The trade-offs associated with getting an education

Similar documents
University of California, Davis Department of Economics Giacomo Bonanno. Economics 103: Economics of uncertainty and information PRACTICE PROBLEMS

ECONOMICS OF UNCERTAINTY AND INFORMATION

ANSWERS TO PRACTICE PROBLEMS oooooooooooooooo

DARTMOUTH COLLEGE, DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 21. Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02. Topic 5: Information

Chapter 33: Public Goods

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

CHAPTER 4 INTEREST RATES AND PRESENT VALUE

Not 0,4 2,1. i. Show there is a perfect Bayesian equilibrium where player A chooses to play, player A chooses L, and player B chooses L.

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 12

The Earnings Function and Human Capital Investment

Lecture Note 23 Adverse Selection, Risk Aversion and Insurance Markets

Professor Scholz Posted March 29, 2006 Economics 441, Brief Answers for Problem Set #3 Due in class, April 5, 2006

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems

$1,000 1 ( ) $2,500 2,500 $2,000 (1 ) (1 + r) 2,000

EXAMPLE OF FAILURE OF EQUILIBRIUM Akerlof's market for lemons (P-R pp )

Radner Equilibrium: Definition and Equivalence with Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium

Topics in Informational Economics 2 Games with Private Information and Selling Mechanisms

Introduction. Education: Stylized Facts. The Schooling Model 4/15/2010. Chapter 6. Present Value Calculations

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

Economics. Earnings and Discrimination. In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions: N. Gregory Mankiw

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Economics 742 Homework #4

March 30, Why do economists (and increasingly, engineers and computer scientists) study auctions?

Chapter 7 Human Capital

Upon Death. Military Papers

1 Two Period Exchange Economy

15 Week 5b Mutual Funds

How do we cope with uncertainty?

Department of Economics Shanghai University of Finance and Economics Intermediate Macroeconomics

Regret Minimization and Security Strategies

Corporate Financial Management. Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure

MetLife Retirement Income. A Survey of Pre-Retiree Knowledge of Financial Retirement Issues

Microeconomic Theory August 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program

Golden rule. The golden rule allocation is the stationary, feasible allocation that maximizes the utility of the future generations.

Professor Scholz Posted November 27, 2006 Economics 441, Problem Set #4 Due in class, Monday, December 11, 2006

Economics 109 Practice Problems 1, Vincent Crawford, Spring 2002

Rural Financial Intermediaries

Applied Economics. Quasi-experiments: Instrumental Variables and Regresion Discontinuity. Department of Economics Universidad Carlos III de Madrid

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants

Section J DEALING WITH INFLATION

MA300.2 Game Theory 2005, LSE

AFM 371 Winter 2008 Chapter 19 - Dividends And Other Payouts

Answers To Chapter 12

University of Hong Kong

Adverse Selection: The Market for Lemons

Chapter 9 THE ECONOMICS OF INFORMATION. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE

Managerial Accounting Prof. Dr. Varadraj Bapat Department of School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy

Web Appendix. Inequality and the Measurement of Residential Segregation by Income in American Neighborhoods Tara Watson

10.1 Elimination of strictly dominated strategies

Problem Set 5 Answers

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 5

THE FINANCIAL PLANNER S GUIDE TO STUDENT LOAN REFINANCING

Chapter 23: Choice under Risk

SIMULATION RESULTS RELATIVE GENEROSITY. Chapter Three

ECON 459 Game Theory. Lecture Notes Auctions. Luca Anderlini Spring 2017

ECON DISCUSSION NOTES ON CONTRACT LAW. Contracts. I.1 Bargain Theory. I.2 Damages Part 1. I.3 Reliance

worthwhile for Scotia.

ECON 301: General Equilibrium V (Public Goods) 1. Intermediate Microeconomics II, ECON 301. General Equilibrium V: Public Goods

Problems with seniority based pay and possible solutions. Difficulties that arise and how to incentivize firm and worker towards the right incentives

Outline Introduction Game Representations Reductions Solution Concepts. Game Theory. Enrico Franchi. May 19, 2010

Smart strategies for maximising retirement income 2012/13

Monthly Treasurers Tasks

Lecture Notes on Anticommons T. Bergstrom, April 2010 These notes illustrate the problem of the anticommons for one particular example.

January 26,

ECON Microeconomics II IRYNA DUDNYK. Auctions.

The Theory of Unconventional Monetary Policy

Binary Options Trading Strategies How to Become a Successful Trader?

Economics and Computation

THE UNIVERSITY OF TEXAS AT AUSTIN Department of Information, Risk, and Operations Management

Excel-Based Budgeting for Cash Flows: Cash Is King!

Almost everyone is familiar with the

Testimony. on Behalf of Aon Hewitt. By Alison T. Borland, FSA. Vice President Retirement Solutions & Strategies. Before. U.S. Senate HELP Committee

IB Interview Guide: Case Study Exercises Three-Statement Modeling Case (30 Minutes)

AN ANALYSIS OF THE HIGHER EDUCATION REFORMS

Economic Development Fall Answers to Problem Set 5

Chapter 19: Compensating and Equivalent Variations

Gender Inequality in US and Japanese Businesses. Akin Can Akdogan Liliya Temes Jieun Yang

Medicare Beneficiaries and Their Assets: Implications for Low-Income Programs

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Social Choice

Reemployment after Job Loss

Exploring the Effect of Wealth Distribution on Efficiency Using a Model of Land Tenancy with Limited Liability. Nicholas Reynolds

Business Analysis for Engineers Prof. S. Vaidhyasubramaniam Adjunct Professor, School of Law SASTRA University-Thanjavur

Name. FINAL EXAM, Econ 171, March, 2015

Chapter 18: The Correlational Procedures

Financial Management Practices of New York Dairy Farms

Online Appendix from Bönke, Corneo and Lüthen Lifetime Earnings Inequality in Germany

MARKET REACTION TO & ANTICIPATION OF ACCOUNTING NUMBERS

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 3: Strategic Form Games - Solution Concepts

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati.

Chapter Six Probability

Part 4: Market Failure II - Asymmetric Information Adverse Selection and Signaling

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy

The Volatility Trap: Why Staying the Course Makes Sense

Cascades in Experimental Asset Marktes

The Irrelevance of Corporate Governance Structure

CABARRUS COUNTY 2008 APPRAISAL MANUAL

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

PROJECT MANAGEMENT. Trying to manage a project without project management is like trying to play a football game without a game plan

Transcription:

Department of Economics, University of California, Davis Professor Giacomo Bonanno Ecn 103 Economics of Uncertainty and Information The trade-offs associated with getting an education Usually higher education is associated with higher income. The main reason why people go to college is that they expect to earn more once they obtain their degree than they would with just a high-school diploma. Consider the hypothetical decision of Ann, who is currently employed with a salary of $35,000 per year. She is considering quitting her job and getting a loan to finance an MBA degree that is expected to take two years. After she gets her MBA, she expects to earn $55,000. Tuition, fees, books and other expenses amount to $25,000 per year. Is it worthwhile for Ann to get an MBA? Consider the following table. A B C E Year MBA cost/benefit net benefit (B this row + B previous row) current job net benefit (D this row + D previous row) Loss from MBA relative to current job 1-25,000-25,000 35,000 35,000-60,000 2-25,000-50,000 35,000 70,000-120,000 3 55,000 5,000 35,000 105,000-100,000 4 55,000 60,000 35,000 140,000-80,000 5 55,000 115,000 35,000 175,000-60,000 6 55,000 170,000 35,000 210,000-40,000 7 55,000 225,000 35,000 245,000-20,000 8 55,000 280,000 35,000 280,000 0 9 55,000 335,000 35,000 315,000 20,000 10 55,000 390,000 35,000 350,000 40,000 The above table seems to suggest that it makes economic sense for Ann to get the MBA only if she plans to work at least 7 years after she gets the degree (thus looking at the 9 th year from now): it is only on the 9 th year from now that the sum of the net benefits is higher if she pursues an MBA than if she stays with her current employer. However, the calculations in the above table are not correct, for two reasons. First of all, the loan will most probably involve interest payments and the repayment of the loan will be spread out over the years (whereas in the above table it is implicitly assumed that Ann will repay the entire loan of $50,000 on the third year, without any interest added to the principal). Secondly, the calculations in the above table make a questionable assumption about how Ann feels about the future: according to the table, she does not discount the future at all, so that $1,000 received ten years from now is worth exactly the same to her as $1,000 received right now. This is typically not the case for most individuals: for almost everyone the value of $1,000 ten years from now is much less than $1,000 today. Impatience can be captured using a discount factor. Let r denote the yearly discount rate, which is generally a number greater than zero, simi- Page 1 of 7

x lar to an interest rate. Then the value of $x received one year in the future is and the value 1 + r x of $x received t years in the future is. (1 ) t + r Let us re-examine Ann s choice when her discount rate is 10% (so that $1,000 a year 1,000 from now is the same as $ = $909.10 now and $1,000 two years from now is the same as 1,000 $ = $826.45 now, etc). Furthermore, suppose that starting from year 3 (the first year on the 2 new job, after obtaining the MBA) she will have to repay her loan in the mount of $8,000 per year over a period of 8 years (thus a total of $64,000). A B C D E F G Year MBA income Present value of row B pesent value (sum of column C values up to this row) current job income Present value of row C pesent value (sum of column F values up to this row) 1 0 0 0 35,000 31,818 31,818 2 0 0 0 35,000 28,926 60,744 3 47,000 35,312 35,312 35,000 26,296 87,040 4 47,000 32,102 67,413 35,000 23,905 110,945 5 47,000 29,183 96,597 35,000 21,732 132,678 6 47,000 26,530 123,127 35,000 19,757 152,434 7 47,000 24,118 147,245 35,000 17,961 170,395 8 47,000 21,926 101,758 35,000 16,328 186,722 9 47,000 19,933 189,104 35,000 14,843 201,566 10 47,000 18,121 207,224 35,000 13,494 215,060 11 55,000 19,277 226,502 35,000 12,267 227,327 12 55,000 17,525 244,026 35,000 11,152 238,479 13 55,000 15,932 259,958 35,000 10,138 248,617 14 55,000 14,483 274,441 35,000 9,217 257,834 With discounting it is only in the 10 th year of work after the MBA (12 th from now) that the MBA starts paying off. 55, 000 8, 000 Explanation about calculations: the entry in row 4, column C is = 32,102, 4 55, 000 8, 000 the entry in row 8, column C is = 21,926, 8 the entry in row 5, column D is: 0 + 0 + 35,312 + 32,102 + 29,183 = 96,597 the entry in row 10, column F is = 13,494 10 the entry in row 4, column G is: 31,818 + 28,926 + 26,296 + 23,905 = 110,945, etc. Page 2 of 7

Some Real-World Numbers The following table reports the median salary level for men with different levels of education in 2008 (http://www.infoplease.com/ipa/a0883617.html ). Highest Education Level Attained Median yearly 2008 Salary ($) No high school 27,964 Some high school but no diploma 33,435 High school grad 43,165 Some college but no degree 50,359 Associate's degree 54,861 Bachelor's degree 82,197 Master's degree 99,516 Professional degree 166,065 Doctoral degree 129,773 A bachelor s degree yields 90% more than a high school diploma. Completing college increases salary by 63% relative to only a few years of college. Estimates for discount rates van also be obtained. In 1991 the Department of Defense was authorized to reduce active duty strength by 25%. This was a difficult task because ordinarily in the military retirement benefits can be collected only after 20 years of service. For this reason the military, instead of just firing people, they created incentives for soldiers to leave. Military personnel who voluntarily departed were offered their choice of two pay packages, both based on the number of years of service and annual salary. One package offered a lump sum payment, and the other offered a set of annual payments. For example, an army sergeant with 12 years of service could get a $35,549 lump sum or an annual payment of $5,925 for 24 years. The discounted value of the stream of annual payments is the same as the lump sum if the discount rate is 19%. Over 90% of the enlisted men who chose to leave the military took the lump sum, revealing that their personal discount rate was higher than 19%. This is a very high discount rate. For comparison purposes, the interest rate at the time was about 7%. Page 3 of 7

EDUCATION AS A SIGNAL Why is higher education associated with higher salaries? One explanation is that education increases the productivity of individuals. Another explanation is that education, although ineffective in terms of affecting productivity, can be used as a signal to make individuals selfselect. Let us consider an example. There are two types of workers. Both workers have 40 years until retirement. There are two types of jobs. One pays $4,000 per month, but it requires a college degree. The other pays $3,200, and it requires only a high school diploma. College tuition and fees cost $40,000 per year. To ease calculations, assume that the future is not discounted. If both types require the same amount of time to complete college, then both types will decide to do exactly the same thing. But suppose that whatever characteristic makes highproductivity type workers have high productivity also allows them to finish college in four years, whereas whatever characteristic makes low-productivity type workers have low productivity also makes them take five years to finish college. Now there is a reason why high-productivity workers might choose to go to college but low-productivity workers will not. Consider the choice facing high-productivity workers. If they choose not to go to college, they can work for a full 40 years at $3,200 per month. Their total income from not going to college is (40)(12)($3,200) = $1,536,000. If they choose to go to college for four years, they must pay $40,000 per year for each of those four years, but then they earn $4,000 per month for the remaining 36 years. Their total income is therefore (4)(-$40,000) + (36)(12)($4000) = $1,568,000. If they go to college, their lifetime income is higher by $32,000. Now look at the choice faced by low-productivity workers. Their total income from not going to college is the same as for high-productivity workers, $1,536,000. If they choose to go to college, however, they must go for five years, paying $40,000 per year in tuition. Afterward they work for the remaining 35 years and earn $4,000 per month. Their total lifetime income when they go to college is (5)(-$40,000) + (35)(12)($4,000) = $1,480,000. If they go to college, their lifetime income is lower by $56,000. In this example, high-productivity workers choose to go to college but low-productivity workers do not. Consequently, the firm can tell apart the two types of workers; the highproductivity workers have college degrees, but the low-productivity workers do not. By choosing to go to college, the high-productivity workers are able to distinguish themselves from their lowproductivity counterparts and benefit from having high productivity. In the example, low-productivity workers need one more year to complete college than highproductivity workers, and that extra year costs $40,000 in tuition and (12)($3,200) = $38,400 in foregone wages for a total of $78,400. The situation considered by Spence, typified by the job market, is one where some relevant information is available to only one side of the market (the potential employees), while the other side of the market (the employer) has to try to infer this information from some observable characteristics. Spence assumes that the population is divided in two groups: those with low productivity and those with high productivity. The employer does not know in advance whether a given applicant belongs to one group or the other and it will take some time before the true productive ability of the employee is revealed. It is therefore in the employer s interest to try to guess the applicant s productive ability on the basis of some characteristics that the employer himself can observe. Those observable characteristics which are under the control of the Page 4 of 7

applicant (like education, the way he dresses, etc.) are called signals, whereas those characteristics which cannot be modified by the applicant (e.g. sex, race, etc.) are called indexes. It is clear that not every observable characteristic will be considered relevant by the employer. For example, the color of the applicant s eyes (an index) or the color of his socks (a signal) are unlikely to be considered important by the employer, while the level of education is likely to be considered relevant. Therefore, within the set of potential signals the employer will select those that - in the light of her previous experience - seem to be correlated with productive capabilities. This selection represents the beliefs of the employer. Suppose the employer believes that education is positively correlated with productivity. Then she will offer a higher salary to those applicants who have acquired more education. We therefore have a first flow of information, from the employer to the prospective employees: by differentiating salaries on the basis of some characteristics the employer reveals her beliefs. Employer s initial beliefs Selection of signals within the set of all potential signals Employees read the employer s beliefs in the wage schedule she offers Let us now turn to the other side of the market: potential employees. A potential employee will face the problem of communicating his unobservable qualities to the employer. The only way he can do this is by using some observable characteristic that can be modified by him, that is, by using a signal. In choosing a signal the potential employee must take into account two factors: 1) signaling costs, that is, the cost of acquiring that particular signal; 2) the employer s beliefs, revealed by the wage schedule (it would be a waste of money and/or effort to acquire a signal which is known to be considered irrelevant by the employer, i.e. a characteristic to which the employer does not pay attention). We therefore have a second flow of information, from the applicant to the employer: Page 5 of 7

At this point the wage contract will be stipulated and after a while the employer will be able to observe the employee s productivity and to relate it to the signal chosen by the employee. The employer s beliefs can then be confirmed (if, for example, the more educated employees are more productive) or falsified (if the more productive are the less educated employees, or if there is no difference in productivity between more and less educated employees). In the first case the employer will not modify her (beliefs and) offered wage schedule, while in the second case she will. We define the first case to be a signaling equilibrium. That is, a signaling equilibrium is a situation in which employers beliefs about the relationship between productivity (which cannot be observed at the time of hiring) and education (or any other signal) are confirmed by the results of her hiring in the market. Thus in equilibrium employers beliefs are self-confirming: the initial beliefs, based on some data (past experience), generate new data which does not contradict them and hence the beliefs tend to persist. The simplest version of Spence s model is based on two main assumptions, one of which is crucial and seems to be necessary for the phenomenon of signaling to take place, whereas the second can be relaxed without affecting the qualitative nature of the results. CRUCIAL ASSUMPTION. The crucial assumption is that signaling costs are negatively correlated with productive ability. That is, people with higher productivity incur lower costs of acquiring education (or the alternative relevant signal) than those with lower productivity. By costs of acquiring education we do not necessarily mean monetary costs: it could simply be effort (e.g. measured in number of hours of study necessary to learn a particular thing). RELAXABLE ASSUMPTION. The second assumption, which is not essential, is that education does not affect productivity. Spence himself developed a model in which this assumption is relaxed. MAIN RESULTS. The two main results of the model are: (1) there may be multiple equilibria (and even an infinite number of them); (2) equilibria may be (and in general are) Pareto inefficient. The second result needs some explanation. First of all, it can easily be understood why the inefficiency occurs. Since the main hypothesis is that of asymmetric information it is not legitimate to compare the signaling equilibrium with a perfect information equilibrium. So the benchmark is represented by the situation where no signaling takes place and employers -- not being able to distinguish between more productive and less productive applicants and not having any elements on which to base a guess -- offer the same wage to every applicant, equal to the average productivity. Call this the non-signaling equilibrium. In a signaling equilibrium (where employers beliefs are confirmed, since less productive people do not invest in education, while the more productive do) everybody may be worse off than in the non-signaling equilibrium. This occurs if the wage offered to the non-educated is lower than the average productivity (= wage offered to everybody in the non-signaling equilibrium) and that offered to the educated people is higher, but becomes lower (than the average productivity) once the costs of acquiring education Page 6 of 7

are subtracted. The possible Pareto inefficiency of signaling equilibria is a strong result and a worrying one: it means that society is wasting resources in the production of education. However, it is not per se enough to conclude that education (i.e. the signaling activity) should be eliminated. The result is not that, in general, elimination of the signaling activity leads to a Pareto improvement: Spence simply pointed out that this is a possibility. What is a general result is that within the set of possible equilibria (recall that multiple equilibria represent the rule and not the exception) some are Pareto superior to others. That is, a Pareto ranking of the signaling equilibria is normally possible. This is a strong result, because it goes against one of the main results of the Arrow-Debreu model. In the Arrow-Debreu model multiple equilibria are possible, but each equilibrium is Pareto efficient and therefore equilibria are not Pareto comparable. The informational impact of indexes. So far we only considered signals, that is, those observable characteristics that can be modified by the agents concerned. The observable characteristics which cannot be modified, like sex, race, nationality, etc., are called indexes. The question that the presence of indexes gives rise to is: can the informational structure of the market have the effect of persistently and consistently discriminating between objectively identical individuals? We can imagine that the population is divided into two groups of equal size: Whites and Blacks. Within each group we have an equal proportion of low-productivity and high-productivity individuals. Signaling (education) costs are different for low- and high-productivity people, but people with the same level of productivity have the same signaling costs, no matter whether they are white or black. Assume also that people with the same productivity have the same preferences and the same objective: to maximize their income net of signaling costs. Therefore the index (race, say) should be absolutely irrelevant: it is a general principle of economics that people with the same opportunity sets and the same preferences will make similar decisions and end up in similar situations. In our model people with the same level of productivity face the same maximization problem, with the same data, and therefore should make the same decisions concerning education, no matter whether they are white or black. The informational structure of the market, however, can destroy this principle. If the employer believes that race (besides education) is correlated with productivity, she might offer a wage schedule which is differentiated on the basis of race and education. Her beliefs may force high-productivity black people to invest in education more than their white counterpart, that is, more than the high-productivity Whites. The reason why this situation can persist is that employers will interpret the incoming data separately for the two groups of Whites and Blacks because they believe that race is a splitting factor. If different levels of education were associated with the same observed level of productivity within the same group, employers would be forced to revise their beliefs. That is, if within the group of Whites different levels of education were accompanied by the same observed productivity, then employers would conclude that, at least above a certain level, education no longer increases productivity. But since Blacks and Whites are judged separately and independently (data on Whites is not used to classify Blacks and vice versa) employers can consistently think that Blacks need to acquire more education than their white counterpart in order to compensate for a genetic handicap. As before, employers beliefs may force Blacks to invest more in education than Whites, thereby confirming employers beliefs, despite the fact that those beliefs have no objective grounds. Thus Blacks end up being over-qualified for their jobs as compared to Whites. Page 7 of 7