cahier n Two -part pricing, public discriminating monopoly and redistribution: a note par Philippe Bernard & Jérôme Wittwer Octobre 2001

Similar documents
Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

MONOPOLY (2) Second Degree Price Discrimination

Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics

Chapter 3 Introduction to the General Equilibrium and to Welfare Economics

Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction. By: Stephen P. Holland

A simple proof of the efficiency of the poll tax

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

1 Two Period Exchange Economy

Transport Costs and North-South Trade

Economics 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Final Exam Suggested Solutions

The Probationary Period as a Screening Device: The Monopolistic Insurer

Problem Set 2. Theory of Banking - Academic Year Maria Bachelet March 2, 2017

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DIRECT OR INDIRECT TAX INSTRUMENTS FOR REDISTRIBUTION: SHORT-RUN VERSUS LONG-RUN. Emmanuel Saez

Answers to June 11, 2012 Microeconomics Prelim

Fiscal policy and minimum wage for redistribution: an equivalence result. Abstract

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Loss-leader pricing and upgrades

1 Appendix A: Definition of equilibrium

Theoretical Tools of Public Finance. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

Citation Economic Modelling, 2014, v. 36, p

Microeconomic Theory August 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #9 - Monopoly

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

Lecture 5. Varian, Ch. 8; MWG, Chs. 3.E, 3.G, and 3.H. 1 Summary of Lectures 1, 2, and 3: Production theory and duality

Was The New Deal Contractionary? Appendix C:Proofs of Propositions (not intended for publication)

Comparative statics of monopoly pricing

Class Notes on Chaney (2008)

Trade Agreements and the Nature of Price Determination

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 3

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

Chapter 2 Equilibrium and Efficiency

License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

Choice. A. Optimal choice 1. move along the budget line until preferred set doesn t cross the budget set. Figure 5.1.

Price Theory of Two-Sided Markets

Payment card interchange fees and price discrimination

The Robinson Crusoe model; the Edgeworth Box in Consumption and Factor allocation

A note on strategic piracy in the economics of software: an explanation by learning costs

Econ205 Intermediate Microeconomics with Calculus Chapter 1

What Industry Should We Privatize?: Mixed Oligopoly and Externality

Bank Leverage and Social Welfare

2. A DIAGRAMMATIC APPROACH TO THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF PUBLIC INPUTS

JEFF MACKIE-MASON. x is a random variable with prior distrib known to both principal and agent, and the distribution depends on agent effort e

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 3

Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium

Social Optimality in the Two-Party Case

Answer Key. q C. Firm i s profit-maximization problem (PMP) is given by. }{{} i + γ(a q i q j c)q Firm j s profit

Public Schemes for Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets

Hedonic Equilibrium. December 1, 2011

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay

On supply function competition in a mixed oligopoly

Omar O. Chisari (UADE and CONICET)

Chapter 1: Monopoly II

FISCAL FEDERALISM WITH A SINGLE INSTRUMENT TO FINANCE GOVERNMENT. Carlos Maravall Rodríguez 1

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Midterm Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy

On Forchheimer s Model of Dominant Firm Price Leadership

Lectures on Externalities

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 7: Optimal Top Income Taxation

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

On the use of leverage caps in bank regulation

Does Retailer Power Lead to Exclusion?

5. COMPETITIVE MARKETS

VERTICAL RELATIONS AND DOWNSTREAM MARKET POWER by. Ioannis Pinopoulos 1. May, 2015 (PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE) Abstract

CEREC, Facultés universitaires Saint Louis. Abstract

Comments on social insurance and the optimum piecewise linear income tax

MS&E HW #1 Solutions

Revenue Equivalence and Income Taxation

Uncertainty in Equilibrium

Characterization of the Optimum

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #7 - Competitive Markets

Emission Permits Trading Across Imperfectly Competitive Product Markets

Problem Set: Contract Theory

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Introductory to Microeconomic Theory [08/29/12] Karen Tsai

Endogenous choice of decision variables

A Two-Dimensional Dual Presentation of Bond Market: A Geometric Analysis

ECON Micro Foundations

USO cost allocation rules and welfare

On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation

GS/ECON 5010 section B Answers to Assignment 3 November 2012

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2015

Firm s Problem. Simon Board. This Version: September 20, 2009 First Version: December, 2009.

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay

THE BOADWAY PARADOX REVISITED

The objectives of the producer

Working Paper Series. This paper can be downloaded without charge from:

Online Appendix. Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing

Econ 230B Spring FINAL EXAM: Solutions

Graduate Microeconomics II Lecture 7: Moral Hazard. Patrick Legros

Optimal Labor Contracts with Asymmetric Information and More than Two Types of Agent

Microeconomics 2nd Period Exam Solution Topics

DISCUSSION PAPERS IN ECONOMICS

Problem Set: Contract Theory

The Timing of Endogenous Wage Setting under Bertrand Competition in a Unionized Mixed Duopoly

International Trade

Supplement to the lecture on the Diamond-Dybvig model

Transcription:

cahier n 2001-06 Two -part pricing, public discriminating monopoly and redistribution: a note par Philippe Bernard & Jérôme Wittwer EURIsCO Université Paris Dauphine Octobre 2001 LEO Univérsité d Orléans EURIsCO, Université Paris Dauphine email: eurisco@dauphine.fr, site web: http://www.dauphine.fr/eurisco/

Two-part pricing, public discriminating monopoly and redistribution : a note Philippe Bernard EURIsCO Université Paris IX Jérôme Wittwer LEO Université d Orléans Octobre 2001 We are grateful to two anonymous referees for careful comments that significantly improved the exposition in the paper. Seminar audiences have also been most helpful.

Résumé This note analyzes some properties of optional two-part pricing in a two type economy. First, the optimal contracts along the Paretian frontier are described. Then, the duality relation between the Rawlsian program and the discriminating monopoly is demonstrated. Last, this property is used to build a mutualist mechanism implementing the constrained Pareto optima. Classification J.E.L. : D42, D61, D63

1 Introduction Optional two-part pricing, extensively used by many public utilities (electricity, water, railways...), gives, as shown by Sharkey and Sibley (1993)[4], some freedom to redistribute the social surplus. 1 These authors show in a partial equilibrium framework that, when a monopoly proposes a menu of contracts, each specifying the fee and the charge price, it is possible for a social planner controlling this monopoly to redistribute towards the weak demand consumer. Our contribution is not to extend their study to a new framework or to other pricings. Our ambition is, first, to emphasize the redistributive mechanism of optional two-part pricing, notably with the help of some graphical presentations, and, second, to propose a simple incentive mechanism implementing the more redistributive optima. As we will see, this mechanism takes advantage of the dual relationship between the program of the discriminating monopoly and the social planner s program. This note is organized as follows. The economy is described in section 2. The constrained Pareto optima are characterized in section 3 even though an implementing mechanism is proposed and studied in section 4. Limits and possible extensions of this work are discussed in the last section. 2 The economy There are two goods, the produced good and the numéraire one. Their quantities are respectively noted q and w. The economy is composed of two types of agents, indexed i =1, 2, defined by their quasi-linear utility functions: u i (q i,w i )=V i (q i )+w i The functions V i verify the following properties : Assumption 1 V i is continuously twice differentiable with : and : V 0 i (q) := V i (q) q > 0, Vi 00 (q) := 2 V i (q) < 0, V q 2 i (0) = 0 (1) V 0 2 (q) >V 0 1 (q) (2) 1 See also Roberts (1979) [3] for the case of non-linear pricing. 1

Relations (1) state that the inverse demand is positive and strictly decreasing. Relation (2) implies that type 2 s demand is higher than type 1 s; for quasi-linear utility functions this relation is also the standard single crossing assumption. The cost function C of the monopoly which produces the good q verifies the following assumption : Assumption 2 C is a convex function on ]0, + [ 2 : C 0 (q) 0, C 00 (q) 0 (3) The monopoly using this technology proposes two contracts (p 1,E 1 ) and (p 2,E 2 ),wherep 1, p 2 are the usage charges, E 1 and E 2 the fees. As asymmetric information prevents perfect discrimination, the contracts must be incentive-compatible. Moreover, in order to eliminate trivial cases, we will suppose that First-best optima are characterized by strictly positive consumptions. 3 Constrained Pareto optima In this section, the constraints regimes of the Paretian program are specified. Then, the Pareto frontier is outlined and the main properties of optimal contracts are discussed. This section doesn t propose any new results, its aim is simply to clarify the characterization of the Pareto frontier and above all to present, with the help of a graphic, a pedagogical analysis of the redistributive mechanism of the optional two-part pricing. In our economy, the constrained Pareto program is : P p (s 2 ): max (pi,e i ) i=1,2 S 1 (p 1 ) E 1 s.t. : (SC 2 ):S 2 (p 2 ) E 2 s 2 (IC i ):S i (p i ) E i S i (p j ) E j,i,j=1, 2 (B) : P i=1,2 n i [p i D i (p i )+E i ]=C(D (p 1,p 2 )) where D i (p i )=V 0 1 i (p i ), S i (p i )=V i (D i (p i )) p i D i (p i ), s i = S i (p i ) E i, D(p 1,p 2 )=n 1 D 1 (p 1 )+n 2 D 2 (p 2 ) and n i is the number of agents of type i. To discuss the constraints regimes of P p (s 2 ), it is useful to consider the first-best optima which verify the incentive constraints. Actually, as for every first-best optimum, prices are equal to the marginal cost, incentive constraints 2 Fixed costs are thus allowed. 2

require equality of fees. Hence, there is a unique first-best optimum which verify the incentive constraints, the so-called Coase two-part pricing. The types surplus at the Coase solution are noted s co 1 and s co 2. 3 In the following, only the domain s 2 <s co 2 is studied 4. In this domain the binding incentive constraint is (IC 2 ). 5 To know if (SC 2 ) binds, it is useful to introduce the Rawlsian solution defined by the maximization of the type 1 surplus subject to incentive and budget constraints. As these constraints always bind, the Rawlsian objective function, after some substitutions, can be rewritten: W R (p 1,p 2 ):= 1 n 1 + n 2 (S s (p 1,p 2 ) n 2 (S 2 (p 1 ) S 1 (p 1 ))) (4) where the social surplus S s (p 1,p 2 )= P i n i V i (D i (p i )) C (D (p 1,p 2 )). As usual in this literature, we assume the concavity of this function, and hence the unicity of the Rawlsian solution ³ p R 1,p R 2. Ifs R i is the surplus of type i at this Rawlsian optimum 6, two cases must be distinguished depending on whether s 2 is above or below s R 2.Fors R 2 s 2 <s co 2 7, the constrained Pareto program is equivalent to maximize W R (p 1,p 2 ) subject to (SC 2 ).The (assumed) strict concavity of W R implies two results. First, (SC 2 ) is binding, second, the second-best frontier, in the surplus space (s 1,s 2 ), is continuous and strictly monotonic (see figure 1). The remaining question is what are the properties of the optimal contracts along the second-best frontier. As,fors R 2 s 2 <s co 2,onlyincentiveand participation contraints of type 2 bind, the program P p (s 2 ) is reduced to the following : P pr (s 2 ): max p1,p 2 1 n 1 +n 2 [S s (p 1,p 2 ) n 2 (S 2 (p 1 ) S 1 (p 1 ))] s.c : (SC 2 ): P i=1,2 n i V i (D i (p i )) = C (D (p 1,p 2 )) n 1 (S 2 (p 1 ) S 1 (p 1 )) + (n 1 + n 2 ).s 2 3 Of course, the Coase solution only exists if the fixed cost is not too big with respect to the demand. 4 The other case is symmetrical. To extend our results to the domain s 2 >s co 2, one only needs to rewrite program P p (s 2 ) by permuting indices, i.e. one needs to maximize s 2 subject to the participation constraint of type 1. 5 The space being limited here and the proof being classical, it is not reproduced in this note. 6 As by assumption s co 1 is strictly positive, s R 1 > 0. Then, from (IC 2 ) and eq. (2), itcan be shown that s R 2 >s R 1 > 0. 7 Of course, for s 2 <s R 2,ass R 2 is the lower value that the Paretian social planner can actually assign to type 2, (SC 2 ) of program P p (s 2 ) is always released. 3

s2 Second Best frontier Coase solution Rawlsian solution First Best frontier 45 s1 Figure~1: The frontier of the constrained Pareto optima with optional twopart pricing For each s 2, first-order conditions give optimal prices: p 2 = C 0 (D(p 1,p 2 )) (5) p 1 = (1+λ)C 0 (D(p 1,p 2 )) λrm 1 (D 1 (p 1 )) + n 2 + n 1 D1 0 (p 1 ) (D 2 (p 1 ) D 1 (p 1 )) λ D 0 1 (p 1 ) D 2 (p 1 ) (6) where Rm 1 (q 1 )=V1(q 0 1 )+q 1 V1 00 (q 1 ) is the marginal revenue upon type 1 and λ the Lagrangian multiplier. 8 8 Equation (6) can be rewrited as follows : p 1 = C 0 (D (p 1,p 2 )) + n 2 λn 1 1+λ D 1 (p 1 ) D 2 (p 1 ) n 1 D 0 1 (p 1) We note that for λ = n 2 /n 1, we obtain the Coasian prices : p 1 = p 2 = C 0 (D (p 1,p 2 )). Otherwise, one could show that for λ =0, p 2 = p R 2. So, intuitively, we could interpret λ as a relative weight of type 2 in a linear social welfare function; but, this interpretation assumes the concavity of the Pareto frontier (in the surplus space). 4

T E'' + p1.q D d 2 E' + c.q E + c.q s2' F B s2 d 1 C A s1 q1 q2 q Figure~2: Starting from the Coasian equilibrium (A and B), the raise of p 1 permits to decrease s 2 (with s 1 constant) in the space (q, T), wheret is the total spending. Equation (5) reflects the fact that p 2 is not an incentive tool when one tries to increase the type 1 surplus above its Coasian level 9. Secondly, we can easily prove that p 1 >C 0.Indeed,eitherRm 1 >C 0,orRm 1 C 0 : in the first case, we have of course p 1 >C 0,and,ifRm 1 C 0,equation(6) implies that p 1 >C 0. Furthermore, after some manipulation, the differentiation of (IC 2 ) gives : ds 1 1=(D 2 (p 1 ) D 1 (p 1 )) dp 1 (7) ds 2 ds 2 Along the constrained Pareto frontier (for s R 2 < s 2 <s co 2 ), ds 1 /ds 2 < 0, one gets from equation (7) : dp 1 /ds 2 < 0. Hence,toraises 1, the social planner must decrease s 2, i.e. increase p 1. The intuition of this result can be grasped graphically. In figure 2, the Coasian equilibrium is depicted by points A and B in the space (q, T) where T is the total spending of each type. The upward line passing through these points is the nil profit line; it is also the spending line 9 This is a well-known result of adverse selection models with Spence-Mirrlees assumption (relation (2) of assumption 1). In a similar framework with n types of agents, Sharkey and Sibley (1993) [4] proves the same result. 5

of each type when the fee is E and the price equal to the marginal cost c 10. The curves passing through A and B are the iso-surplus curves corresponding respectively to types 1 and 2. At the Coase optimum, and in fact at each constrained Pareto optimum, the only way to increase s 1 is obviously to decrease s 2. Nevertheless, for this, one needs to release the incentive constraint of type 2, i.e. to decrease the surplus of the dishonest type 2. Starting from the Coasian point A, the only way to proceed is to raise p 1 (with an appropriate adjustment of E 1 leaving s 1 constant) 11. As the surplus of the dishonest type 2, reached at point F, is now only s 0 2 (< s 2 ), the social planner can extract at most dπ 2 with the new contract (E 0,c). As we can see in figure 2, the increase of budget surplus dπ 2 over type 2 exceeds the budget loss dπ 1 over type 1. 12 So, starting from the Coase equilibrium, such an adjustment leaves a positive net budget surplus which, equally redistributed to check incentive constraints, increases type 1 s surplus 13. Since it permits more redistributive surplus allocation than the Coase solution,optionaltwo-partpricingisausefultoolforthesocialplanner.but, if he doesn t directly control the monopoly, implementation of the constrained optima is questionable : how can he induce the monopoly to select the right two-part pricing? 4 Implementation by discriminating monopoly In this section we build mechanisms which implement the more redistributive optima. To reach this aim we study a regulated monopoly, the so-called monopoly àlaedgeworth. 14 This monopoly is supposed to use optional twopart pricing and is subject to an additional constraint to leave a minimal surplus to type 1. The implementing mechanisms are then deduced from the duality relation between the discriminating program of this monopoly and the Rawlsian program; this duality relation was incidentally noticed by Roberts (1979) ([3], p. 80-81) in a continuous types economy but for a non linear pricing. 10 For simplicity, we supposed in this graphic that the marginal cost is constant. 11 Indeed, it is easy to see that a decrease of p 1 (leaving s 1 constant) incites type 2 to lie, increases s 2, and breaks the budget constraint. 12 In fact, at first order, dπ 1 is negligeable which is not the case of dπ 2. 13 Those adjustments can be reproduced for all constrained Pareto optima but the Rawlsian one. 14 This solution deserves to be called monopoly à la Edgeworth with reference to Edgeworth s contributions to the regulated monopoly literature (e.g. Edgeworth (1910) [2]). 6

Before introducing the monopoly àlaedgeworth, let us first introduce the program of the simple discriminating monopoly using optional two-part pricing : P m : max (pi,e i ) i=1,2 Pi=1,2 n i (p i D i (p i )+E i ) C(D (p 1,p 2 )) s.t. : (PC i ):S i (p i ) E i 0, i=1, 2 (IC i ):S i (p i ) E i S i (p j ) E j,i,j=1, 2 and begin to show that the Rawlsian prices are also the monopolistic ones. Proposition 1 The Rawlsian prices ³ p R 1,p R 2 are the solutions of the monopoly program. Proof. Under assumption 1, (IC 2 ) and (PC 1 ) are the only active constraints and one gets : E 1 = S 1 (p 1 ),E 2 = S 1 (p 1 )+(S 2 (p 2 ) S 2 (p 1 )) Hence, after substitutions, the objective function becomes : Π (p 1,p 2 ) = X n i.v i (D i (p i )) C (D (p 1,p 2 )) n 2 (S 2 (p 1 ) S 1 (p 1 )) i=1,2 = (n 1 + n 2 ).W R (p 1,p 2 ) Theendoftheproofisnowobvious. Consequently, the monopoly equilibrium and the Rawlsian solution differ only by E 1 and E 2. In fact, this result hides a fundamental link between them: they are the two polar solutions of the monopoly àlaedgeworth. The latter is a discriminating monopoly with an additional surplus constraint for type 1 : P em (s 1 ): max (pi,e i ) i=1,2 Pi=1,2 n i (p i D i (p i )+E i ) C(D(p 1,p 2 )) s.t. : (SC 1 ):S 1 (p 1 ) E 1 s 1 (PC 2 ):S 2 (p 2 ) E 2 0 (IC i ):S i (p i ) E i S i (p j ) E j,i,j=1, 2 As one can easily demonstrate using classical arguments, equation 2 of assumption 1 implies that (SC 1 ) and (IC 2 ) are the only binding constraints. After manipulations, the program P em (s 1 ) is reduced to the subsequent free maximization : max p 1,p 2 (n 1 + n 2 )[W R (p 1,p 2 ) s 1 ] 7

Optimal prices and quantities are independent of s 1 level and equal to the monopoly ones. By raising s 1 (from 0 to s R 1 ), all surplus distributions between the monopoly equilibrium and the Rawlsian solution can be achieved. Actually, for s 1 = s R 1, the program of the monopoly à la Edgeworth is the dual of the Rawlsian program. So, naturally, it gives not only the same prices but also the same fees. Of course, the monopoly à la Edgeworth is an abstract mechanism since s 1 is exogenous. A way to make the mechanism more realistic is to consider a mutualist mechanism, i.e. aprofit sharing device. In our framework, one can view a mutualist monopoly as a firm which redistributes all its profit to its members 15 according to a sharing key. If this key is contingent upon the chosen contracts, membership guarantees a part of the profit evenifthemember doesn t consume. Furthermore, we will suppose that this sharing key is fixed ex ante and the profits are redistributed ex post. The mutualist monopoly s customers are thus considered just as shareholders. Therefore, it is natural to suppose that the aim of the mutualist monopoly is to maximize profit. Finally, for a sharing key ³ θ 1, θ 2, θ the program of this monopoly is then : ³ p mu θ1, θ 2, θ : max (pi,e i ) i=1,2 Pi=1,2 n i (p i D i (p i )+E i ) C(D(p 1,p 2 )) s.t. : (PC 1 ):S 1 (p 1 ) E 1 + θ 1 Π θπ (PC 2 ):S 2 (p 2 ) E 2 + θ 2 Π θπ (IC i ):S i (p i ) E i + θ i Π S i (p j ) E j + θ j Π,i,j=1, 2 where θπ is the guarantee share profit andθ i Π is the profit shareoftypei. Proposition 2 If the monopoly profit is uniformly distributed, θ 1 = θ 2 = θ, the mutualist monopoly equilibrium gives the Rawlsian surplus to each type. Proof. With the uniform sharing key, the program is reduced to the program P m. So the optimal quantities and fees are the Rawlsian ones. The intuition of the previous proposition can be easily grasped graphically (see figure 3). Points A and B correspond to the private monopoly equilibrium (where s 1 =0) 16. Because of the quasi-linearity of preferences, a uniform monetary transfer (to both types) implies a vertical translation of the Edgeworthian monopoly equilibrium : when a surplus s 1 is granted to type 1, the private equilibrium is translated to the new equilibrium represented by A 0 and B 0. 15 If the good produced is a public utility, all agents are potential consumers and can be viewed as members of the mutualist monopoly. 16 As it is depicted, a further rise of p 1 doesn t increase the net profit (0 <dπ 2 = dπ 1 ). 8

T d 2 =- d 1 D B s2 s1 = 0 // d 1 A C // B' _ s2 + s1 _ s1 = s1 A' q1 q2 q Figure~3: The equilibrium of the monopoly à la Edgeworth (in the constant marginal cost case) and its translation. Furthermore, the previous mechanism suggests its extension to the set of constrained Pareto optima with s R 2 < s 2 s co 2. Proposition 3 For every s 2,withs R 2 < s 2 s co 2,thereexistsapricecap p such that the mutualist discriminating monopoly mechanism implements quantities and prices of the constrained Pareto optimum corresponding to s 2. Proof. With the price cap p, the monopoly program becomes : P mpc (p) : max (pi,e i ) i=1,2 Pi=1,2 n i (p i D i (p i )+E i ) C(D(p 1,p 2 )) s.t. : (PC i ):S i (p i ) E i 0, i=1, 2 (IC i ):S i (p i ) E i S i (p j ) E j,i,j=1, 2 (PCC i ):p i p, i, j =1, 2 Assumption 1 always implies that (IC 1 ) and (IC 2 ) can t be both binding. As (PC 2 ) is released, (IC 2 ) must bind, and (IC 1 ) is then loosened. So, (PC 1 ) 9

is active and the program P mpc (p) is reduced to : P mpc (p) : max p1,p 2 S s (p 1,p 2 ) n 2 (S 2 (p 1 ) S 1 (p 1 )) s.t. : (PCC i ):p i p, i =1, 2 For right values of p (p co 1 p p R 1 ), this program implies, for every value of p 1, p 2 = C 0. And by strict concavity, p 1 = p. Toimplementconstrained Pareto optima (in quantities and prices) for s R 2 < s 2 s co 2,itissufficient to set p = p p 1 (s 2 ),wherep p 1 (s 2 ) is the optimal price p 1 of program P p (s 2 ). 17 5 Conclusion This note explores the redistributive properties of optional two-part pricing in a two type economy. It shows that a monopolistic structure market augmented by a uniform profit sharingallowsonetoimplementthemostredistributive optimum, the Rawlsian solution. If a price-cap is added, this mutualist mechanism allows one to achieve less redistributive constrained optima. However, there are three caveats to bear in mind. First, in a pure mutualist mechanism, only customers share profit, even though, in the proposed mechanism, each agent receives profit independently of his consumption decision. However, as here each agent is a customer, the difference is blurred. So, this mechanism can only be applied to a subset of quasi-universally consumed goods, such as electricity, water, public transport. Second, the efficiency of this mechanism requires of course the social plannertohavesuchpreciseinformationastopreventmanagersandemployees from capturing profits. So, the mechanism supposes a strict monitoring of the managers. Last, a strong implicit assumption of this paper is the fact that the social planner has a unique redistribution tool : public pricing. Of course, in a more general framework he can also use income taxation. So, a natural extension would be to study the complementarity between discriminating public pricing and income taxation. 18 Références [1] R. Boadway and M. Marchand, (1995). The use of public expenditures for redistributive purposes. Oxford Economic Papers, 47: 45 59, 1995. 17 To understand that the optimal price p 1 of program P p (s 2 ) is a function of s 2,itis useful to notice that the equation (8) implicitly depends of s 2 (through λ). 18 See for example Boadway and Marchand (1995) [1]. 10

[2] F.Y. Edgeworth, (1910). Applications of probabilities to economics. In F.Y. Edgeworth (1925), editor, Papers Relating to Political Economy, pages 387 428. Burt Franklin, New York, 1970. 2nd edition, initially published in 1910. [3] K. Roberts, (1979). Welfare considerations of non-linear pricing. Economic Journal, 89: 66 83, 1979. [4] W. Sharkey and D. Sibley, (1993). Optimal non-linear pricing with regulatory preference over customer type. Journal of Public Economics, 50: 197 229, 1993. 11