Preface to Global imbalances. Is the world economy really at risk?, by Anton Brender and Florence Pisani

Similar documents
DEVELOPING COUNTRIES AND THE DOLLAR. C. P. Chandrasekhar and Jayati Ghosh

Ian J Macfarlane: Payment imbalances

Global Imbalances and the U.S. Current Account Deficit. Economics 826 January 2009

Macroeconomics in an Open Economy

Global Imbalances. January 23rd

"The Continuing Problem of China's Currency Management Policy"

Lower prices. Lower costs, esp. wages. Higher productivity. Higher quality/more desirable exports. Greater natural resources. Higher interest rates

A macroeconomic survey of Europe

CRS Report for Congress

Chapter 18. Openness in Goods and Financial Markets

Singapore Economic Review Conference (SERC) 2007

Lecture #8: How Scary is the US Trade Deficit?

Fallacies Behind the RMB Predictions

12 ECB GLOBAL IMBALANCES: RECENT DEVELOPMENTS AND POLICY REQUIREMENTS

Chapter 24 CRISES IN EMERGING MARKETS

The views expressed in this paper are those of the author(s) only, and the presence of them, or of links to them, on the IMF website does not imply

Are we in a cyclical downturn of the business cycle,

Capital Account Controls and Liberalization: Lessons for India and China

Fallacies Behind the RMB Predictions

The U.S. Current Account Balance and the Business Cycle

Period 3 MBA Program January February MACROECONOMICS IN THE GLOBAL ECONOMY Core Course. Professor Ilian Mihov

Chapter 4. Why Do Interest Rates Change? Chapter Preview

Short run prospects in Europe and the United States

A macroeconomic survey of Europe

June 24th, Rate Reversal. Author: Benjamin Struck President

14.05 Intermediate Applied Macroeconomics Problem Set 5

Fiscal Policy in a low interest rate environment

Keeping you informed matters

How Successful is China s Economic Rebalancing?*

INTERNATIONAL FINANCE. Objectives. Financing International Trade. Financing International Trade. Financing International Trade CHAPTER

Open Economy AS/AD: Applications

Masaaki Shirakawa: The transition from high growth to stable growth Japan s experience and implications for emerging economies

An Overview of World Goods and Services Trade

China s macroeconomic imbalances: causes and consequences. John Knight and Wang Wei

Developing futures to mitigates risks as China's economy shifts gear

The 2006 Economic Report of the President

Is China the Next Bubble?

Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit

Helpful Hint Fiscal Policy and the AS-AD Model

Eurasian Economic Union. Advantages and disadvantages

Sinology KEY QUESTIONS FOR CHINA INVESTORS IN 2015 PART II. by Andy Rothman. Why Do I Keep Saying China Won t Ease this Year?

WS32 Institutions of the financial sector

Lecture #2: Notes on Balance of Payments and Exchange Rates

Whither the US equity markets?

Global Imbalances and the Financial Crisis: Products of Common Causes

Hunting growth: Japanese outbound M&A on the rise

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHY IS THE DOLLAR SO HIGH? Martin Feldstein. Working Paper

The euro: Its economic implications and its lessons for Canada

Mr Thiessen discusses the euro: its economic implications and its lessons for Canada

Saving, Investment, and the Financial System

Rutgers University Spring Econ 336 International Balance of Payments Professor Roberto Chang. Problem Set 1. Name:

Global Markets. CHINA AND GLOBAL MARKET VOLATILITY.

Asia/Pacific Economic Overview

17.2 U.S. Government Spending and Revenue Introduction. Chapter 17 The Government and the Macroeconomy. In 2008, federal spending

Closed vs. Open Economies

Quantitative Easing Too Small to Fail Part IV Dr. Manuel E. Maldonado Cotto

International Finance

Class Notes. Intermediate Macroeconomics. Li Gan. Lecture 7: Economic Growth. It is amazing how much we have achieved.

Globalization and crises

Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit

The Global Recession of 2016

ASIAN WEEKLY ECONOMIC INSIGHTS

Gauging Current Conditions:

Econ 102 Final Exam Name ID Section Number

Emerging market central banks investment strategies: Tailwind for the euro?

TRUE FACTS AND FALSE PERCEPTIONS ABOUT FEDERAL DEFICITS" Remarks by Thomas C. Melzer Rotary Club of Springfield, Missouri December 6, 1988

The Government Deficit and the Financial Crisis

China might NEVER become the biggest

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances

Trade led Growth in Times of Crisis Asia Pacific Trade Economists Conference 2 3 November 2009, Bangkok. Session 1

trends by catherine l. mann

Measuring the off-balance-sheet wealth management business of commercial banks

18.1 Benefits of Trade 18.2 Trade Restrictions and Free-Trade Agreements 18.3 Balance of Payments 18.4 Foreign Exchange Rates

The Macro-economy and the Global Financial Crisis

To understand where the U.S. Economy is going, we need to understand where we have been

The U.S. Economy and Monetary Policy. Esther L. George President and Chief Executive Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City

Petrodollars, the Savings Bust, and the U.S. Current Account Deficit

Economy at Risk: The Growing U.S. Trade Deficit

Goals of Topic 8. NX back!! What is the link between the exchange rate and net exports? How do different policies affect the trade deficit?

Bourgeois Fantasies about Economic Bubbles

vox Research-based policy analysis and commentary from leading economists

The Spanish economy: situation and outlook XIV Día de los Economistas 2015/Colegio de Economistas de las Islas Baleares

Gaining Currency. The Rise of the Renminbi. Eswar S. Prasad. OUP UNCORRECTED PROOF REVISES, Thu Jul , NEWGEN

Theory of the rate of return

Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit

Exam Number. Section

Lecture 1. Global Imbalances

TOWARDS A REFORM OF THE GLOBAL RESERVE SYSTEM 1. Joseph E. Stiglitz Columbia University

ECO 209Y MACROECONOMIC THEORY AND POLICY. Term Test #3. February 12, 2018

Macroeconomic Measurement 3: The Accumulation of Value

Bruce Greenwald: The Crisis Bigger than Global Warming

Measuring China's Fiscal Policy Stance

Objectives for Class 26: Fiscal Policy

Stock Market Fluctuations

How understanding the business life cycle helps in credit assessment. from businessbankingcoach.com in association with

1. Record levels of American outward foreign direct investment from 2000 to 2009,

Global Imbalances and Current Account Imbalances

POST-CRISIS GLOBAL REBALANCING CONFERENCE ON GLOBALIZATION AND THE LAW OF THE SEA WASHINGTON DC, DEC 1-3, Barry Bosworth

I don't understand the argument that even though inflation is not accelerating, the world nevertheless suffers from "global excess liquidity":

Do Changes in Asset Prices Denote Changes in Wealth? When stock or bond prices drop sharply we are told that the nation's wealth has

Transcription:

Preface to Global imbalances. Is the world economy really at risk?, by Anton Brender and Florence Pisani Olivier Blanchard February 20, 2007 If, twenty years ago, you had asked economists whether globalization and financial integration would lead to large current account deficits in some countries, and large surpluses in others, they would have answered with a strong yes. But they would almost surely have gotten the sign wrong. They would have predicted that poor countries, with low saving and plenty of opportunities for investment would borrow funds from richer countries, and, symmetrically, rich countries, with higher saving and fewer investment opportunities would indeed be willing and eager to lend those funds. Nearly the opposite has happened. In 2006, the richest country in the world, the United States, borrowed close to $900 billion from the rest of the world. More than half of these funds were provided by countries in Asia and Latin America. Nearly one third came from China. Poor countries lending gigantic sums to large countries; the United States on a spending spree. Can we make sense of it all? Will it come to a crashing end? These are the questions taken up by Brender and Pisani. Their answers: Yes, there is some logic behind the apparent madness. And, no, with a bit of luck, things will work themselves out smoothly. I agree with both answers. How do we make sense of what is going on? The presumption that globalization should lead to an investment boom in poor countries was based on a simple idea: Poor countries have low 1

wages, but large access to state-of-the-art technology. What more attractive combination could there be when firms think about where to invest? This idea has turned out to be only partly right: Many things matter beyond wage costs: Property rights, the ability to enforce contracts, all play a central role in investment decisions, and poor countries are typically not very good in these dimensions. Investment is a risky activity. Whether firms can get the outside funds depends on the development of the financial system, its ability to take on risk, and to diversify or eliminate it to satisfy risk-averse savers. Again, poor countries are typically not very good in these dimensions. Sometimes their financial system takes on too much risk, leading to a crisis. The crisis in turn leads it to avoid risk, and in the process reduce investment. This is very much the story of Asia, both pre- and post-asian crisis. After having been burned in the 1990s, domestic financial intermediation institutions are reluctant to take risks, and this is one of the main reasons why investment in (non-china) Asia is low today. So, with a few exceptions, access to the world financial markets has not led to an investment boom in poor countries. The presumption that saving would be low in poor countries was based on an equally simple idea. When people s incomes are close to subsistence levels, they can hardly save. And if they can save, to the extent that they expect the future to be brighter, they will save less. Again, reality does not fit this simple idea: China s saving rate is one of the highest in the world. One of the main reasons is high household saving. With the shift to a market economy, the safety nets which used to be provided by state firms have largely disappeared. With little protection against health risks, the loss of a job, with the need to save for retirement, the need to save for education, Chinese people are saving nearly half of their income. The investment rate in China is high, but the saving rate is even higher. The result: China as a major supplier of funds to the rest of the world. Now turn to the other side, the US as the major borrower in the world. It is usual to blame the US budget deficit for the large US current account deficit. The apparent logic is again simple: Unless domestic savers are 2

willing to save more, the more the US government borrows, the more the United States as a whole has to borrow abroad. But the relation between budget deficits and current account deficits is far from simple, both in theory and in practice. In practice, US current account deficits started increasing in the 1990s just as the budget deficits were decreasing. And, as a matter of arithmetic, the budget deficit in 2006 was roughly equal to only one third of the current account deficit. So, while fiscal policy in the US should surely be less expansionary, the sources of the US current account deficit must be found primarily in private saving and investment. Private saving is indeed very low. Household saving in particular is close to zero. Are US consumers wildly irrational? The evidence is unclear. On the one hand, US consumers are indeed saving little out of their income. On the other hand, the large increases in their financial and housing wealth have more than compensated for their low saving. The large majority of Americans appear to have enough to finance their retirement. Combine this low saving with strong investment, reflecting technological progress and high profitability, and you have the other half of the equation, an excess of US investment over US saving, and the demand for the funds that the rest of the world wants to lend. Is there more to the story? Obviously yes. Three points are worth mentioning: First, and while they have less important roles, there are other players in this world game. For example, oil producers, having learned their lessons from previous episodes, are saving a large proportion of their higher oil incomes, leading to larger current account surpluses at home, and larger current account deficits in oil importing countries. Second, at a given interest rate, positive shifts in saving have exceeded shifts in investment, leading to a decline in the world interest rate: Riskless rates are low around the world, and this is what lies behind most of the increase in asset and housing prices. For the most part, what we see around the world are not speculative bubbles, but increases in fundamental values, driven by lower interest rates. Third, not only does the non-us world want to save more than it invests, but it prefers dollar to euro or yen assets. Why this is comes from a mix 3

of reasons, the liquidity of US government bond markets, the depth of the US equity markets, the weight of history in determining the currency composition of central bank reserves. The result is lower required rates of return on US assets than on non-us assets. And so, despite the fact that the United States has now been for many years a large debtor vis á vis the rest of the world, it only started to pay (slightly) more in interest income to the rest of the world than it received in 2006. How will it all end? With a bang, or with a long whisper? The way to answer the question is to think about each of the factors behind the current configuration, and what is likely to happen to it in the future. Given the economists record on exchange rate and other predictions, humility is of the essence. I believe however a number of things can be said: Sooner or later, the flows of funds to the United States will slow, and the US current account deficit will have to decrease. Indeed, eventually, the US trade deficit will have to turn into a surplus. How far in the future? My own sense is that much of it will have to happen over the coming decade: Chinese saving will decrease: The political pressure on the Chinese government to provide better insurance and health care is growing. As safety nets are improved, saving will decrease, domestic demand will increase. To control total demand, the Chinese government will let the RMB appreciate, reducing the Chinese current account surplus. The Asian financial system will improve, leading to higher investment. The US budget deficit will be reduced. Central banks will increase the proportion of non-dollar assets in their reserves. Euro markets will become more liquid and deeper, making Euro assets relatively more attractive for financial investors. All these factors will lead to a change in the configuration of saving and investment around the world, and to a decrease in US deficits. As this happens, we shall see a steady depreciation of the dollar, an appreciation of the RMB, and a likely appreciation of the euro and the yen. If this happens smoothly, central banks can handle the adjustment through interest rate changes. Will it happen smoothly, or will investors panic? One would be foolish to give an answer with much confidence, but my bet is on a slow and steady adjustment. 4

I hope I have given you a taste of the arguments developed by Brender and Pisani in their small and fascinating book. They give you the flesh and the details which I could not give here. They help you think about what may be the most complex and intellectually exciting economic developments of our times. I hope you enjoy your reading as much I did mine. Cambridge, Massachusetts, February 20, 2007 5