Commodity Prices, Commodity Currencies, and Global Economic Developments

Similar documents
Are the Commodity Currencies an Exception to the Rule?

Has Globalization Changed the Inflation Process?

Journal of Economics and Financial Analysis, Vol:1, No:1 (2017) 1-13

Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions

Discussion The Changing Relationship Between Commodity Prices and Prices of Other Assets with Global Market Integration by Barbara Rossi

Predictive Dynamics in Commodity Prices

Combining State-Dependent Forecasts of Equity Risk Premium

Introduction... 2 Theory & Literature... 2 Data:... 6 Hypothesis:... 9 Time plan... 9 References:... 10

Fundamentals Based Exchange Rate Prediction Revisited

State Switching in US Equity Index Returns based on SETAR Model with Kalman Filter Tracking

Improving Forecast Accuracy of Financial Vulnerability: Partial Least Squares Factor Model Approach

Modeling and Predictability of Exchange Rate Changes by the Extended Relative Nelson Siegel Class of Models

CAN EXCHANGE RATES FORECAST COMMODITY PRICES? 1 AN UPDATE

Real Exchange Rates and Primary Commodity Prices

Financial Times Series. Lecture 6

A Note on the Oil Price Trend and GARCH Shocks

Realized and Anticipated Macroeconomic Conditions Forecast Stock Returns

Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis

Housing Prices and Growth

What is the Expected Return on a Stock?

Shocks vs Structure:

Topic 4: Introduction to Exchange Rates Part 1: Definitions and empirical regularities

Currency Risk Premia and Macro Fundamentals

1. Operating procedures and choice of monetary policy instrument. 2. Intermediate targets in policymaking. Literature: Walsh (Chapter 11, pp.

MA Advanced Macroeconomics 3. Examples of VAR Studies

Stock market firm-level information and real economic activity

Equity Price Dynamics Before and After the Introduction of the Euro: A Note*

Forecasting Singapore economic growth with mixed-frequency data

Overseas unspanned factors and domestic bond returns

The Relationship between Commodity Prices and Currency Exchange Rates: Evidence from the Futures Markets

Is the Potential for International Diversification Disappearing? A Dynamic Copula Approach

On modelling of electricity spot price

Does Money Matter? An Artificial Intelligence Approach

Predicting RMB exchange rate out-ofsample: Can offshore markets beat random walk?

Money and monetary policy: The ECB experience

A Non-Random Walk Down Wall Street

Factor Model Forecasts of Inflation in Croatia

Oesterreichische Nationalbank. Eurosystem. Workshops. Proceedings of OeNB Workshops. Macroeconomic Models and Forecasts for Austria

The Asset Pricing Model of Exchange Rate and its Test on Survey Data

Real Time Macro Factors in Bond Risk Premium

Discussion of The Term Structure of Growth-at-Risk

Improving Forecast Accuracy of Financial Vulnerability: PLS Factor Model Approach

A Note on the Oil Price Trend and GARCH Shocks

Do High-Frequency Financial Data Help Forecast Oil Prices? The MIDAS Touch at Work

Money and monetary policy: The ECB experience

Overseas unspanned factors and domestic bond returns

Bank Lending Shocks and the Euro Area Business Cycle

The Bilateral J-Curve: Sweden versus her 17 Major Trading Partners

Forecasting Volatility with Empirical Similarity and Google Trends

Comments on Kristin Forbes: Why do Foreigners Invest in the United States? Henning Bohn

Forecasting volatility with macroeconomic and financial variables using Kernel Ridge Regressions

A joint Initiative of Ludwig-Maximilians-Universität and Ifo Institute for Economic Research

Do High-Frequency Financial Data Help Forecast Oil Prices? The MIDAS Touch at Work

Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis. () Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis 1 / 29

Implied Volatility v/s Realized Volatility: A Forecasting Dimension

Oil Price Movements and the Global Economy: A Model-Based Assessment. Paolo Pesenti, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, NBER and CEPR

Can 123 Variables Say Something About Inflation in Malaysia?

Macroeconomic determinants of international commodity prices. Jeffrey Frankel Harpel Professor Capital Formation & Growth Harvard University

Comment on Can Exchange Rates Forecast Commodity Prices? by Yu-chin Chen, Ken Rogoff and Barbara Rossi

Optimal Window Selection for Forecasting in The Presence of Recent Structural Breaks

Dynamic Sparsity Modelling

Empirical Distribution Testing of Economic Scenario Generators

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS YALE UNIVERSITY P.O. Box New Haven, CT

Return Predictability: Dividend Price Ratio versus Expected Returns

Macroeconomic Uncertainty Indices Based on Nowcast and Forecast Error Distributions Online Appendix

Yafu Zhao Department of Economics East Carolina University M.S. Research Paper. Abstract

Online Appendix to Bond Return Predictability: Economic Value and Links to the Macroeconomy. Pairwise Tests of Equality of Forecasting Performance

Topic 4: Introduction to Exchange Rates Part 1: Definitions and empirical regularities

Futures Markets, Oil Prices, and the Intertemporal Approach to the Current Account

Factor Forecasting for Agricultural Production Processes

Lecture 5. Predictability. Traditional Views of Market Efficiency ( )

Discussion of Trend Inflation in Advanced Economies

FORECASTING THE CYPRUS GDP GROWTH RATE:

Financial Econometrics Jeffrey R. Russell. Midterm 2014 Suggested Solutions. TA: B. B. Deng

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2012, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

Is there a significant connection between commodity prices and exchange rates?

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment

Discussion: Molodtsova and Papell, Phoenix Taylor Rule Exchange Rate Forecasting During the Financial Crisis

Uncertainty and Economic Activity: A Global Perspective

Stressing Bank Profitability for Interest Rate Risk

Lecture 3: Factor models in modern portfolio choice

Predicting the Equity Premium with Implied Volatility Spreads

Chapter 6 Forecasting Volatility using Stochastic Volatility Model

Common risk factors in currency markets

Modelling Power Futures Volatility: Comparison of ARMA and GARCH Models based on EEX Data

April 6, Table of contents. Global Inflation Outlook

Workshop on resilience

Unobserved Heterogeneity Revisited

The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics

The Role of APIs in the Economy

Part I. Please answer in the provided space only

Blame the Discount Factor No Matter What the Fundamentals Are

P R E S E N T S. U.S. Economic Outlook Virtuous Growth

Monetary Policy and the Predictability of Nominal Exchange Rates

A Note on Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios

Bayesian Dynamic Linear Models for Strategic Asset Allocation

DISCUSSION. The causal effect of credit guarantees for SMEs: evidence from Italy. by Alessio D Ignazio and Carlo Menon

Can Hedge Funds Time the Market?

Backtesting and Optimizing Commodity Hedging Strategies

Transcription:

Commodity Prices, Commodity Currencies, and Global Economic Developments Jan J. J. Groen Paolo A. Pesenti Federal Reserve Bank of New York August 16-17, 2012 FGV-Vale Conference The Economics and Econometrics of Commodity Prices, Rio de Janeiro

First... The views expressed in the paper and this presentation are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System.

In case we need motivation...... refer to Bernanke (June 2008 speech Outstanding Issues in the Analysis of Inflation ). Emphasizes importance for policy: Forecasting commodity price changes. Understanding the factors that drive those changes. Spectacular commodity price swings in recent times: Oil price more than doubled between the end of 2006 and the time of the Bernanke speech. Food prices rose by about 50 percent over same time horizon. At time of speech, inflationary pressures very much in the minds of monetary policymakers across the globe. Soon after: near-collapse of trade worldwide, plunge in commodity prices, disinflation risks.

In case we need motivation...... refer to Bernanke (June 2008 speech Outstanding Issues in the Analysis of Inflation ). Emphasizes importance for policy: Forecasting commodity price changes. Understanding the factors that drive those changes. Spectacular commodity price swings in recent times: Oil price more than doubled between the end of 2006 and the time of the Bernanke speech. Food prices rose by about 50 percent over same time horizon. At time of speech, inflationary pressures very much in the minds of monetary policymakers across the globe. Soon after: near-collapse of trade worldwide, plunge in commodity prices, disinflation risks.

In case we need motivation...... refer to Bernanke (June 2008 speech Outstanding Issues in the Analysis of Inflation ). Emphasizes importance for policy: Forecasting commodity price changes. Understanding the factors that drive those changes. Spectacular commodity price swings in recent times: Oil price more than doubled between the end of 2006 and the time of the Bernanke speech. Food prices rose by about 50 percent over same time horizon. At time of speech, inflationary pressures very much in the minds of monetary policymakers across the globe. Soon after: near-collapse of trade worldwide, plunge in commodity prices, disinflation risks.

Commodity Price Forecasting: Policy Practice Central Banks: Produce forecasts for, e.g., future WTI oil spot prices and the IMF Non-Fuel Commodity Price Index. Based on futures prices, assuming that: Futures prices efficiently incorporates public information. Contains information about the global economy, not just individual commodity. Forecast model: p t+h,t = α h + (fp h t p t ) + ɛ t+h,t, t = 1,..., T with p t = ln(p t ) and P t is a commodity spot price index, fp h t is log futures price for h-period horizon, and p t+h,t = p t+h p t for the forecasting horizon h > 0. BUT: Futures prices are biased predictors, especially since 2006.

Commodity Price Forecasting: Policy Practice Central Banks: Produce forecasts for, e.g., future WTI oil spot prices and the IMF Non-Fuel Commodity Price Index. Based on futures prices, assuming that: Futures prices efficiently incorporates public information. Contains information about the global economy, not just individual commodity. Forecast model: p t+h,t = α h + (fp h t p t ) + ɛ t+h,t, t = 1,..., T with p t = ln(p t ) and P t is a commodity spot price index, fp h t is log futures price for h-period horizon, and p t+h,t = p t+h p t for the forecasting horizon h > 0. BUT: Futures prices are biased predictors, especially since 2006.

Commodity Price Forecasting: Policy Practice Central Banks: Produce forecasts for, e.g., future WTI oil spot prices and the IMF Non-Fuel Commodity Price Index. Based on futures prices, assuming that: Futures prices efficiently incorporates public information. Contains information about the global economy, not just individual commodity. Forecast model: p t+h,t = α h + (fp h t p t ) + ɛ t+h,t, t = 1,..., T with p t = ln(p t ) and P t is a commodity spot price index, fp h t is log futures price for h-period horizon, and p t+h,t = p t+h p t for the forecasting horizon h > 0. BUT: Futures prices are biased predictors, especially since 2006.

WTI Futures vs. Realized Spots $/Barrel $/Barrel 160 160 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 0 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 Source: Bloomberg Note: Dashed lines represent futures curves

Have we now reached some pragmatic consensus on how to predict swings in commodity prices? Our paper: check to exactly how close we have come to that It: Conducts a horse race between various approaches to predict 10 different indices of commodity spot prices. Uses common factor models with global economic data and Rogoff-type currency-based models Attempts to beat simple statistical benchmarks, i.e, random walk and autoregressive processes. Basic message: inconclusiveness. Not necessarily pessimistic, but throws cold water on excessive hopes.

Have we now reached some pragmatic consensus on how to predict swings in commodity prices? Our paper: check to exactly how close we have come to that It: Conducts a horse race between various approaches to predict 10 different indices of commodity spot prices. Uses common factor models with global economic data and Rogoff-type currency-based models Attempts to beat simple statistical benchmarks, i.e, random walk and autoregressive processes. Basic message: inconclusiveness. Not necessarily pessimistic, but throws cold water on excessive hopes.

Have we now reached some pragmatic consensus on how to predict swings in commodity prices? Our paper: check to exactly how close we have come to that It: Conducts a horse race between various approaches to predict 10 different indices of commodity spot prices. Uses common factor models with global economic data and Rogoff-type currency-based models Attempts to beat simple statistical benchmarks, i.e, random walk and autoregressive processes. Basic message: inconclusiveness. Not necessarily pessimistic, but throws cold water on excessive hopes.

Three Approaches to Forecasting Commodity Prices Atheist: at the end of the day, nothing works. Just use random walk or autoregressive processes. True Believer: you need a theory, you need a model. The truth is out there, maybe fundamentals, maybe not. Squeeze data for information. In practice, use futures prices. Or commodity currencies. Agnostic: the rest of us. Open-mindedness and willingness to experiment. We d love to be true believers, but not convinced yet.

Three Approaches to Forecasting Commodity Prices Atheist: at the end of the day, nothing works. Just use random walk or autoregressive processes. True Believer: you need a theory, you need a model. The truth is out there, maybe fundamentals, maybe not. Squeeze data for information. In practice, use futures prices. Or commodity currencies. Agnostic: the rest of us. Open-mindedness and willingness to experiment. We d love to be true believers, but not convinced yet.

Three Approaches to Forecasting Commodity Prices Atheist: at the end of the day, nothing works. Just use random walk or autoregressive processes. True Believer: you need a theory, you need a model. The truth is out there, maybe fundamentals, maybe not. Squeeze data for information. In practice, use futures prices. Or commodity currencies. Agnostic: the rest of us. Open-mindedness and willingness to experiment. We d love to be true believers, but not convinced yet.

Atheist Approach There is nothing beyond the time series itself. Use an autoregressive (AR) model as forecasting benchmark k p t+h,t = α h + ρ i p t i+1,t i + ɛ t+h,t, i=1 t = 1,..., T with p t i+1,t i = p t i+1 p t i for i = 1,..., k. k selected by sequentially applying BIC criterion. The unconditional mean benchmark is simply: p t+h,t = α h + ɛ t+h,t, implies a random walk (RW) forecast for p t.

Atheist Approach There is nothing beyond the time series itself. Use an autoregressive (AR) model as forecasting benchmark k p t+h,t = α h + ρ i p t i+1,t i + ɛ t+h,t, i=1 t = 1,..., T with p t i+1,t i = p t i+1 p t i for i = 1,..., k. k selected by sequentially applying BIC criterion. The unconditional mean benchmark is simply: p t+h,t = α h + ɛ t+h,t, implies a random walk (RW) forecast for p t.

Atheist Approach There is nothing beyond the time series itself. Use an autoregressive (AR) model as forecasting benchmark k p t+h,t = α h + ρ i p t i+1,t i + ɛ t+h,t, i=1 t = 1,..., T with p t i+1,t i = p t i+1 p t i for i = 1,..., k. k selected by sequentially applying BIC criterion. The unconditional mean benchmark is simply: p t+h,t = α h + ɛ t+h,t, implies a random walk (RW) forecast for p t.

True Believers Approach Three schools of thought : Commodity markets have relatively inelastic demand small revisions in the expected future supply expansion can have large and highly volatile price effects.

Three schools of thought : True Believers Approach Speculative strategies that drive commodity futures prices up must be reflected in higher spot prices today regardless of long-term fundamentals. Especially when there are rapid declines in short-term interest rates opportunity cost of physical commodity holding is relatively low (Frankel, 2008).

Three schools of thought : True Believers Approach Commodities typically represent significant components of output for most commodity exporting countries, and these countries are too small to have an impact on world markets. Their exchange rates thus move today anticipating future terms of trade adjustment; see Chen, Rogoff and Rossi (2010) - CRR hereafter. p t+h,t = α h + M γ m et m + m=1 k ρ i p t i+1,t i + ɛ t+h,t. et 1,..., em t are relative changes in U.S. dollar exchange rates of M commodity-exporting economies. i=1

Three schools of thought : True Believers Approach Commodities typically represent significant components of output for most commodity exporting countries, and these countries are too small to have an impact on world markets. Their exchange rates thus move today anticipating future terms of trade adjustment; see Chen, Rogoff and Rossi (2010) - CRR hereafter. p t+h,t = α h + M γ m et m + m=1 k ρ i p t i+1,t i + ɛ t+h,t. et 1,..., em t are relative changes in U.S. dollar exchange rates of M commodity-exporting economies. i=1

Three schools of thought : True Believers Approach Commodities typically represent significant components of output for most commodity exporting countries, and these countries are too small to have an impact on world markets. Their exchange rates thus move today anticipating future terms of trade adjustment; see Chen, Rogoff and Rossi (2010) - CRR hereafter. p t+h,t = α h + M γ m et m + m=1 k ρ i p t i+1,t i + ɛ t+h,t. i=1 M commodity-exporting economies: Australia, Canada, Chile, New Zealand, and South Africa.

Agnostic Approach Use a large amount of information on global economic conditions, i.e., commodity exchange rates as well as... N macro-economic time series across major developed and developing countries: industrial production, business and consumer confidence data, retail sales volumes, unemployment rates, core consumer prices (excluding food and energy), money aggregates and interest rates. Data on inventories and production of industrial metals, oil, natural gas and coal. Baltic Dry Index (BDI) - aggregates shipping rates across many different routes and vessels.

Agnostic Approach Use a large amount of information on global economic conditions, i.e., commodity exchange rates as well as... N macro-economic time series across major developed and developing countries: industrial production, business and consumer confidence data, retail sales volumes, unemployment rates, core consumer prices (excluding food and energy), money aggregates and interest rates. Data on inventories and production of industrial metals, oil, natural gas and coal. Baltic Dry Index (BDI) - aggregates shipping rates across many different routes and vessels.

Agnostic Approach Use a large amount of information on global economic conditions, i.e., commodity exchange rates as well as... N macro-economic time series across major developed and developing countries: industrial production, business and consumer confidence data, retail sales volumes, unemployment rates, core consumer prices (excluding food and energy), money aggregates and interest rates. Data on inventories and production of industrial metals, oil, natural gas and coal. Baltic Dry Index (BDI) - aggregates shipping rates across many different routes and vessels.

Agnostic Approach Use these data in factor-augmented regressions: r k p t+h,t = α h + βi h f i,t + ρ i p t j+1,t j + ɛ t+h,t, i=1 j=1 f 1,t,..., f r,t : dynamic factors from large data set

Factor-Based Macro Forecasting Tools y t = α (x 1,t x N,t ) + ɛ t ; t = 1,..., T with x 1,t,..., x N,t normalized and N large. Stock-Watson (2002) PC regression: x t = (x 1,t x N,t ) = Λ F t + e t with F t are combinations of x-variables using the r dominant eigenvectors from X X with X = (x 1 x T ) Groen-Kapetanios (2009a) PLS regression: factors f t are orthogonal combinations of x-variables using r dominant eigenvectors from X yy X with y = (y 1 y T ) Note r r and f t F t. PLS regression directly selects that subset from F t that has the best (in-sample) fit for y t.

Agnostic Approach Use these data in factor-augmented regressions: p t+h,t = α h + r βi h f i,t + i=1 k ρ i p t j+1,t j + ɛ t+h,t, f 1,t,..., f r,t : dynamic factors from large data set through: Principal Components (PC): extract linear combinations of predictors that provides the best description of the large data set. Partial Least Squares (PLS) regression: extract orthogonal linear combinations of predictors that have maximum explanatory power for p t+h,t. j=1 Use modified BIC to select r and k. See Groen and Kapetanios (2009b).

Agnostic Approach Use these data in factor-augmented regressions: p t+h,t = α h + r βi h f i,t + i=1 k ρ i p t j+1,t j + ɛ t+h,t, f 1,t,..., f r,t : dynamic factors from large data set through: Principal Components (PC): extract linear combinations of predictors that provides the best description of the large data set. Partial Least Squares (PLS) regression: extract orthogonal linear combinations of predictors that have maximum explanatory power for p t+h,t. j=1 Use modified BIC to select r and k. See Groen and Kapetanios (2009b).

Agnostic Approach Use these data in factor-augmented regressions: p t+h,t = α h + r βi h f i,t + i=1 k ρ i p t j+1,t j + ɛ t+h,t, f 1,t,..., f r,t : dynamic factors from large data set through: Principal Components (PC): extract linear combinations of predictors that provides the best description of the large data set. Partial Least Squares (PLS) regression: extract orthogonal linear combinations of predictors that have maximum explanatory power for p t+h,t. j=1 BICM = T ( 2 ln{ˆσ2ˆɛ } + (1 + k) ln(t ) + r ln(t ) 1 + T ). N

Data I 10 Forecast variables: Commodity Research Bureau (CRB): both overall index and industrial metals sub-index start from 1973. S&P/Goldman Sachs Index (SPG): overall from 1973, industrial metals and energy sub-indices start in 1977 and 1983, respectively. IMF Non-fuel Commodity Prices Index (IMF) starts in 1980 along with the IMF industrial metals sub-index. Dow Jones-AIG Commodity Index (DJAIG): from 1991, along with its sub-indices for energy and metals.

Data II Predictor variables: Cross-sectional sizes of panels vary depending on time span of underlying index. CRB and SPG aggregate: 1973.03-2009.2 with total of N = 96 series in the panel. SPG industrial metals sub-index: 1977.02-2009.2 with N = 112 SPG energy sub-index: 1983.02-2009.02 with N = 127. IMF: 1980.02-2009.02 with N = 122. DJAIG: 1991.02-2009.02, with N = 143.

Forecasting: Methodology All models sequentially re-estimated using a fixed rolling data window of 120 monthly observations. After each re-estimation we generate a forecast h-month ahead. Details We then report the relative MSE differentials as: with B = AR or RW. MSE adj F RMSE = MSE B MSE adj F, MSE B : Clark and West (2006, 2007) finite sample correction for spurious noise in MSE of the fundamentals-based predictions resulting from inappropriately fitting a larger model on the data.

Forecasting: Methodology All models sequentially re-estimated using a fixed rolling data window of 120 monthly observations. After each re-estimation we generate a forecast h-month ahead. Details We then report the relative MSE differentials as: with B = AR or RW. MSE adj F RMSE = MSE B MSE adj F, MSE B : Clark and West (2006, 2007) finite sample correction for spurious noise in MSE of the fundamentals-based predictions resulting from inappropriately fitting a larger model on the data.

Forecasting: Methodology All models sequentially re-estimated using a fixed rolling data window of 120 monthly observations. After each re-estimation we generate a forecast h-month ahead. Details We then report the relative MSE differentials as: with B = AR or RW. ( MSE adj F = MSE F RMSE = MSE B MSE adj F, MSE B 1 T t 0 h T h s=t 0 ) ( ) 2 ˆp s,s+h B ˆpF s,s+h We test H 0 : MSE B MSE adj F H 1 : MSE B MSE adj F > 0. = 0 versus

Forecasting: Methodology All models sequentially re-estimated using a fixed rolling data window of 120 monthly observations. After each re-estimation we generate a forecast h-month ahead. Details We then report the relative MSE differentials as: with B = AR or RW. ( MSE adj F = MSE F RMSE = MSE B MSE adj F, MSE B 1 T t 0 h T h s=t 0 ) ( ) 2 ˆp s,s+h B ˆpF s,s+h We test H 0 : MSE B MSE adj F H 1 : MSE B MSE adj F > 0. = 0 versus

Forecasting: Methodology All models sequentially re-estimated using a fixed rolling data window of 120 monthly observations. After each re-estimation we generate a forecast h-month ahead. Details We then report the relative MSE differentials as: RMSE = MSE B MSE adj F, MSE B with B = AR or RW. We test H 0 : MSE B MSE adj F = 0 versus H 1 : MSE B MSE adj F > 0. z adj MSE = (T t 0 h) 1 2 MSE B MSE adj F ( ( )) 1 N(0, 1) 2 Var ũ adj t+h

And the winner is... There is no obvious winner! Information from large panels of global economic variables can help, but their forecasting properties are by no means overwhelming. No overwhelming evidence for the notion that commodity currencies are useful predictors. Even less empirical support for commodity futures. Across 10 commodity indices no easy patterns or generalizations are found

Some Specific Results... for CRB Aggregate and IMF Non-Fuel Commodity Price Indices

Forecasting the CRB Aggregate Index: 1973.03-2009.02 CRR PC Regression PLS Regression h RW AR RW AR RW AR 1 0.07-0.01 0.00-0.01 0.20 0.14 (1.34)* (-0.56) (0.03) (-0.63) (1.86)** (0.99) 3 0.02 0.02-0.02 0.00 0.14 0.14 (0.34) (0.59) (-0.88) (-0.16) (1.28)* (0.82) 6 0.02 0.05-0.06-0.02-0.10-0.09 (0.25) (1.14) (-0.71) (-0.55) (-0.56) (-0.73) 12 0.02 0.06-0.09-0.02 0.00 0.02 (0.25) (0.93) (-0.85) (-0.24) (0.00) (0.16) 24-0.01 0.07-0.19-0.05-0.59-0.48 (-0.08) (1.56)* (-1.97) (-0.57) (-2.84) (-2.40)

Forecasting the IMF Non-Fuel Index: 1980.02-2009.02 CRR PC Regression PLS Regression h RW AR RW AR RW AR 1 0.34 0.03 0.32-0.01 0.44 0.18 (1.49) (1.49) (1.20) (-0.69) (2.33)*** (1.37)* 3 0.15-0.01 0.13-0.01 0.25 0.10 (3.31)*** (-0.29) (1.86)** (-0.37) (2.15)** (1.00) 6 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.03-0.10-0.10 (0.36) (0.37) (-0.01) (0.98) (-0.37) (-0.46) 12 0.03 0.04-0.07-0.02 0.15 0.14 (0.40) (0.93) (-0.75) (-0.06) (0.18) (0.41) 24-0.08 0.00-0.39-0.29-0.14-0.07 (-1.03) (-0.03) (-2.31) (-2.20) (-0.91) (-0.49)

Sensitivity Test I Is the extra information of the PLS-based factor model vis-à-vis the CRR model significant enough to warrant its use? Test whether out-of-sample M r p t+h,t = α h + γ m et m + βi h fi,t PLS + is better than m=1 p t+h,t = α h + i=1 M γ m et m + m=1 k ρ i p t j+1,t j +ɛ t+h,t, j=1 k ρ i p t i+1,t i + ɛ t+h,t. i=1

Sensitivity Test I h 1 3 6 12 24 CRB Aggregate 0.18 0.25-0.05 0.14-0.09 (1.44)* (1.95)** (-0.41) (1.43)* (-0.37) IMF Non-Fuel 0.17 0.14-0.06 0.23-0.03 (1.48)* (1.31)* (-0.24) (0.83) (-0.26) The PLS-based factor model has a slight edge over the CRR model.

Sensitivity Test II Consistent time series on a broad set of commodity futures and forward rates for 1-, 3-, 6- and 12-months ahead horizons are only available from the mid-1980s onwards. We are forced to limit this experiment to the DJ-AIG price indices. What are the results? The forecasting performances are basically unchanged when we add these futures and forwards to the relevant predictor variable panels. Thus, qualitatively, the factor-augmented model results relative to the naive benchmark models remain similar.

Sensitivity Test II Consistent time series on a broad set of commodity futures and forward rates for 1-, 3-, 6- and 12-months ahead horizons are only available from the mid-1980s onwards. We are forced to limit this experiment to the DJ-AIG price indices. What are the results? The forecasting performances are basically unchanged when we add these futures and forwards to the relevant predictor variable panels. Thus, qualitatively, the factor-augmented model results relative to the naive benchmark models remain similar.

The DJ-AIG Aggregate Index without futures: 1973.03-2009.02 PC Regression PLS Regression h RW AR RW AR 1 0.19 0.03 0.40 0.18 (0.58) (0.63) (0.60) (1.03) 3 0.00 0.03 0.48 0.48 (0.05) (1.06) (0.94) (0.93) 6-0.08 0.03 0.06 0.17 (-0.22) (0.55) (1.31)* (0.80) 12 0.25 0.34 0.20 0.33 (0.84) (1.33)* (0.62) (0.86) 24 0.62 0.82 0.04 0.08 (2.14)** (1.80)** (0.07) (0.19)

The DJ-AIG Aggregate Index with futures: 1973.03-2009.02 PC Regression PLS Regression h RW AR RW AR 1 0.26 0.09 0.58 0.32 (0.33) (0.87) (1.23) (0.46) 3 0.10 0.11 0.45 0.45 (0.68) (1.15) (0.95) (0.98) 6 0.03 0.05 0.07 0.17 (0.27) (2.17)** (1.04) (0.75) 12 0.10-0.02 0.22 0.32 (0.25) (-0.18) (0.58) (0.36) 24 0.00-0.04 0.09 0.12 (-0.02) (-0.19) (0.15) (0.35)

Conclusions Basic message: inconclusiveness. Information from a large global economic data panel can help when PLS is used...... but as of yet the forecasting properties are by no means overwhelming. Policy lessons: Commodity price forecasts provide only highly noisy hints about their actual future trajectories and persistence. Excessive confidence in such forecasts may bias policymakers views and beliefs about future inflation risks.

Conclusions Basic message: inconclusiveness. Information from a large global economic data panel can help when PLS is used...... but as of yet the forecasting properties are by no means overwhelming. Policy lessons: Commodity price forecasts provide only highly noisy hints about their actual future trajectories and persistence. Excessive confidence in such forecasts may bias policymakers views and beliefs about future inflation risks.

Conclusions Basic message: inconclusiveness. Information from a large global economic data panel can help when PLS is used...... but as of yet the forecasting properties are by no means overwhelming. Policy lessons: Commodity price forecasts provide only highly noisy hints about their actual future trajectories and persistence. Excessive confidence in such forecasts may bias policymakers views and beliefs about future inflation risks.

Details Sequential Updating for Forecasting 1. For any horizon h generate first forecast on t 0 = ω. 2. Extract r max PC and PLS factors from N predictor variables over the sample t = t 0 ω + 1,..., t 0 h. 3. Determine for t = t 0 ω + 1,..., t 0 h the optimal lag order and number of factors using BICM across j = 0,..., k max = 12 and i = 1,..., r max = 6. Gives (ˆk BICM PC PC PLS PLS, ˆr BICM ) and (ˆk BICM, ˆr BICM ). Similarly, use BIC for optimal lag order in AR benchmark and CRR model. 4. Given the outcome of step 3, estimate over the sample t = t 0 ω + 1,..., t 0 h. 5. Extract ˆr PC and PLS factors from the N predictor variables over the sample t = t 0 ω + 1,..., t 0. 6. Generate forecast ˆp t+h,t using the estimated dimensions from step 3, the parameter estimates from step 4, and factors from step 5. 7. Repeat for t 0 = ω + 1,..., T h and for any forecast horizon h.