Completeness and Hedging. Tomas Björk

Similar documents
VII. Incomplete Markets. Tomas Björk

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

last problem outlines how the Black Scholes PDE (and its derivation) may be modified to account for the payment of stock dividends.

4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs. Math6911 S08, HM Zhu

Bluff Your Way Through Black-Scholes

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

CHAPTER 12. Hedging. hedging strategy = replicating strategy. Question : How to find a hedging strategy? In other words, for an attainable contingent

Math 181 Lecture 15 Hedging and the Greeks (Chap. 14, Hull)

Hedging. MATH 472 Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan

FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008

TEACHING NOTE 98-04: EXCHANGE OPTION PRICING

SYSM 6304: Risk and Decision Analysis Lecture 6: Pricing and Hedging Financial Derivatives

The Black-Scholes Model

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

Derivative Securities Fall 2012 Final Exam Guidance Extended version includes full semester

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

Advanced Corporate Finance. 5. Options (a refresher)

KØBENHAVNS UNIVERSITET (Blok 2, 2011/2012) Naturvidenskabelig kandidateksamen Continuous time finance (FinKont) TIME ALLOWED : 3 hours

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models

Option Pricing. 1 Introduction. Mrinal K. Ghosh

The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

P&L Attribution and Risk Management

Lecture 18. More on option pricing. Lecture 18 1 / 21

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

non linear Payoffs Markus K. Brunnermeier

Change of Measure (Cameron-Martin-Girsanov Theorem)

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Calibration Lecture 4: LSV and Model Uncertainty

MATH 476/567 ACTUARIAL RISK THEORY FALL 2016 PROFESSOR WANG. Homework 3 Solution

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging

Mathematics of Finance Final Preparation December 19. To be thoroughly prepared for the final exam, you should

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

Youngrok Lee and Jaesung Lee

Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation

BIRKBECK (University of London) MSc EXAMINATION FOR INTERNAL STUDENTS MSc FINANCIAL ENGINEERING DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, MATHEMATICS AND STATIS- TICS

Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options

AN ANALYTICALLY TRACTABLE UNCERTAIN VOLATILITY MODEL

Derivative Securities Section 9 Fall 2004 Notes by Robert V. Kohn, Courant Institute of Mathematical Sciences.

Greek parameters of nonlinear Black-Scholes equation

Lecture Notes for Chapter 6. 1 Prototype model: a one-step binomial tree

FE610 Stochastic Calculus for Financial Engineers. Stevens Institute of Technology

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Mathematics of Financial Derivatives

International Mathematical Forum, Vol. 6, 2011, no. 5, Option on a CPPI. Marcos Escobar

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model

Option Pricing Models for European Options

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

Lecture 11: Ito Calculus. Tuesday, October 23, 12

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 6

Risk Neutral Measures

The Black-Scholes Equation

Stochastic Volatility

THE BLACK-SCHOLES FORMULA AND THE GREEK PARAMETERS FOR A NONLINEAR BLACK-SCHOLES EQUATION

A Brief Review of Derivatives Pricing & Hedging

Options Markets: Introduction

Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1)

A Worst-Case Approach to Option Pricing in Crash-Threatened Markets

Homework Assignments

Incorporating Managerial Cash-Flow Estimates and Risk Aversion to Value Real Options Projects. The Fields Institute for Mathematical Sciences

Options. An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan. J. Robert Buchanan Options

Mathematics in Finance

Practical Hedging: From Theory to Practice. OSU Financial Mathematics Seminar May 5, 2008

************* with µ, σ, and r all constant. We are also interested in more sophisticated models, such as:

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

Replication strategies of derivatives under proportional transaction costs - An extension to the Boyle and Vorst model.

PAijpam.eu ANALYTIC SOLUTION OF A NONLINEAR BLACK-SCHOLES EQUATION

Math489/889 Stochastic Processes and Advanced Mathematical Finance Solutions to Practice Problems

Option Pricing. Simple Arbitrage Relations. Payoffs to Call and Put Options. Black-Scholes Model. Put-Call Parity. Implied Volatility

Pricing Barrier Options under Local Volatility

2 f. f t S 2. Delta measures the sensitivityof the portfolio value to changes in the price of the underlying

Barrier options. In options only come into being if S t reaches B for some 0 t T, at which point they become an ordinary option.

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

K = 1 = -1. = 0 C P = 0 0 K Asset Price (S) 0 K Asset Price (S) Out of $ In the $ - In the $ Out of the $

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Chapter 9 - Mechanics of Options Markets

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES

Black-Scholes-Merton Model

Definition Pricing Risk management Second generation barrier options. Barrier Options. Arfima Financial Solutions

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Derivative Securities

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

Basic Concepts in Mathematical Finance

Simple Robust Hedging with Nearby Contracts

ON AN IMPLEMENTATION OF BLACK SCHOLES MODEL FOR ESTIMATION OF CALL- AND PUT-OPTION VIA PROGRAMMING ENVIRONMENT MATHEMATICA

FINANCIAL PRICING MODELS

Advanced Stochastic Processes.

Financial Derivatives Section 5

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Valuation of Equity Derivatives

The Uncertain Volatility Model

On Using Shadow Prices in Portfolio optimization with Transaction Costs

Transcription:

IV Completeness and Hedging Tomas Björk 1

Problems around Standard Black-Scholes We assumed that the derivative was traded. How do we price OTC products? Why is the option price independent of the expected rate of return α of the underlying stock? Suppose that we have sold a call option. Then we face financial risk, so how do we hedge against that risk? All this has to do with completeness. 2

Definition: We say that a T -claim X can be replicated, alternatively that it is reachable or hedgeable, if there exists a self financing portfolio h such that V h (T )=X, P a.s. In this case we say that h is a hedge against X. Alternatively, h is called a replicating or hedging portfolio. If every contingent claim is reachable we say that the market is complete Basic Idea: If X can be replicated by a portfolio h then the arbitrage free price for X is given by Π [t; X] = V h (t). 3

Trading Strategy Consider a replicable claim X which we want to sell at t = 0.. Compute the price Π [0; X] and sell X at a slightly (well) higher price. Buy the hedging portfolio and invest the surplus in the bank. Wait until expiration date T. The liabilities stemming from X is exactly matched by V h (T ), and we have our surplus in the bank. 4

Completeness of Black-Scholes Theorem: The Black-Scholes model is complete. Proof. Fix a claim X =Φ(S(T )). We want to find processes V, u 0 and u such that { dv = V u 0dB } B + u ds S i.e. V (T ) = Φ(S(T )). dv = V { u 0 r + u α } dt + Vu σdw, V (T ) = Φ(S(T )). 5

Heuristics: Let us assume that X is replicated by h = (u 0,u ) with value process V. Ansatz: V (t) =F (t, S(t)) Ito gives us dv = {F t + αsf s + 12 } σ2 S 2 F ss dt + σsf s dw, Write this as dv = V F t + αsf s + 1 2 σ2 S 2 F ss V dt+v SF s V σdw. Compare with dv = V { u 0 r + u α } dt + Vu σdw 6

Define u by u (t) = S(t)F s(t, S(t)), F (t, S(t)) This gives us the eqn dv = V F t + 1 2 σ2 S 2 F ss r + u α rf dt + Vu σdw. Compare with dv = V { u 0 r + u α } dt + Vu σdw Natural choice for u 0 is given by u 0 = F t + 1 2 σ2 S 2 F ss, rf 7

The relation u 0 + u = 1 gives us the Black- Scholes PDE F t + rsf s + 1 2 σ2 S 2 F ss rf =0. The condition V (T )=Φ(S(T)) gives us the boundary condition F (T,s)=Φ(s) Moral: The model is complete and we have explicit formulas for the replicating portfolio. 8

Main Result Theorem: Define F as the solution to the boundary value problem F t + rsf s + 1 2 σ2 s 2 F ss rf = 0, F (T,s) = Φ(s). Then X can be replicated by the relative portfolio u 0 (t) = F (t, S(t)) S(t)F s(t, S(t)), F (t, S(t)) u (t) = S(t)F s(t, S(t)). F (t, S(t)) The corresponding absolute portfolio is given by h 0 (t) = F (t, S(t)) S(t)F s(t, S(t)), B(t) h (t) = F s (t, S(t)), and the value process V h is given by V h (t) =F (t, S(t)). 9

Notes Completeness explains unique price - the claim is superfluous! Replicating the claim P a.s. Replicating the claim Q a.s. for any Q P. Thus the price only depends on the support of P. Thus (Girsanov) it will not depend on the drift α of the state equation. The completeness theorem is a nice theoretical result, but the replicating portfolio is continuously rebalanced. Thus we are facing very high transaction costs. 10

Completeness vs No Arbitrage Question: When is a model arbitrage free and/or complete? Answer: Count the number of risky assets, and the number of random sources. R = number of random sources N = number of risky assets Intuition: If N is large, compared to R, you have lots of possibilities of forming clever portfolios. Thus lots of chances of making arbitrage profits. Also many chances of replicating a given claim. 11

Meta-Theorem Generically, the following hold. The market is arbitrage free if and only if N R The market is complete if and only if N R Example: The Black-Scholes model. R=N=1. Arbitrage free and complete. 12

Parity Relations Let Φ and Ψ be contract functions for the T - claims X =Φ(S(T )) and Y =Ψ(S(T )). Then for any real numbers α and β we have the following price relation. Π [t; αφ+βψ] = απ [t;φ] + βπ [t;ψ]. Proof. Linearity of mathematical expectation. Consider the following basic contract functions. Prices: Φ S (x) = x, Φ B (x) 1, Φ C,K (x) = max [x K, 0]. Π [t;φ S ] = S(t), Π [t;φ B = e r(t t), Π [ ] t;φ C,K = c(t, S(t); K, T ). 13

If we have then Φ=αΦ S + βφ B + n i=1 γ i Φ C,Ki, Π [t;φ] = απ [t;φ S ]+βπ [t;φ B ]+ n i=1 γ i Π [ t;φ C,Ki ] We may replicate the claim Φ using a portfolio consisting of basic contracts that is constant over time, i.e. a buy-and hold portfolio: α shares of the underlying stock, β zero coupon T -bonds with face value $1, γ i European call options with strike price K i, all maturing at T. 14

Put-Call Parity Consider a European put contract Φ P,K (s) = max [K s, 0] It is easy to see (draw a figure) that Φ P,K (x) = Φ C,K (x) s + K = Φ P,K (x) Φ S (x)+φ B (x) We immediately get Put-call parity: r(t t) p(t, s; K) =c(t, s; K) s + Ke Thus you can construct a synthetic put option, using a buy-and-hold portfolio. 15

Delta Hedging Consider a fixed claim X =Φ(S T ) with pricing function F (t, s). Setup: We are at time t, and have a short (interpret!) position in the contract. Goal: Offset the risk in the derivative by buying (or selling) the (highly correlated) underlying. Definition: A position in the underlying is a delta hedge against the derivative if the portfolio (underlying + derivative) is immune against small changes in the underlying price. 16

Formal Analysis 1 = number of units of the derivative product x = number of units of the underlying s = today s stock price t = today s date Value of the portfolio: V = 1 F (t, s)+x s A delta hedge is characterized by the property that V s =0. We obtain F s + x =0 Solve for x! 17

Result: We should have ˆx = F s shares of the underlying in the delta hedged portfolio. Definition: For any contract, its delta is defined by Result: We should have = F s. ˆx = shares of the underlying in the delta hedged portfolio. Warning: The delta hedge must be rebalanced over time. (why?) 18

Black Scholes For a European Call in the Black-Scholes model we have =N[d 1 ] NB This is not a trivial result! From put call parity it follows (how?) that for a European Put is given by =N[d 1 ] 1 Check signs and interpret! 19

Rebalanced Delta Hedge Sell one call option a time t = 0 at the B-S price F. Compute and by shares. (Use the income from the sale of the option, and borrow money if necessary.) Wait one day (week, minute, second..). The stock price has now changed. Compute the new value of, and borrow money in order to adjust your stock holdings. Repeat this procedure until t = T. Then the value of your portfolio (B+S) will match the value of the option almost exactly. 20

Lack of perfection comes from discrete, instead of continuous, trading. You have created a synthetic option. (Replicating portfolio). Formal result: The relative weights in the replicating portfolio are u S = S F, u B = F S F 21

Portfolio Delta Assume that you have a portfolio consisting of derivatives Φ i (S Ti ), i =1,,n all written on the same underlying stock S. F i (t, s) = pricing function for i:th derivative i = F i s h i = units of i:th derivative Portfolio value: Π= n i=1 h i F i Portfolio delta: Π = n i=1 h i i 22

Gamma A problem with discrete delta-hedging is. As time goes by S will change. This will cause = F s to change. Thus you are sitting with the wrong value of delta. Moral: If delta is sensitive to changes in S, then you have to rebalance often. If delta is insensitive to changes in S you do not need to rebalance so often. 23

Definition: Let Π be the value of a derivative (or portfolio). Gamma (Γ) is defined as i.e. Γ= s Γ= 2 Π s 2 Gamma is a measure of the sensitivity of to changes in S. Result: For a European Call in a Black-Scholes model, Γ can be calculated as Γ= N [d 1 ] Sσ T t Important fact: For a position in the underlying stock itself we have Γ=0 24

Gamma Neutrality A portfolio Π is said to be gamma neutral if its gamma equals zero, i.e. Γ Π =0 Since Γ = 0 for a stock you can not gammahedge using only stocks. item Typically you use some derivative to obtain gamma neutrality. 25

General procedure Given a portfolio Π with underlying S. Consider two derivatives with pricing functions F and G. x F = number of units of F x G = number of units of G Problem: Choose x F and x G such that the entire portfolio is delta- and gamma-neutral. Value of hedged portfolio: V =Π+x F F + x G G 26

Value of hedged portfolio: We get the equations V =Π+x F F + x G G V s = 0, i.e. 2 V s 2 = 0. Π + x F F + x G G = 0, Γ Π + x F Γ F + x G Γ G = 0 Solve for x F and x G! 27

Particular Case In many cases the original portfolio Π is already delta neutral. Then it is natural to use a derivative to obtain gamma-neutrality. This will destroy the delta-neutrality. Therefore we use the underlying stock (with zero gamma!) to delta hedge in the end. 28

Formally: V =Π+x F F + x S S Π + x F F + x S S = 0, Γ Π + x F Γ F + x S Γ S = 0 We have Π = 0, S = 1 Γ S = 0. i.e. Π + x F F + x S = 0, Γ Π + x F Γ F = 0 x F = Γ Π Γ F x S = F Γ Π Γ F Π 29

Further Greeks Θ = Π t, V = Π σ, ρ = Π r V is pronounced Vega. NB! A delta hedge is a hedge against the movements in the underlying stock, given a fixed model. A Vega-hedge is not a hedge against movements of the underlying asset. It is a hedge against a change of the model itself. 30