PREFERENTIAL TRADING ARRANGEMENTS

Similar documents
The Relative Significance of EPAs in Asia-Pacific

Legal Review of FTA Tariff Negotiations

APEC AND PROGRESS TOWARD BOGOR GOALS

tariff global business nontariff barriers multinational corporation quota direct foreign investment trade barriers voluntary export restraints

Division on Investment and Enterprise

The Relative Significance of EPAs in Asia-Pacific

Exploring Global Business

Chapter 5. Partial Equilibrium Analysis of Import Quota Liberalization: The Case of Textile Industry. ISHIDO Hikari. Introduction

Analysis of Regional Investment Frameworks Worldwide

Advancing Good Corporate Governance by Promoting Utilization of the OECD Principles of Corporate Governance

Japan s New Trade Policy in Asia-Pacific

The Next-Generation Interactive APEC Tariff Database

Entrepreneurs, E commerce, and SMEs in APEC

Plurilateralism: A New Way of Trade Liberalism?

Why Corporate Governance is Important in APEC Economies

Global Economic Management and Asia s Responsibility Masahiro Kawai Asian Development Bank Institute

Re: Consulting Canadians on a possible Canada-ASEAN Free Trade Agreement

AUSTRALIA S POLICIES TOWARDS PROTECTION AND FREE TRADE

EU Trade Policy and CETA

ECON CHAPTER. McEachern Micro. International Trade. Designed by Amy McGuire, B-books, Ltd.

Economic Impact of Canada s Participation in the Comprehensive and Progressive Agreement for Trans-Pacific Partnership

A world in transition: PwC s 2017 APEC CEO Survey, November APEC CEO Survey. The Philippines findings.

A world in transition: PwC s 2017 APEC CEO Survey, November APEC CEO Survey. Malaysia s findings.

Harnessing Globalisation to Build a Better World for the Benefit of All. Yose Rizal Damuri Centre for Strategic and International Studies

Is Southeast Asia Still Too Dependent on U.S. Growth? Claire Innes Asia-Pacific Group Global Insight

APEC Development Outlook and the Progress of Regional Economic Cooperation and Integration

Introduction. Institute for International Economics Institute for International Economics

TPP11 Agreement in Principle: Japan s Role in Mega-regional Trade Agreements

The Impact of Free Trade Agreements in Asia

Comments in Response to Executive Order Regarding Trade Agreements Violations and Abuses Docket No. USTR

A world in transition: PwC s 2017 APEC CEO Survey, November APEC CEO Survey. The United States findings.

External Trade. EU TRADE & INVESTMENT POLICY & THE ROLE OF FTAs. ASEAN OECD INVESTMENT POLICY CONFERENCE November 2010

Japan-ASEAN Comprehensive Economic Partnership

2017 APEC CEO Survey Key Findings

Regional Integration Arrangements in Economic Development

Subject Index. Asian economies: GDP growth rates ( ) ; moves toward economic integration, See also East Asian countries

2010/IEG/WKSP1/002 Overview of IIAs and Treaty-Based Investment Disputes

Regional Trade and Economic Integration

FREE TRADE AGREEMENTS ANALYSIS

Economy Report - China

Facultad de Ciencias Económicas y Empresariales TRABAJO FIN DE GRADO GRADO EN ECONOMÍA INTERNACIONAL. Economic effects of bilateral trade agreements:

A world in transition: PwC s 2017 APEC CEO Survey, November APEC CEO Survey. Australia s findings.

Pharmaceutical Regulatory and Compliance Congress

CHAPTER 16 International Trade

UNITED NATIONS CONFERENCE ON TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT THE POTENTIAL FOR GSTP TRADE EXPANSION. Note prepared by the UNCTAD secretariat

FAQ: Forces in the Global Market

I IB Economics (Groups III and VI): Grade 11

AQA Economics A-level

RIETI Special Seminar. The New Landscape of World Trade with Mega-FTAs and Japan's Strategy. Handout. URATA Shujiro

Compendium of Auto Taxes in APEC Region

China s FTA Arrangement with Other Countries and. Its Prospect

INTERNATIONAL TRADE. Xie, Yiqing

Green trade liberalisation - Green Goods Initiative

The European Union Trade Policy

Rina Oktaviani Bogor Agricultural University, Indonesia

The Rise Of Regionalism In The Multilateral System And Features Of Preferential Trade Agreements In Asia And The Pacific

No October 2013

Chapter 3. Exploring Global Business

The Rise Of Regionalism In The Multilateral System And Features Of Preferential Trade Agreements In Asia And The Pacific

CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web

INTERNATIONAL TAX PLANNING. Singapore Domestic Law And Treaties SHANKER IYER FCA

ASIA IN THE WORLD ECONOMY: THREE POLICY CHALLENGES

CASE FAIR OSTER. International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism. Trade Surpluses and Deficits

Beyond the Uruguay Round

Asia and the Pacific: Economic Outlook and Drivers

Presentation by Economy Under Review - Chile

TPP, RCEP and Prospects for Eventual Convergence Robert Scollay NZPECC and APEC Study Centre, University of Auckland

Japan s FTA Strategy. August 7, Shujiro URATA Waseda University

2. LEGAL FRAMEWORK (1) EXISTING GATT/WTO PROVISIONS ON RTAS

ANALYSIS OF JAPAN S EXISTING AND FORTHCOMING FREE TRADE AGREEMENTS IN THE ASIA PACIFIC AND GLOBAL CONTEXT

Volume Author/Editor: Takatoshi Ito and Anne O. Krueger, Eds. Volume URL:

Services Trade: Essential Fuel for U.S. and Global Economic Growth

2007/SOM2/IEG-GOS/WKSP/002a Services in International Investment Agreements (IIA) - Presentation

Session 1 : Economic Integration in Asia: Recent trends Session 2 : Winners and losers in economic integration: Discussion

The Importance of CJK FTA for the Development of Trilateral Cooperation

On the Comparison of Safeguard Mechanisms of FTAs

Impacts of East Asian Integration on Vietnam: A CGE Analysis

Economic Outlook and Risks in the APEC Region

Click here to advance to the next slide.

APEC, East Asia Consortium and Global Imbalance

Moving towards a Common External Tariff Regime in ASEAN. Draft Final Report

International Economics

Reviewing the Importance. for Indonesia

SETTLEMENT OF DISPUTES

CASE FAIR OSTER PRINCIPLES OF MICROECONOMICS E L E V E N T H E D I T I O N. PEARSON 2014 Pearson Education, Inc.

Economic Impact of Canada s Potential Participation in the Trans-Pacific Partnership Agreement

Appendix A Specification of the Global Recursive Dynamic Computable General Equilibrium Model

Course Economics and Business Management Prof. Dr. Marius Dannenberg. Chapter 3 Markets and Government in the Global Economy

Asia-Pacific Trade Briefs: Hong Kong, China

Comment on Masaki Kuwahara A Search for Potential Female Labor Forces in Japan s Aging Society Challenges for Prime Minister Yukio Hatoyama

Asian Insights Third quarter 2016 Asia s commitment in policies and reforms

Environmental Goods Agreement (EGA) negotiations Civil Society Dialogue meeting 13 September 2016

Department of Foreign Affairs and Trade

Event 1. Module 2. The Converging Strands Between Trade and Investment Session Two: The mega regionals, impacts for members and non-members

2016/MRT/012 Session 3

Can Regionalism Work? Caroline Freund

ANNUAL SESSION OF THE PARLIAMENTARY CONFERENCE ON THE WTO Geneva, 1-2 December 2006

EFTA FREE TRADE RELATIONS

Economic Integration in South East Asia and the Impact on the EU

CFRED The Trans Pacific Partnership Impact and Implications. Assessing the content from a business perspective

Transcription:

PREFERENTIAL TRADING ARRANGEMENTS The Treaty of Rome, reached in 1957, set in motion a process of integrating the economies of Western Europe. This process has culminated with the European Union which is beginning to achieve a level of economic integration just short of that in the US. The student is encouraged to visit the EU s homepage at EUROPA - European Union website, the official EU website on the web. In 1988 the US signed a free trade agreement with Canada. In 1994 the agreement was extended to include Mexico. With concurrent trade liberalization in the rest of Latin America, there is a momentum that may lead to a Western Hemispheric trade bloc. The Bush and Clinton administrations have advocated the expansion of NAFTA into the Trade Bloc of the Americas, but resistance by labor groups in the US has stalled progress. NAFTA s homepage at www.nafta-secalena.org is also interesting reading. The countries of the Pacific Rim already in the political union called ASEAN - Association of South East Asian Nations - are slowly progressing in forming a free trade agreement between them. On a broader scale APEC, the Asian Pacific Economic Cooperation, includes not only the ASEAN nations but all Pacific Rim countries. Current APEC membership includes Australia, Brunei, Canada, Chile, People's Republic of China, Hong Kong, Indonesia, Korea, Japan, Malaysia, Mexico, New Zealand, Papua New Guinea, the Philippines, Singapore, Chinese Taipei, Thailand, and the United States of America. What are the implications of this regionalization on continued liberalization of international trade? This is a controversial topic. The two sides of the issue give opposing answers to the following two questions. Does regionalization mean the abandonment of WTO (GATT)? Will regionalization help or hinder the goal of global free trade? What is important is that regionalization is occurring and we need to have an understanding of its implications. There are several types of preferential trading arrangements. These are based on the level of integration among participating countries. These are listed below in order of the level of economic integration from least to most. A free trade agreement is the removal of barriers of trade between members. It still requires border checks between members since individual countries still have different trade relations with the rest of the world. This leads to what is known as the transshipment problem. Transshipment is when goods are shipped through a third country. A Trade Blocs page 1

foreign exporter in order to avoid high tariffs would export its goods to the member country with TRADE BLOCS Andean Group Arab Maghreb Union Asia Pacific Economic Cooperation Forum APEC Association of Southeast Asian Nations ASEAN Caribbean Community and Common Market CARICOM Central American Common Market Commonwealth of Independent States CIS Economic Community of Central African States CEEAC Economic Community of West African States ECOWAS European Free Trade Association EFTA European Union EU Latin American Integration Association LAIA North American Free Trade Agreement NAFTA South Asian Association for Regional Cooperation SAARC Southern Cone Common Market MERCOSUR members of the customs union. the lowest tariff rates and then ship the product to other member countries with relatively higher tariff rates. To avoid this problem, free trade agreements usually contain local content regulations. Customs unions not only have removal of trade barriers the same as FTA but they have a higher level of integration by including a common external tariff. With a common external tariff, all members adopt the same trade policies with the rest of the world. This does away with the transshipment problem since tariff rates are the same across all A common market has the same provisions as a customs union but also eliminates barriers to factor movements among its members. This is a significant jump in the level of integration. Labor is now free to migrate between countries in a common market. An economic union, the European Union for example, augments the level of integration found in a common market. It requires the coordination of economic policy among its members. This may take the shape of a common currency or restrictions on fiscal policy. As we move up the level of economic integration the greater will be the loss of national sovereignty for the individual member. A country s ability to set its own course diminishes as policymaking is done at the union level. THEORY OF TRADE BLOCS The formation of a trade bloc is achieved by granting preferential treatment to member nations as opposed to non-members. The realignment of countries into a trade bloc will have effects that are both immediate and also that develop over time. Trade Blocs page 2

Static effects The static effect leads to a change in the trade patterns among members as well as with nonmember countries. We use the welfare economic tools of consumer and producer surplus to analyze the implications of forming a trade bloc. The change in the patterns of trade has two major static effects, one that leads to a more efficient allocation of resources, and the other which is movement away from global comparative advantage. Trade creation, which increases efficiency in the allocation of resources, arises from the removal of trade barriers between member countries. The major result of this is, barring any other impediments, that resources among member countries will be applied to activities for which they have the lowest opportunity costs among S the member nations, in essence to their comparative advantages. P* + t P* A B C D qs qst qdt qd Quantity Figure 1 Suppose there are two countries in a trade bloc, the US and Mexico. Further suppose that Mexico is a lower cost producer of an item. Thus the US would import the good. Figure 1 portrays the US s demand and supply of the good. With a tariff, imports are restricted to qdt-qst. The elimination of the US tariff (t) on Mexican imports, leads to a gain for US consumers of the areas A+B+C+D. Of these, A and C represent transfers for producers and government, respectively. Hence the net gain which accrues to the country are areas B and D which results from the elimination of deadweight loss. This is similar to our previous discussion of the costs of a tariff. D The other static effect, trade diversion, leads to a less efficient allocation of resources. The discussion of trade diversion requires introducing an outside non-member nation into the analysis. In essence by giving preferential treatment to member countries over non-members, the possibility Trade Blocs page 3

exists that production of the good will shift from the lowest cost producer to a higher cost producer. This would represent a shift away from comparative advantage and a less efficient allocation of resources. Suppose there are three countries, the US, Mexico and Chile. Of these, let Chile be the lowest cost producer of the good, while the US is the highest cost producer. In Figure 2 Chile s price (Pc) is lower than Mexico s (Pm), whereas the US autarkic price (Pa) is higher than both the others. Pm + t Pc + t Pm Pc Figure 2 A B qs qst C E Sa D Da Quantity qdt qd Prior to the US entering a trade bloc with Mexico, Chile has both the comparative advantage as well as the competitive advantage in producing and selling the good. Competitive advantage is defined here as the full price of the good to US consumers. This would be inclusive of taxes and tariffs. With a uniform tariff against both Mexico and Chile, Chile s competitive price (Pc + t) would still be lower than Mexico s competitive price (Pm + t). In this case, the US will import the good from Chile. If the US and Mexico form a trade bloc exclusive of Chile, the set of relevant prices to US consumers changes because the tariffs on Mexican goods are eliminated. This gives Mexico the competitive advantage even though Chile has a comparative advantage. Now, with Pm being less than Pc+t, the good will be imported from Mexico instead of Chile. So, as a result of the trade bloc, production of the good shifts away from the lowest cost producer, Chile, to the higher cost producer, Mexico. This represents a movement away from comparative advantage and leads to a less efficient allocation of resources. The welfare implications require comparing consumer and producer surpluses before and after the formation of the trade bloc. Initially, US consumers paid Pc+t for the good and the US government earned tariff revenues of t*(q dt -q st ) given by areas C+E. With the formation of the trade bloc, price fell to Pm when the tariff was eliminated. Consumers in the US gain areas A+B+C+D of which A and C represent transfers from producers and government, respectively. Government lost all tariff revenue. Area C is transferred to consumers and area E represents a loss not being captured by Trade Blocs page 4

anyone. Areas B + D represented the deadweight loss of having the tariff which now goes to consumers because of the trade bloc. Therefore the net gain to society is the sum of areas B+D less area E. Should area E be greater than B+D, then the US could be made worse off for having joined the trade bloc. The degree of trade diversion will depend upon two factors: the level of protection levied against non-member nations, and the differential in the costs of production between the low-cost member producer and the lowest-cost non-member producer. What is important is a comparison of the competitive costs between the two. The country that will prevail, after all is said and done, is the one that can provide the good to US consumers the most cheaply. Mexico has the advantage of not having the tariff but Chile has the lower cost of production. For trade diversion to occur, Chile has the comparative advantage ( Pm > Pc) but Mexico has the competitive advantage (Pc + t > Pm). With this last statement, the greater the difference between Pc+t and Pm, the greater the scope for trade diversion. Subtracting Pm from Pc+t and rearranging terms gives the price spread of (Pc-Pm) + t. The larger this number, the greater the possibilities for trade diversion. Note that we have two counteracting forces. The tariff (t) is a positive number and so the greater the preferential treatment accorded to the member nation the more likely trade diversion will occur. The first term represents the differential in the cost of production between Chile and Mexico. Since Chile has the comparative advantage, it is a negative number. If Chile s costs of production are less than Mexico s by an amount greater than the tariff, [ -(Pc-Pm) > t ], then Chile can absorb the tariff and still retain the competitive advantage and no trade diversion occurs. But, as either the tariff rises or the cost differential narrows, the greater the price spread and the scope for trade diversion. In a world of growing regionalization where industrial countries are including middle-income countries in trade blocs, the implications for trade diversion are enormous. For example, NAFTA s combining the US and Mexico will lead to a great deal of trade diversion from nonmember countries with similar cost structures as Mexico. The advantages that accrue to Mexico will be at the expense of other middle- income countries, particularly of the Pacific Rim and Latin America. Trade Blocs page 5

Dynamic Effects Joining a trade bloc increases the size of the market that a firm can sell to. This has important implications with regards to economies of scale, especially for smaller countries. A small country may not have sufficient market demand for a firm to fully capture economies of scale. In Europe s situation with many small countries, there was a high degree of redundancy in the number of firms, each servicing domestic markets. Each firm was in essence inefficient in that the size of the domestic market did not allow it to expand production sufficiently to enjoy the low costs of largescale production. With the formation of the EU, the number of firms will decrease but the size of the remaining firms will expand, creating efficiency. Reports about the European Union estimate the gains from economies of scale will lead to about a 3% expansion of European production. Increasing market size will also diminish the market power of individual firms. By opening up markets, domestic firms will face greater competition. Monopoly power will fade as a result, and domestic firms will have an incentive to increase productivity through implementing newer technology or better management. In situations where partner countries are dissimilar in capital endowments, there may also exist possibilities for investment. Capital will find the highest return. In general this is where capital is scarce. Trade Blocs page 6