The Effects of Macro-Level Noise on Unemployment, Inflation and Growth

Similar documents
Prices and Output in an Open Economy: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

紅石國際教育中心. Red Rock Institute & Publishing

Exchange Rates in the Long Run

!&Z -** -. oremacroeconorracs. Gerald W. Stone Metropolitan State College of Denver. Worth Publishers

The Yield Curve as a Predictor of Economic Activity the Case of the EU- 15

Lecture 12: Economic Fluctuations. Rob Godby University of Wyoming

Macroeconomic Theory and Policy

Statistical annex. Sources and definitions

Money and the Economy CHAPTER

Algorithmic Order Guide

A Lower Bound on Real Interest Rates

INSTITUTE OF ECONOMIC STUDIES

Expectations Theory and the Economy CHAPTER

Saving, Investment, and the Financial System. Premium PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich, Updated by Vance Ginn

Corrigendum. OECD Pensions Outlook 2012 DOI: ISBN (print) ISBN (PDF) OECD 2012

At the end of this report, we summarize some important Year-End Considerations which employers should be prepared to address.

Monetary Policy in Euroland

OECD Report Shows Tax Burdens Falling in Many OECD Countries

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2014

Graph 1. Source: (World Bank, 2017) Name: Student ID: Inflation rate/unem ployment rate/gdp growth Rate. Time period

Issue Brief for Congress

University of Macedonia Department of Economics. Discussion Paper Series. Inflation, inflation uncertainty and growth: are they related?

The Velocity of Money and Nominal Interest Rates: Evidence from Developed and Latin-American Countries

Approach to Employment Injury (EI) compensation benefits in the EU and OECD

Lecture 9: Intermediate macroeconomics, autumn Lars Calmfors

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2016

WikiLeaks Document Release

Table 1: Foreign exchange turnover: Summary of surveys Billions of U.S. dollars. Number of business days

Ageing and employment policies: Ireland

How Wealthy Are Europeans?

Regional Economic Outlook

EMPLOYABILITY AND LABOUR MARKET

EMPLOYMENT RATE Employed/Working age population (15 64 years)

ECFIN-C3 (2009) PART 1 MAIN DEVELOPMENTS

Performance Budgeting (PB) in OECD Countries

Syllabus. MACROECONOMICS Instructors: Dmitriy A. Veselov.

CANADA S LABOUR MARKET PRE- AND POST-CRISIS

Analysis of European Union Economy in Terms of GDP Components

FRESNO COUNTY EMPLOYEES' RETIREMENT ASSOCIATION Franklin Templeton International Equity - Country Allocation & Returns Period Ending: June 30, 2007

2017 Federico Caffè Lectures. Monetary Policy in Times of Low Inflation

Aviation Economics & Finance

TAXES, FINANCING AND SKILLS IN PORTUGAL

International Macroeconomics

Switzerland and Germany top the PwC Young Workers Index in developing younger people

Optimal fiscal policy

Is Economic Growth Good for Investors? Jay R. Ritter University of Florida

Learning Goal. To develop an understanding of the Millennium Development Goal targets

Growth in OECD Unit Labour Costs slows to 0.4% in the third quarter of 2016

Appendix: Suggestions for Future Simulations

Introduction to Public Finance

Restoring compe//veness: what has gone right, what has gone wrong?

Trade and Development Board Sixty-first session. Geneva, September 2014

WORKINGPAPER SERIES. Trends In The Rentier Income Share In OECD Countries, Dorothy Power Gerald Epstein Matthew Abrena

Downstream natural gas in Europe the role of upstream oil and gas companies

Statistical Annex ANNEX

Neil Foster, Robert Stehrer, Marcel Timmer, Gaaitzen de Vries. WIOD conference, april 2012 Groningen

Lecture 22. Aggregate demand and aggregate supply

MONETARY POLICY. 8Topic

The Case for Fundamental Tax Reform: Overview of the Current Tax System

Cyclical Convergence and Divergence in the Euro Area

Downward Nominal Wage Rigidity in the OECD

), is described there by a function of the following form: U (c t. )= c t. where c t

Does the Confidence Fairy Exist?

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2017

The macroeconomic effects of a carbon tax in the Netherlands Íde Kearney, 13 th September 2018.

The Phillips Curve. By: OpenStaxCollege

Chart pack to council for cooperation on macroprudential policy

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2018

Unit 6: Opening up the parliamentary process

Sources of Government Revenue across the OECD, 2015

Work Capacity of Older Workers: Canada and the United States

Okun s law revisited. Is there structural unemployment in developed countries?

Implementing ICP Recommendations Financing The Road To Prosperity. Paul Daniel Muller. President Montreal Economic Institute

DFA Global Equity Portfolio (Class F) Quarterly Performance Report Q2 2014

26/10/2016. The Euro. By 2016 there are 19 member countries and about 334 million people use the. Lithuania entered 1 January 2015

Statistics Brief. Investment in Inland Transport Infrastructure at Record Low. Infrastructure Investment. July

UK trade long-term trends and recent developments

Trust and Fertility Dynamics. Arnstein Aassve, Università Bocconi Francesco C. Billari, University of Oxford Léa Pessin, Universitat Pompeu Fabra

THE SHORT-RUN TRADEOFF BETWEEN INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT

Health Care Spending and the Aging of the Population

Unemployment and Inflation

Lecture 10. Welfare State Expenditure ANDREEA STOIAN, PHD DEPARTMENT OF FINANCE AND CEFIMO

PRODUCTIVE AGEING ROBERT BUTLER MEMORIAL LECTURE ILC GLOBAL ALLIANCE

DANMARKS NATIONALBANK

DFA Global Equity Portfolio (Class F) Performance Report Q3 2018

DFA Global Equity Portfolio (Class F) Performance Report Q4 2017

DFA Global Equity Portfolio (Class F) Performance Report Q2 2017

GO ON TO THE NEXT PAGE. -8- Unauthorized copying or reuse of any part of this page is illegal.

Lecture: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

May 2012 Euro area international trade in goods surplus of 6.9 bn euro 3.8 bn euro deficit for EU27

PREDICTING VEHICLE SALES FROM GDP

Constraints on Exchange Rate Flexibility in Transition Economies: a Meta-Regression Analysis of Exchange Rate Pass-Through

PENSIONS IN OECD COUNTRIES: INDICATORS AND DEVELOPMENTS

First estimate for 2011 Euro area external trade deficit 7.7 bn euro bn euro deficit for EU27

DFA Global Equity Portfolio (Class F) Performance Report Q3 2015

CHAPTER 15 Long-Run Macroeconomic Adjustments

Global Dividend-Paying Stocks: A Recent History

International Seminar on Strengthening Public Investment and Managing Fiscal Risks from Public-Private Partnerships

June 2012 Euro area international trade in goods surplus of 14.9 bn euro 0.4 bn euro surplus for EU27

The Influence of Monetary and Fiscal Policy on Aggregate Demand. Lecture

Transcription:

The Effects of Macro-Level Noise on Unemployment, Inflation and Growth Eric Findlay February 28 The economic theory, developed in the early 197s, of the physicist Henri Rathgeber is examined. The seminar paper present the more technical issues and the seminar presentation will work on more conceptual issues. On a physical level, associated with every transaction is a minimum required transmission of information. Claude Shannon's information theory determines the minimum level of redundant, or extra information required to correct noisy messages. If information transmission in economic systems is noisy, and the transaction of a unit of currency is on average associated with a given amount of information, then extra currency added to the system is required to compensate for noise. Noise causes a shortfall in actual goods and services transacted over what buyers and sellers wish to transact, therefore the received error rate results in unemployment. The result is an linear inverse relationship between the rate of change in the money flow and the unemployment rate. Holding the growth rate constant results in a linear inverse relationship between inflation and unemployment. We call this simple tradeoff a Fisher line. Changes in the growth rate cause horizontal shifts in the Fisher line. In addition, we find that there is a positive feedback between increases in the inflation rate and the interest rate, which pushes the Fisher Line to the right under high inflation conditions, explaining post-197 stagflation conditions. Post-stagflation low inflation targeting causes capital equilibriation and left-shifts of the Fisher line, explaining the widespread decrease in unemployment rates with the introduction of inflation-targeting policy. The theory raises the question of how to reach full employment. High inflation selections temporarily reduce the unemployment rate but cause right-shifts of the Fisher

line resulting in both high inflation and high unemployment. The introduction of a unit of account indexation breaks the inflation feedback process and allows us to make stable selections anywhere along the Fisher line, allowing stable full-employment selections to be made. Figure 1 shows the results of information theory. Given a message with an error rate of e, a redundancy rate of h is required to result in the correct message being received. Figure 1 Received Error Rate as a Function of Redundancy Rate Redundancy Rate (%) h e Received Error Rate (%) We assume that the law of supply and demand holds, and that money is neutral. We add one extra assumption, that there is noise in the transmission of the information required for all transactions, that both buyers and seller agree to, to occur. Since, on average, there is a certain average amount of currency per unit of information, we need to correct errors by adding redundant information, and therefore extra currency, to our system. Assuming money-neutrality, this means that we require a certain rate of increase in the flow of currency. Noise causes a shortfall in actual goods and services transacted over what buyers and sellers wish to transact, therefore the received error rate in

this transmission results in unemployment. Figure 2 shows the consequences of noise. Figure 2 Unemployment as a Function of Rate of Change in Money Flow Change in Money Flow (%) h e We can divide currency flow into a price index and quantity. Let F be the flow of curency. Note that this includes all transactions, including intermediate goods. The rate of change of the flow of currency is equal to the inflation rate, I, plus, G, the growth rate (of Q). In Figure 3 we call the relationship between the inflation rate of unemployment rate when G is held constant a Fisher line, after Irving Fisher who first published empirical results on this

relationship in 1926. For a constant inflation rate, a decrease in the growth rate G, results in a decrease in F, causing an increase in the unemployment rate. Therefore, changing the growth rate shifts the Fisher line horizontally as shown in Figure 3. Figure 3 Fisher Line Dynamics Fisher Line Increased Growth Rate Decreased Growth Rate We now examine a positive feedback relationship between inflation and the interest rate. If C are firm's nominal costs, W is nominal wage costs, i the interest rate, and K nominal capital costs, then if the interest rate i is constant, an increase in the inflation rate, will cause C, W and K to rise proportionally so that there is no change in real costs. However, because a component of the interest rate compensates for increases in the inflation rate, i will not remain constant but increase in response to increases in the inflation rate. Therefore, if there is an increase in the inflation rate, capital costs will increase faster than the inflation rate, causing real costs to increase. Profits will

create a constraint on this condition and at some point Q must decrease, causing a right-shift in the Fisher line. If central banks respond with an expansionary policy as shown in Figure 5, this will cause further increases in the inflation rate which then feeds back into the interest rate, causing positive feedback. Expansionary economic policy results in rapid increases in both the inflation and unemployment rate, as experienced in the 197s, as shown in the 'inflation feedback' shift in Figure 5. If central banks shift to low inflation-targeting monetary policy then we see a shift along the Fisher line resulting in decreased inflation rates but further increases in the unemployment rate as seen in the 'shift to low inflation' in Figure 5. Firms are now subject to fixed contracts at high interest rates, and growth rates will be restricted until these contracts are paid off. Thus we see a slow increase in growth rates and decrease in the unemployment rate, at low inflation rates until economies return to capital equilibrium in the sense that payments on contracts are close to present interest rates. Figure 4 Monetary Response to Inflation Feedback Expansionary Policy Contractionary Policy

Figure 5 Inflation Feedback Cycle Inflation Feedback Shift to Low Inflation Capital Equilibriation

Figure 6 Unemployment and Inflation, United States 197-26 13 12 8 11 1 1974-79 slope=-3.37 79 74 198-83 slope=-3.1 9 81 8 75 7 78 6 5 197-73 slope=-2.93 73 7 9 89 77 76 82 4 3 2 71 88 87 5 6 72 1 96 95 4 94 99 97 3 98 2 91 84 85 93 92 86 83 1 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1 11 We examine whether the theory is consistent with evidence. Lucas, in his Nobel prize lecture in 1996 suggests that there are short-run inverse relationships between unemployment and inflation in the periods 196-1969, 197-1973, 1974-1979 and 198-1983 in the United States, but that this relationship shifts. Plotting the periods Lucas selects in Figure 6, we find three Fisher lines with remarkably similar slopes. As the inflation rate increases from 1972 to 1973, inflation feedback develops and the Fisher Line shifts to the right between 1973 and 1974. The Federal Reserve reacts to increases in inflation with contractionary policy, ending the inflation feedback, however the period 1976 to 1979 sees a reversion to expansionary policy and feedback sets in again until 198. A clockwise loop can be observed between 1974 and 1979 which can be observed across many countries. A decrease in the inflation rate is associated with the Fisher line and capital equilibriation keeping the Fisher line constant or shifting to the left. An increase in the inflation rate is assoicated with inflation feedback shifting the Fisher line to the right. This results in

clockwise loops. From 198, the Federal Reserve adopts a strong contractionary policy and inflation targeting, resulting in a shift along the Fisher line between 198 and 1983. Post 1983 shows decreasing unemployment under inflation targeting, resulting from capital equilibriation. This shift continues to 2, where the United States economy returns to a stable position of low inflation and unemployment resulting from noise at that low inflation rate. Figure 7 Unemployment and Inflation, Australia 197-25 14 13 12 74 75 76 1975-81 slope=-3.56 11 1 77 82 9 8 73 8 81 79 86 87 83 7 6 78 89 988 1985-95 slope=-2.17 85 71 72 5 4 7 1 95 84 3 2 1 2 5 3 4 1997-1 slope=-2.75 97 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1 11 12 99 98 96 91 94 92 93 A similar picture can be observed in Australia, with inflation feedback between 197 and 1975, decreases along the Fisher Line between 1975 and 1995, including a intermediate change in central bank policy between 1978 and 1986 until low inflation was reached in 1992. Capital equilibriation causes decreases in unemployment until the present. Australia now remains in a relatively stable state, with unemployment and inflation similar to the United States.

Figure 8 Unemployment and Inflation, Norway 1972-26 12 81 11 1 8 75 82 9 8 74 77 76 87 78 83 7 6 73 72 86 88 84 1981-93 slope=-2.26 5 85 4 79 89 9 3 1 91 2 98 996 97 3 95 9293 1 2 5 96 94 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 4 In Norway the central bank introduced strong contractionary policy in 1981, before Norway could experience unemployment resulting from inflation feedback. Between 1981 and 1993 a Fisher line is observed, resulting in 1992 in an unemployment rate that was still relatively low compared to the United States and Australia. From this time a slow shift to an unemployment rate similar to United States and Australia of around 4 or 5 percent is observed. On the other hand, Ireland experienced strong inflation feedback so that in 1986, after inflation targeting is introduced, the unemployment rate was above 17 percent. However until 1999, capital equilibriation was strong leading to an a similar position of low inflation and an unemployment rate of around 4 or 5 percent from 1999. Such consistent capital equilibriation behaviour across countries, towards a similar unemployment rate, is difficult to explain using market failure or natural rate of unemployment theories.

Figure 9 Unemployment and Inflation, Ireland 1983-26 1 9 8 7 83 1983-86 slope=-1.67 84 6 5 4 3 1 2 6 3 1999-26 slope=-3.56 89 9 91 92 87 85 86 2 1 5 4 99 98 97 96 95 94 93 88 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 Table 1 Unemployment rate 1995 2 Change in unemployment rate from 1995 to 2 Austria 5.9 5.8 -.1 Belgium 12.9 1.6-2.3 Denmark 1.2 5.8-4.4 Finland 15.4 9.1-6.3 France 11.6 1.3-1.3 Germany 8.1 8.7 +.6

Greece 1. 1.9 +.9 Ireland 12.2 5. -7.2 Italy 11.7 11.2 -.5 Netherlands 7.1 3.2-3.9 Norway 4.9 3.8-1.1 Portugal 7.2 4.3-2.9 Spain 22.7 14. -8.7 Sweden 7.7 4.5-3.2 United Kingdom 8.6 6. -2.6 Source: Gilles Saint-Paul, Why Are European Countries Diverging in Their Unemployment Experience?, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Autumn 24, vol. 18, no. 4, Table 1, p.5. Table 1 shows a similar situation for other European nations. Only Germany and Greece experienced increases in the unemployment rate between 1995 and 2, and both of these increases were less than 1 percent compared to more significant unemployment decreases in other European nations. Figure 1 Three Components of Phillips Curve

1. Full Employment (Including Frictional) 2. Fisher Line 3. Liquidity Trap In 1956 A.W.Phillips published empirical evidence that the relationship between unemployment and inflation is a curve. We show how a Phillips curve can be constructed from three components as shown in Figure 1. First we examine the full employment component. Figure 13 Unemployment and Inflation, All Countries

From Figure 13, there appears to be a lower bound on unemployment between 1 and 2 percent. This can be accounted for by frictional unemployment or 'between jobs' unemployment. At high rates of increase in flow of money, sufficient currency is added to the system to prevent unemployment resulting from noise. The vertical line on Figure 12 is the full employment rate, taking into account frictional unemployment. Component 2 is determined by the position of the Fisher line.

Figure 14 Unemployment and Inflation, United Kingdom 1913-1948 32 19 3 18 28 26 24 17 22 2 18 16 16 14 4 12 46 1 47 41 15 8 6 42 43 37 4 44 45 48 14 39 2 132 36 35 25 38 29-2 27 28 24 23 26 3 34 33 31 32-4 -6-8 -1-12 -14-16 -18-2 22-22 -24 21-26 2 4 6 8 1 12 14 16 18 2 22

Figure 15 Unemployment and Inflation, Japan 1971-26 22 2 74 18 16 14 12 1 73 75 8 76 77 8 6 71 4 2 72 81 78 79 9 91 82 89 83 85 84 92 93 88 8694 87 97 95 96 98 6 5 4 99 1 3 2-2 1 2 3 4 5 6 Figure 14 shows the empirical data that Phillips presented in his 1956 paper. Figure 15 shows recent Japan data. In both plots, we can observe a strong curvilinear relationship between unemployment and inflation. Between 1921 aqnd 1936 in the United Kingdom and in Japan from 1987 to the present, both countries experiences liquidity trap conditions. This suggests that liquidity trap conditions result in a horizontal relationship between inflation and unemployment. We show this on Figure 1 as a horizontal line. Taking these three components together explains a curvilinear relationship for those countries which have produced a clear Phillips curve.

Figure 16 Stable and Unstable Unemployment/Inflation Choices Unstable Selection Stable Selection The theory illuminates the problem in achieving full employment. We are able to select points along the Fisher line through central bank open-market-operations. At low inflations, the selection is stable, even if the Fisher line shifts from left to right depending on variations in the growth rate. At full employment selections, however, the Fisher line consistently shifts to the right, resulting in high inflation and unemployment. A full-employment selection, if adhered to, would result in hyperinflation. Economists such as Jevons, Marshall, Irving Fisher and more recently Robert Shiller have investigated what is called an indexed unit of account. Currency is written into contracts in a unit of account so that when payments are due, the value in contracts is converted using a measure such as the CPI into a currency value. In this way, the real value of payments is

determined regardless of any changes in the price level. Such a arrangement is used in Chile and is called the Unidad de Fomento. If all contracts are written in an indexed unit of account, then the inflation component in the interest rate is eliminated, the inflation feedback process becomes nonexistant, and it is now possible to select any points as shown in Figure 17. The black point shows a full-employment selection. The introduction of an indexed unit of account results in the possibility of central banks controlling for stable full employment. Figure 17 Full Employment Policy

References Fisher, Irving, 'A Compensated Dollar', The Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 27, no. 2 (February 1913) pp. 213-235. Fisher, Irving, 'A Statistical Relation between Unemployment and Price Changes', International Labour Review, vol. 13, no. 6 (June 1926), pp. 785-92, republished in The Journal of Political Economy, vol. 81, no. 2, part 1 (March-April 1973) pp. 496-52. Jevons, William Stanley, 'Money and the Mechanism of Exchange', Chapter XXV, 'A Tabular Standard of Value', D. Appleton and Co., New York, 1875, also available online at www.econlib.org. Lucas, Robert E. Jr., 'Nobel Lecture: Money Neutrality', The Journal of Political Economy, vol. 14, no. 4, (August 1996) pp. 661-682. Phillips, A.W., 'The Relation between Unemployment and the Rate of Change of Money Wage Rates in the United Kingdom, 1861-1957, Economica, New Series, vol. 25, no. 1, (November 1958) pp.283-299. Pigou (ed.), 'Memorials of Alfred Marshll', Macmillan & Co., London 1925. Shannon, Claude, 'The Mathematical Theory of Communication', University of Illinois, 1949. Shiller, Robert J., 'The New Financial Order: Risk in the 21st Century', Princeton University Press, 23, Chapter Fifteen, 'New Units of Measurement'.