (as can be veri"ed by di!erentiating Eq. (6) with respect to σ), and thereby have a negative e!ect on investment. However, there is an additional e!ect of the higher volatility: because of higher volatility, the variable x is now more likely to reach the critical level x*. This is similar to the `realization e!ecta of Metcalf and Hassett (1995), and will have a positive e!ect on investment. Thus, there are two e!ects of higher volatility on investment, one negative and the other positive. To get an idea of the overall e!ect, we examine the probability of investment next. 4. The probability of investing The probability of reaching the critical level x* (i.e., probability of investing) within some time period ¹ is given by (this can be derived from Harrison (1985), (pp. 11}14)) Prob(Inv)"Φ ln(x /x*)#(μ!1/2σ )¹ σ ¹ # x* x Φ ln(x /x*)!(μ!1/2σ )¹ σ ¹, (7) where x is the starting (or time 0) value of x, and Φ(. ) the area under the standard normal distribution. Substituting for x* from Eq. (6), we get Prob(Inv)"Φ ln[x (1!1/α)/(r#λρσ!μ)]#(μ!1/2σ )¹ σ ¹ # r#λρσ!μ x (1!1/α) Φ ln[x (1!1/α)/(r#λρσ!μ)]!(μ!1/2σ )¹ σ ¹. (8)

S. Sarkar / Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 24 (2000) 219}225 223 Eq. (8) gives the probability of investment occurring within time ¹, in terms of the parameters of the economy and the project. A higher (lower) probability implies a greater (smaller) chance of project acceptance, hence a positive (negative) e!ect on investment. Since the sign of the derivative [d(prob)/dσ] cannot be determined unambiguously, it is not clear how a higher σ will a!ect the probability of investing. We therefore have to use numerical results to illustrate the uncertainty}investment relationship. 5. Numerical analysis We start with the following base case parameter values: μ"0, r"10%, ρ"0.7, λ"0.4, x "0.1, and ¹"5 yr. We use μ"0 because we wish to focus on volatility e!ects and not growth e!ects; ρ"0.7 re#ects a project imperfectly (but positively) correlated with the market, which is a good description of the majority of projects; and λ"0.4 is the approximate historical average (see Bodie et al., 1996, p. 185). Note that using a di!erent value of x will result in di!erent Prob(Inv), but will make no di!erence to the relationship between σ and Prob(Inv), which is what we are interested in. With the above parameter values, we computed Prob(Inv) for di!erent values of σ. The results are displayed in Fig. 1. From Fig. 1, we see that the probability of investing is initially an increasing function of volatility, but after a certain point (about σ"0.39 for the base case) it becomes a decreasing function of volatility. Therefore, for low levels of Fig. 1. Probability of investing as a function of volatility. Parameters: μ"0, r"10%, ρ"0.7, λ"0.4, x "0.1, and ¹"5 yr.

224 S. Sarkar / Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 24 (2000) 219}225 uncertainty, an increase in uncertainty increases the probability of investing and thereby has a positive e!ect on the expected rate of investment. With the base case parameters, the direction of the overall e!ect of volatility on investment is thus ambiguous. This result is also robust to the exact choice of parameter values, as was con"rmed by repeating the computations for wide range of parameter values around the base case. This illustrates our main result: An increase in uncertainty might actually speed up investment, contrary to what the literature generally predicts. The e!ects of the various parameters can be summarized as follows: the uncertainty}investment relationship is more likely to be positive when (i) the current level of uncertainty σ is low, (ii) λ is high, (iii) ρ is high, (iv) r is high, (v) μ is low, and (vi) ¹ is short. We also "nd that the trigger x* is always an increasing function of σ, as predicted. To summarize, this article has demonstrated that a higher level of uncertainty might have a positive e!ect on investment (in the sense of increasing the probability of investing), particularly for low-growth and low-risk projects. The economic implication is that more uncertainty is not always bad for investment, because under certain conditions, it can actually increase the probability of investing. For example, in the case of a low-risk low-growth "rm (such as that found in a regulated industry like the utilities sector), a moderate increase in uncertainty might increase the probability of investing, and thus have a positive e!ect on investment. We would like to add a caveat here: what the article has shown is that the probability of investing might be an increasing function of the uncertainty or volatility σ in certain scenarios. However, from this result, it is di$cult to reach a "rm conclusion regarding the e!ect on aggregate investment. Recall that our result was based on a single-project partial-equilibrium model. In order to make any inference regarding the e!ect on aggregate investment, we would have to extend the model to a multi-"rm or industry general equilibrium setting. Not only would this complicate the model enormously (see Cecchetti (1993) for a discussion of these complications), we would also need to incorporate the impact of other factors such as the arrival rate for the projects or characteristics of the "rms in the industry. Moreover, these factors would themselves have to be endogenous in a complete general equilibrium model. Since it is beyond the scope of this paper, we leave the extension of the model to a general equilibrium setting for future research on this topic. Acknowledgements I would like to thank Praveen Kumar, the editor Berc Rustem and two anonymous referees for their comments. I am responsible for any remaining errors.

References S. Sarkar / Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 24 (2000) 219}225 225 Bodie, Z., Kane, A., Marcus, A.J., 1996. Investments. Irwin McGraw-Hill, Boston. Caballero, R.J., 1991. On the sign of the investment}uncertainty relationship. American Economic Review 81, 279}288. Cecchetti, S.G., 1993. Comment on: in#ation uncertainty, relative price uncertainty, and investment in U.S. manufacturing. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 25, 550}554. Dixit, A.K., 1989. Entry and exit decisions under uncertainty. Journal of Political Economy 97, 620}638. Dixit, A.K., Pindyck, R.S., 1994. Investment Under Uncertainty. Princeton University Press, Princeton. Harrison, J.M., 1985. Brownian Motion and Stochastic Flow Systems. Wiley, New York. Mauer, D.C., Ott, S.H., 1995. Investment under uncertainty: the case of replacement investment decisions. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 30, 581}606. McDonald, R., Siegel, D., 1986. The value of waiting to invest. Quarterly Journal of Economics 101, 707}727. Merton, R.C., 1973. An intertemporal capital asset pricing model. Econometrica 41, 867}887. Metcalf, G.E., Hassett, K.A., 1995. Investment under alternative return assumptions: comparing random walks and mean reversion. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 19, 1471}1488. Pindyck, R.S., 1988. Irreversible investment, capacity choice, and the value of the "rm. American Economic Review 78, 969}985.