Lecture 3: Tax incidence

Similar documents
Sample Exam Questions/Chapter 7

Competitive Markets. Market supply Competitive equilibrium Total surplus and efficiency Taxes and subsidies Price maintenance Application: Imports

Intermediate Microeconomics

Chapter 2 Supply, Demand, and Markets SOLUTIONS TO EXERCISES

EQ: What is Price Elasticity of Supply?

MACROECONOMICS - CLUTCH CH. 6 - INTRODUCTION TO TAXES.

AS/ECON 4070 AF Answers to Assignment 1 October 2001

Does Congress decide who pays the taxes? 2013 Pearson

2c Tax Incidence : General Equilibrium

ALGEBRAIC REPRESENTATION

MICROECONOMICS - CLUTCH CH. 6 - INTRODUCTION TO TAXES AND SUBSIDIES

Lecture 6. Supply, demand, and government policies

Introduction to Microeconomics AP/ECON C Test #2 (c)

Chapter 12 TAXES AND TAX POLICY Principles of Economics in Context (Goodwin et al.)

Elasticity. The Concept of Elasticity

Market Demand Demand Elasticity Elasticity & Revenue. Market Demand cont. Chapter 15

Chapter 9. The Instruments of Trade Policy

Seminar on Public Finance

2 Maximizing pro ts when marginal costs are increasing

NAME: INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMIC THEORY FALL 2006 ECONOMICS 300/012 Midterm II November 9, 2006

2007 Thomson South-Western

If it is important to you, you will find a way If not, you will find an excuse. Frank Banks

Figure a. The equilibrium price of Frisbees is $8 and the equilibrium quantity is six million Frisbees.

PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM Welfare Analysis

why how price quantity

is a concept that relates the responsiveness (or sensitivity) of one variable to a change in another variable. Elasticity of A with respect to B = %

Economics 335 Problem Set 6 Spring 1998

Recitation #6 Week 02/15/2009 to 02/21/2009. Chapter 7 - Taxes

File: Ch02, Chapter 2: Supply and Demand Analysis. Multiple Choice

CHAPTER 17: PUBLIC CHOICE THEORY AND THE ECONOMICS OF TAXATION

AS/ECON AF Answers to Assignment 1 October Q1. Find the equation of the production possibility curve in the following 2 good, 2 input

1 Supply and Demand. 1.1 Demand. Price. Quantity. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 2 of the text.

The theory of taxation (Stiglitz ch. 17, 18, 19; Gruber ch.19, 20; Rosen ch.13,14,15)

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #9 - Monopoly

Lecture 12: Taxes. Session ID: DDEE. EC101 DD & EE / Manove Taxes & International Trade p 1. EC101 DD & EE / Manove Clicker Question p 2

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis

THE ELASTICITY OF DEMAND

Monopoly Chapter 24 (cont.)

Econ 301 Summer 2003 Asinski

SUPPLY, DEMAND, AND GOVERNMENT POLICIES

Second Quiz Review: Solutions Managerial Economics: Eco 685

Tax Incidence ADE Fall

ECON/MGMT 115. Industrial Organization

CH 8. Name: Class: Date: Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Lecture 6 Notes. Maria Zhu Duke University. November 16, 2016

1 Maximizing profits when marginal costs are increasing

Market Demand Demand Elasticity Elasticity & Revenue Marginal Revenue. Market Demand Chapter 15

ECON 312/302: MICROECONOMICS II Lecture 6: W/C 7 th March 2016 FACTOR MARKETS 1 Dr Ebo Turkson. Chapter 15. Factor Markets Part 1

CHAPTER 2 REVENUE OF THE FIRM

Derivations: LR and SR Profit Maximization

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Chapter 10 THE PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM COMPETITIVE MODEL. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Economics 101 Fall 2010 Homework #3 Due 10/26/10

Elasticity and Its Applications. Copyright 2004 South-Western

Answer ALL questions from Section A and ONE question from Section B. Section A weighs 60% of the total mark and Section B 40% of the total mark.

Chapter 3 Read this chapter together with unit 3 in the study guide. Applying the Supply-and- Demand Model

Incidence of Taxation

b) If the supply curve is horizontal, then an upward shift in the demand function will lead to a higher price and quantity in equilibrium.

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 November 2005

Basics of Economics. Alvin Lin. Principles of Microeconomics: August December 2016

CPR-no: 14th January 2013 Managerial Economics Mid-term

PROBLEM SET 7 ANSWERS: Answers to Exercises in Jean Tirole s Theory of Industrial Organization

Version 1 READ THESE INSTRUCTIONS CAREFULLY. DO NOT BEGIN WORKING UNTIL THE PROCTOR TELLS YOU TO DO SO

ANSWERS To next 16 Multiple Choice Questions below B B B B A E B E C C C E C C D B

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

SUPPLY AND DEMAND APPLICATION AND EXTENSIONS: THE IMPACT OF A TAX

3. After you have completed the exam, sign the Honor Code statement below.

Estimating Market Power in Differentiated Product Markets

EQ: What is Elasticity?

Simon Fraser University Department of Economics. Econ342: International Trade. Final Examination. Instructor: N. Schmitt

September-December 2016 Examinations ACCA F5 21. Many factors are relevant when considering what price to charge.

Assignment 5. Intermediate Micro, Spring Due: Thursday, April 10 th

Elasticity & Applications of Supply & Demand Analysis. UAPP693 Economics in the Public & Nonprofit Sectors Steven W. Peuquet, Ph.D.

Practice Test Microeconomics Chapter 6

EQ: How Do I Calculate Elasticity?

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text.

Introduction. Monopoly 05/10/2017

ECS ExtraClasses Helping you succeed. Page 1

Price Theory of Two-Sided Markets

Chapter 16: Equilibrium

Homework # 8 - [Due on Wednesday November 1st, 2017]

The Macroeconomic Policy Model

Microeconomics, IB and IBP

ECON. CHAPTER Elasticity of. McEachern Micro. Demand and Supply. Designed by Amy McGuire, B-books, Ltd.

Solutions to Assignment #2

Economics Honors Exam 2009 Solutions: Microeconomics, Questions 1-2

Microeconomic Analysis

AP Microeconomics Chapter 16 Outline

ECO 100Y L0101 INTRODUCTION TO ECONOMICS. Midterm Test #2

Final Exam - Solutions

Chapter 7 Pricing with Market Power SOLUTIONS TO EXERCISES

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis November 13, 2008 Professor John Parman. Midterm 2

Lecture 12: Taxes. Suppose in the graph, the government sets a price ceiling at $. Then, Price 240. Supply. Demand. 1,000 2,000 3,000 Quantity

OUTLINE October 4, Oligopoly. Monopolistic Competition. Profit Maximization 10/2/ :56 AM. Imperfect Competition, continued.

ECON 251 Exam 1 Pink Fall 2012

Market demand is therefore given by the following equation:

Taxation and Efficiency : (a) : The Expenditure Function

In Jormungand, Koko Hekmatyar is an arms dealer. Suppose she faces the market for Javelin ATGM missiles, and the demand is given by Px = 10,000-2Qx.

Elasticity and its Application

Lesson-36. Profit Maximization and A Perfectly Competitive Firm

Transcription:

Lecture 3: Tax incidence Economics 336/337 University of Toronto Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 1 / 18

Tax incidence in competitive markets What is the economic incidence of a tax on a single market i.e. who really pays the tax? Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 2 / 18

Tax incidence in competitive markets What is the economic incidence of a tax on a single market i.e. who really pays the tax? To answer, look at how prices change with the tax. Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 2 / 18

Tax incidence in competitive markets What is the economic incidence of a tax on a single market i.e. who really pays the tax? To answer, look at how prices change with the tax. Public Economics (Toronto) Figure : Tax incidence Tax Incidence in a competitive market 2 / 18

Incidence and elasticities In the previous example, supply was relatively elastic and tax was shifted forward to purchasers. What if demand is more elastic? Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 3 / 18

Incidence and elasticities In the previous example, supply was relatively elastic and tax was shifted forward to purchasers. What if demand is more elastic? Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 3 / 18

Algebraic approach We can generalize to any supply Q s (p) and demand Q d (p(1 + τ)) functions, where τ is percentage tax rate. Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 4 / 18

Algebraic approach We can generalize to any supply Q s (p) and demand Q d (p(1 + τ)) functions, where τ is percentage tax rate. Equilibrium consumer price solves Q d (p (1 + τ)) = Q s (p ). The tax causes percentage changes in demand and supply: Q d ( p Q d ɛ d p + τ ) 1 + τ Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 4 / 18

Algebraic approach We can generalize to any supply Q s (p) and demand Q d (p(1 + τ)) functions, where τ is percentage tax rate. Equilibrium consumer price solves Q d (p (1 + τ)) = Q s (p ). The tax causes percentage changes in demand and supply: Q d ( p Q d ɛ d p + τ ) 1 + τ Q s Q s ɛ s p p Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 4 / 18

Algebraic approach We can generalize to any supply Q s (p) and demand Q d (p(1 + τ)) functions, where τ is percentage tax rate. Equilibrium consumer price solves Q d (p (1 + τ)) = Q s (p ). The tax causes percentage changes in demand and supply: Solving for p : Q d ( p Q d ɛ d p + τ ) 1 + τ Q s Q s ɛ s p p Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 4 / 18

Algebraic approach We can generalize to any supply Q s (p) and demand Q d (p(1 + τ)) functions, where τ is percentage tax rate. Equilibrium consumer price solves Q d (p (1 + τ)) = Q s (p ). The tax causes percentage changes in demand and supply: Q d ( p Q d ɛ d p + τ ) 1 + τ Q s Q s ɛ s p p Solving for p : p p ɛd τ ɛ s + ɛ d 1 + τ Degree of forward shifting of tax is greater when ɛ s is Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 4 / 18

Algebraic approach We can generalize to any supply Q s (p) and demand Q d (p(1 + τ)) functions, where τ is percentage tax rate. Equilibrium consumer price solves Q d (p (1 + τ)) = Q s (p ). The tax causes percentage changes in demand and supply: Q d ( p Q d ɛ d p + τ ) 1 + τ Q s Q s ɛ s p p Solving for p : p p ɛd τ ɛ s + ɛ d 1 + τ Degree of forward shifting of tax is greater when ɛ s is large or ɛ d Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 4 / 18

Algebraic approach We can generalize to any supply Q s (p) and demand Q d (p(1 + τ)) functions, where τ is percentage tax rate. Equilibrium consumer price solves Q d (p (1 + τ)) = Q s (p ). The tax causes percentage changes in demand and supply: Q d ( p Q d ɛ d p + τ ) 1 + τ Q s Q s ɛ s p p Solving for p : p p ɛd τ ɛ s + ɛ d 1 + τ Degree of forward shifting of tax is greater when ɛ s is large or ɛ d small. Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 4 / 18

Perfect elasticity When supply is perfectly inelastic (vertical) or demand is perfectly elastic (horizontal) curve, the entire burden is borne by the supply side regardless of where the tax is applied. P S(p) = S(p t) P S(p t) S(p) D(p) D(p) X X Figure : Full backward shifting Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 5 / 18

Perfect elasticity When supply is perfectly inelastic (vertical) or demand is perfectly elastic (horizontal) curve, the entire burden is borne by the supply side regardless of where the tax is applied. P S(p) = S(p t) P S(p t) S(p) D(p) D(p) X X Figure : Full backward shifting When supply is perfectly elastic or demand is perfectly inelastic, then tax is fully borne by: Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 5 / 18

Perfect elasticity When supply is perfectly inelastic (vertical) or demand is perfectly elastic (horizontal) curve, the entire burden is borne by the supply side regardless of where the tax is applied. P S(p) = S(p t) P S(p t) S(p) D(p) D(p) X X Figure : Full backward shifting When supply is perfectly elastic or demand is perfectly inelastic, then tax is fully borne by: purchaser. Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 5 / 18

Perfect elasticity When supply is perfectly inelastic (vertical) or demand is perfectly elastic (horizontal) curve, the entire burden is borne by the supply side regardless of where the tax is applied. P S(p) = S(p t) P S(p t) S(p) D(p) D(p) X X Figure : Full backward shifting When supply is perfectly elastic or demand is perfectly inelastic, then tax is fully borne by: purchaser. Exercise: Draw the relevant graphs to show this. Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 5 / 18

Examples: Factor taxes The big taxes are on production factors, which tend to have very high or low elasticities, and very strong tax shifting. Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 6 / 18

Examples: Factor taxes The big taxes are on production factors, which tend to have very high or low elasticities, and very strong tax shifting. Examples: 1 A tax on residential properties in a city. Is the tax on rental properties borne by renters or landlords? Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 6 / 18

Examples: Factor taxes The big taxes are on production factors, which tend to have very high or low elasticities, and very strong tax shifting. Examples: 1 A tax on residential properties in a city. Is the tax on rental properties borne by renters or landlords? 2 A payroll tax on labour, when firms employ both capital and labour in production. Is this tax borne by workers or by firms (capital)? Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 6 / 18

Examples: Factor taxes The big taxes are on production factors, which tend to have very high or low elasticities, and very strong tax shifting. Examples: 1 A tax on residential properties in a city. Is the tax on rental properties borne by renters or landlords? 2 A payroll tax on labour, when firms employ both capital and labour in production. Is this tax borne by workers or by firms (capital)? 3 A payroll tax on firms in a single city in a metropolitan area. If firms (jobs) can easily move to the suburbs, who pays this tax? Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 6 / 18

Examples: Factor taxes The big taxes are on production factors, which tend to have very high or low elasticities, and very strong tax shifting. Examples: 1 A tax on residential properties in a city. Is the tax on rental properties borne by renters or landlords? 2 A payroll tax on labour, when firms employ both capital and labour in production. Is this tax borne by workers or by firms (capital)? 3 A payroll tax on firms in a single city in a metropolitan area. If firms (jobs) can easily move to the suburbs, who pays this tax? 4 A withholding tax on dividends paid to foreign shareholders of Canadian corporations. If Canada is a small open economy, who bears this tax? Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 6 / 18

Examples: Factor taxes The big taxes are on production factors, which tend to have very high or low elasticities, and very strong tax shifting. Examples: 1 A tax on residential properties in a city. Is the tax on rental properties borne by renters or landlords? 2 A payroll tax on labour, when firms employ both capital and labour in production. Is this tax borne by workers or by firms (capital)? 3 A payroll tax on firms in a single city in a metropolitan area. If firms (jobs) can easily move to the suburbs, who pays this tax? 4 A withholding tax on dividends paid to foreign shareholders of Canadian corporations. If Canada is a small open economy, who bears this tax? Hint: first consider a tax on all capital in a SOE. Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 6 / 18

Tax incidence over time Backward shifting may take an extreme form when taxes (or subsidies) affect asset values. Example: Consider a house that rents for $R t and pays $τ t in property taxes in year t = 1, 2,.... If the property has no alternative uses, its market value at date 0 is P 0 = t=1 where i is the interest rate. (Why?) R t τ t (1 + i) t Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 7 / 18

Present discounted value and the no arbitrage condition The formula says the market price of the house equals the present discounted value of rents less taxes. This can be derived from the condition that in equilibrium there can be no arbitrage gains from buying or selling houses. Proof: Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 8 / 18

Present discounted value and the no arbitrage condition The formula says the market price of the house equals the present discounted value of rents less taxes. This can be derived from the condition that in equilibrium there can be no arbitrage gains from buying or selling houses. Proof: In any period t, the cost of a bond-financed arbitrage must equal the returns: Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 8 / 18

Present discounted value and the no arbitrage condition The formula says the market price of the house equals the present discounted value of rents less taxes. This can be derived from the condition that in equilibrium there can be no arbitrage gains from buying or selling houses. Proof: In any period t, the cost of a bond-financed arbitrage must equal the returns: P t + (R t τ t ) = (1 + i)p t 1 Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 8 / 18

Present discounted value and the no arbitrage condition The formula says the market price of the house equals the present discounted value of rents less taxes. This can be derived from the condition that in equilibrium there can be no arbitrage gains from buying or selling houses. Proof: In any period t, the cost of a bond-financed arbitrage must equal the returns: P t + (R t τ t ) = (1 + i)p t 1 Rearranging, P t 1 = 1 1 + i P t + 1 1 + i (R t τ t ) Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 8 / 18

Present discounted value and the no arbitrage condition The formula says the market price of the house equals the present discounted value of rents less taxes. This can be derived from the condition that in equilibrium there can be no arbitrage gains from buying or selling houses. Proof: In any period t, the cost of a bond-financed arbitrage must equal the returns: P t + (R t τ t ) = (1 + i)p t 1 Rearranging, P t 1 = 1 1 + i P t + 1 1 + i (R t τ t ) Recursively substituting for t = 1, 2,... gives P 0 = 1 1 + i (R 1 1 τ 1 ) + (1 + i) 2 (R 2 τ 2 ) +... Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 8 / 18

A permanent increase in taxes τ, τ,... causes house price to fall by P 0 = t=1 τ (1 + i) t = τ i Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 9 / 18

A permanent increase in taxes τ, τ,... causes house price to fall by P 0 = t=1 τ (1 + i) t = τ i The initial owner bears the full present value burden of the permanent tax increase. The tax is capitalized into the asset value. Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 9 / 18

A permanent increase in taxes τ, τ,... causes house price to fall by P 0 = t=1 τ (1 + i) t = τ i The initial owner bears the full present value burden of the permanent tax increase. The tax is capitalized into the asset value. Other cases of capitalization 1 Municipal service differences capitalized into Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 9 / 18

A permanent increase in taxes τ, τ,... causes house price to fall by P 0 = t=1 τ (1 + i) t = τ i The initial owner bears the full present value burden of the permanent tax increase. The tax is capitalized into the asset value. Other cases of capitalization 1 Municipal service differences capitalized into house prices. Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 9 / 18

A permanent increase in taxes τ, τ,... causes house price to fall by P 0 = t=1 τ (1 + i) t = τ i The initial owner bears the full present value burden of the permanent tax increase. The tax is capitalized into the asset value. Other cases of capitalization 1 Municipal service differences capitalized into house prices. 2 Investment tax incentives capitalized into Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 9 / 18

A permanent increase in taxes τ, τ,... causes house price to fall by P 0 = t=1 τ (1 + i) t = τ i The initial owner bears the full present value burden of the permanent tax increase. The tax is capitalized into the asset value. Other cases of capitalization 1 Municipal service differences capitalized into house prices. 2 Investment tax incentives capitalized into share prices. Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 9 / 18

A permanent increase in taxes τ, τ,... causes house price to fall by P 0 = t=1 τ (1 + i) t = τ i The initial owner bears the full present value burden of the permanent tax increase. The tax is capitalized into the asset value. Other cases of capitalization 1 Municipal service differences capitalized into house prices. 2 Investment tax incentives capitalized into share prices. 3 Supply management policies capitalized into Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 9 / 18

A permanent increase in taxes τ, τ,... causes house price to fall by P 0 = t=1 τ (1 + i) t = τ i The initial owner bears the full present value burden of the permanent tax increase. The tax is capitalized into the asset value. Other cases of capitalization 1 Municipal service differences capitalized into house prices. 2 Investment tax incentives capitalized into share prices. 3 Supply management policies capitalized into licence values. Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 9 / 18

Irrelevance of statutory incidence Notice we have not considered the statutory incidence of the tax: i.e. who actually writes the cheque to government. Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 10 / 18

Irrelevance of statutory incidence Notice we have not considered the statutory incidence of the tax: i.e. who actually writes the cheque to government. Example Labour unions lobby hard to have payroll taxes (e.g. for health care) paid by employers, not employees, while business associations want the opposite. What difference would it make in our model to change the statutory incidence of a tax? Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 10 / 18

Irrelevance of statutory incidence Notice we have not considered the statutory incidence of the tax: i.e. who actually writes the cheque to government. Example Labour unions lobby hard to have payroll taxes (e.g. for health care) paid by employers, not employees, while business associations want the opposite. What difference would it make in our model to change the statutory incidence of a tax? 1 Tax on seller: consumer pays p and producer receives p t so equilibrium when D(p ) = S(p t). Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 10 / 18

Irrelevance of statutory incidence Notice we have not considered the statutory incidence of the tax: i.e. who actually writes the cheque to government. Example Labour unions lobby hard to have payroll taxes (e.g. for health care) paid by employers, not employees, while business associations want the opposite. What difference would it make in our model to change the statutory incidence of a tax? 1 Tax on seller: consumer pays p and producer receives p t so equilibrium when D(p ) = S(p t). 2 Tax on buyer: pays p to seller and t to government, and equilibrium when D(ˆp + t) = S(ˆp). Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 10 / 18

Irrelevance of statutory incidence Notice we have not considered the statutory incidence of the tax: i.e. who actually writes the cheque to government. Example Labour unions lobby hard to have payroll taxes (e.g. for health care) paid by employers, not employees, while business associations want the opposite. What difference would it make in our model to change the statutory incidence of a tax? 1 Tax on seller: consumer pays p and producer receives p t so equilibrium when D(p ) = S(p t). 2 Tax on buyer: pays p to seller and t to government, and equilibrium when D(ˆp + t) = S(ˆp). So p = ˆp + t: Statutory incidence is irrelevant. Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 10 / 18

Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 11 / 18

Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 12 / 18

Statutory incidence: Qualifications Our result on the irrelevance of statutory incidence requires that prices can fully and immediately adjust in response to the tax. So in cases with imperfect adjustment, statutory incidence can matter: 1 regulated prices e.g. minimum wage, rent control 2 long-term contracts 3 menu costs of price adjustments Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 13 / 18

Statutory incidence: Qualifications Our result on the irrelevance of statutory incidence requires that prices can fully and immediately adjust in response to the tax. So in cases with imperfect adjustment, statutory incidence can matter: 1 regulated prices e.g. minimum wage, rent control 2 long-term contracts 3 menu costs of price adjustments Exercise If workers are paid the minimum wage, how does economic incidence of a payroll tax change with the statutory incidence? Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 13 / 18

Incidence in non-competitive markets People often find it hard to accept that business tax cuts get shifted on to consumers in this way. One common objection is that some markets are not perfectly competitive, so incentives to pass on tax changes may differ. If sellers have market power, how does incidence change? Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 14 / 18

Incidence in non-competitive markets People often find it hard to accept that business tax cuts get shifted on to consumers in this way. One common objection is that some markets are not perfectly competitive, so incentives to pass on tax changes may differ. If sellers have market power, how does incidence change? Example Markets for cigarettes and gasoline appear to be non-competitive and highly taxed. Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 14 / 18

Incidence in non-competitive markets People often find it hard to accept that business tax cuts get shifted on to consumers in this way. One common objection is that some markets are not perfectly competitive, so incentives to pass on tax changes may differ. If sellers have market power, how does incidence change? Example Markets for cigarettes and gasoline appear to be non-competitive and highly taxed. There is some evidence that these taxes are overshifted: prices on average rise by more than 100% of the tax increase. Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 14 / 18

A monopolist has constant marginal cost and q inverse demand curve P(Q). Profit is P(Q)Q (c + t)q Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 15 / 18

A monopolist has constant marginal cost and q inverse demand curve P(Q). Profit is P(Q)Q (c + t)q The profit-maximizing quantity solves MR(Q ) = P(Q ) + P (Q )Q = c + t Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 15 / 18

A monopolist has constant marginal cost and q inverse demand curve P(Q). Profit is P(Q)Q (c + t)q The profit-maximizing quantity solves MR(Q ) = P(Q ) + P (Q )Q = c + t If we write MR(Q) = P [ ( 1 Q )] P = P(Q) (1 1ɛ ) P Q d Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 15 / 18

A monopolist has constant marginal cost and q inverse demand curve P(Q). Profit is P(Q)Q (c + t)q The profit-maximizing quantity solves MR(Q ) = P(Q ) + P (Q )Q = c + t If we write MR(Q) = P [ ( 1 Q )] P = P(Q) (1 1ɛ ) P Q d then we have P(Q ) = c + t 1 1/ɛ d. Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 15 / 18

A monopolist has constant marginal cost and q inverse demand curve P(Q). Profit is P(Q)Q (c + t)q The profit-maximizing quantity solves MR(Q ) = P(Q ) + P (Q )Q = c + t If we write MR(Q) = P [ ( 1 Q )] P = P(Q) (1 1ɛ ) P Q d then we have P(Q ) = c + t 1 1/ɛ d. A competitive firm sets p = MC + t, but a monopolist sets MR = MC + t. The degree of tax shifting then depends on the relationship between demand and marginal revenue, as well as on elasticities. Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 15 / 18

What does this condition imply for tax shifting? Cases: 1 Suppose that elasticity of demand is constant. Then price is a constant markup (greater than zero) over marginal cost c + t. For P(Q ) > 0 we must have ɛ d > 1 (monopolist operates on the elastic portion of the demand curve) so 1 1/ɛ d < 1: Price rises by Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 16 / 18

What does this condition imply for tax shifting? Cases: 1 Suppose that elasticity of demand is constant. Then price is a constant markup (greater than zero) over marginal cost c + t. For P(Q ) > 0 we must have ɛ d > 1 (monopolist operates on the elastic portion of the demand curve) so 1 1/ɛ d < 1: Price rises by more than 100 per cent of the tax. Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 16 / 18

What does this condition imply for tax shifting? Cases: 1 Suppose that elasticity of demand is constant. Then price is a constant markup (greater than zero) over marginal cost c + t. For P(Q ) > 0 we must have ɛ d > 1 (monopolist operates on the elastic portion of the demand curve) so 1 1/ɛ d < 1: Price rises by more than 100 per cent of the tax. 2 Suppose instead that demand is linear: P(Q) = A bq. Then P/ Q = b and the first-order condition is which simplifies to (A bq) bq = c + t, Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 16 / 18

What does this condition imply for tax shifting? Cases: 1 Suppose that elasticity of demand is constant. Then price is a constant markup (greater than zero) over marginal cost c + t. For P(Q ) > 0 we must have ɛ d > 1 (monopolist operates on the elastic portion of the demand curve) so 1 1/ɛ d < 1: Price rises by more than 100 per cent of the tax. 2 Suppose instead that demand is linear: P(Q) = A bq. Then P/ Q = b and the first-order condition is (A bq) bq = c + t, which simplifies to P = A 2 + c + t 2. Price rises by exactly Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 16 / 18

What does this condition imply for tax shifting? Cases: 1 Suppose that elasticity of demand is constant. Then price is a constant markup (greater than zero) over marginal cost c + t. For P(Q ) > 0 we must have ɛ d > 1 (monopolist operates on the elastic portion of the demand curve) so 1 1/ɛ d < 1: Price rises by more than 100 per cent of the tax. 2 Suppose instead that demand is linear: P(Q) = A bq. Then P/ Q = b and the first-order condition is (A bq) bq = c + t, which simplifies to P = A 2 + c + t 2. Price rises by exactly one-half of the tax. Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 16 / 18

Quantitative incidence analysis Quantitative incidence analysis estimates how tax burdens vary by income class a full measure of progressivity of the tax system. Standard approach uses: data on statutory tax rates on income, sales, property, etc. data on ownership of capital and labour, expenditure patterns by income group a theory of economic incidence of various taxes Simulates effects on each income group of removing all taxes. How progressive is the Canadian tax system overall? Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 17 / 18

Average tax rates by income group, Canada, 1988 Source: Vermaeten, Gillespie and Vermaeten (1994) Public Economics (Toronto) Tax Incidence 18 / 18