Effects of monetary policy shocks on the trade balance in small open European countries

Similar documents
IMPACT OF SOME OVERSEAS MONETARY VARIABLES ON INDONESIA: SVAR APPROACH

The Price Puzzle and Monetary Policy Transmission Mechanism in Pakistan: Structural Vector Autoregressive Approach

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD

Interpreting sterling exchange rate movements

New evidence on the effects of US monetary policy on exchange rates

Misspecification, Identification or Measurement? Another Look at the Price Puzzle

QED. Queen s Economics Department Working Paper No Monetary Transmission Mechanism in a Small Open Economy: A Bayesian Structural VAR Approach

THE ROLE OF EXCHANGE RATES IN MONETARY POLICY RULE: THE CASE OF INFLATION TARGETING COUNTRIES

HONG KONG INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY RESEARCH

Asian Economic and Financial Review EMPIRICAL TESTING OF EXCHANGE RATE AND INTEREST RATE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS IN CHINA

The International Transmission of Euro Area Monetary Policy Shocks. by Nils Jannsen and Melanie Klein

Delayed Overshooting: Is It an 80s Puzzle?

Information from "nancial markets and VAR measures of monetary policy

The Credit Channel in a Small, Open Economy

Liquidity Matters: Money Non-Redundancy in the Euro Area Business Cycle

Not all international monetary shocks are alike for the Japanese economy

THE POLICY RULE MIX: A MACROECONOMIC POLICY EVALUATION. John B. Taylor Stanford University

A Threshold VAR Model of Interest Rate and Current Account: Case of Turkey

Economics Letters 108 (2010) Contents lists available at ScienceDirect. Economics Letters. journal homepage:

MONETARY ECONOMICS Objective: Overview of Theoretical, Empirical and Policy Issues in Modern Monetary Economics

The Current Account and Real Exchange Rate Dynamics in African Countries. September 2012

COLUMBIA UNIVERSITY GRADUATE SCHOOL OF BUSINESS. Professor Frederic S. Mishkin Fall 1999 Uris Hall 619 Extension:

Using Exogenous Changes in Government Spending to estimate Fiscal Multiplier for Canada: Do we get more than we bargain for?

Course Outline and Reading List

The Changing Macroeconomic Response to Stock Market Volatility Shocks *

On the size of fiscal multipliers: A counterfactual analysis

Is the Exchange Rate a Shock Absorber or Source of Shocks? New Empirical Evidence

working Sources of Business Cycles in Korea and the United States by David Altig and Alan C. Stockman FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

Global and National Macroeconometric Modelling: A Long-run Structural Approach Overview on Macroeconometric Modelling Yongcheol Shin Leeds University

Does the Confidence Fairy Exist?

International Finance: Reading List Economics 642: Winter 2004 Linda Tesar

Inflation Persistence and Relative Contracting

MONETARY POLICY TRANSMISSION MECHANISM IN ROMANIA OVER THE PERIOD 2001 TO 2012: A BVAR ANALYSIS

Effects of Optimal Monetary Policy Rules on Welfare in a Small Open Economy: A Simulation Analysis

Effectiveness of monetary policy under different levels of capital flows for an emerging economy: Turkey

Monetary Policy Shocks in the Euro Area and Global Liquidity Spillovers

Monetary policy transmission in Switzerland: Headline inflation and asset prices

Monetary Policy and Long-term U.S. Interest Rates

On the sources of business cycles in the G-7

Iranian Economic Review, Vol.15, No.28, Winter Business Cycle Features in the Iranian Economy. Asghar Shahmoradi Ali Tayebnia Hossein Kavand

Recent developments in the euro area suggest. What caused current account imbalances in euro area periphery countries?

Bachelor Thesis Finance ANR: Real Estate Securities as an Inflation Hedge Study program: Pre-master Finance Date:

Asian Economic and Financial Review SOURCES OF EXCHANGE RATE FLUCTUATION IN VIETNAM: AN APPLICATION OF THE SVAR MODEL

Hideki Nishigaki Hitotsubashi University. Abstract

Uncertainty and the Transmission of Fiscal Policy

Exchange Rates and Uncovered Interest Differentials: The Role of Permanent Monetary Shocks. Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé and Martín Uribe

Bank Lending Shocks and the Euro Area Business Cycle

International Monetary Theory and Policy Economics 5602

Reassessing Exchange Rate Overshooting in a Monetary Framework

International Monetary Transmission, a Factor-Augmented Vector Autoregressive (FAVAR) Approach: The Cases of Mexico and Brazil

A Test of Two Open-Economy Theories: The Case of Oil Price Rise and Italy

Effects of U.S. Quantitative Easing on Emerging Market Economies

UCD CENTRE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH WORKING PAPER SERIES

Inflation Targeting in Korea: A Model of Success?

Vector Autoregression Model of Monetary Policy for India and the Case of Inflation Targeting 1. Introduction

Zhenyu Wu 1 & Maoguo Wu 1

SOME PARTICULARITIES OF THE MONETARY TRANSMISSION CHANNELS IN ROMANIA

Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle. Is This Time Different? Raju Huidrom University of Virginia. Midwest Macro Conference

Has the Inflation Process Changed?

Measuring Monetary Policy in Emerging Market Countries: The Case Turkey

Identifying of the fiscal policy shocks

Real and nominal effects of central bank monetary policy $

New Open Economy Macroeconomics: Evidence from an Empirical Test on South Asian Economic Data

3. Measuring the Effect of Monetary Policy

The Effects of Japanese Monetary Policy Shocks on Exchange Rates: A Structural Vector Error Correction Model Approach

5. STRUCTURAL VAR: APPLICATIONS

Current Account and Real Exchange Rate Dynamics in Indonesia

Testing the Stickiness of Macroeconomic Indicators and Disaggregated Prices in Japan: A FAVAR Approach

Rethinking the Link Between Exchange Rates & Inflation: Misperceptions and New Approaches

Structural Vector Autoregressive Analysis of Monetary Policy in Thailand

International Monetary Theory and Policy ECON 5602 S

Teaching Inflation Targeting: An Analysis for Intermediate Macro. Carl E. Walsh * First draft: September 2000 This draft: July 2001

Test of the bank lending channel: The case of Hungary

Productivity, monetary policy and financial indicators

A Reply to Roberto Perotti s "Expectations and Fiscal Policy: An Empirical Investigation"

Growth Rate of Domestic Credit and Output: Evidence of the Asymmetric Relationship between Japan and the United States

Topic 8: Financial Frictions and Shocks Part1: Asset holding developments

What Macroeconomic Risks Are (not) Shared by International Investors?

CONFIDENCE AND ECONOMIC ACTIVITY: THE CASE OF PORTUGAL*

Are international business cycles different under fixed and flexible exchange rate regimes?

Discussion of DSGE Models for Monetary Policy. Discussion of

Monetary and Fiscal Policy Switching with Time-Varying Volatilities

The Impact of an Increase In The Money Supply and Government Spending In The UK Economy

The implementation of monetary policy in the Euroarea, United Kingdom and USA: Evidence from financial crisis period*

Teaching Inflation Targeting: An Analysis for Intermediate Macro. Carl E. Walsh * September 2000

Asian Economic and Financial Review MONETARY POLICY TRANSMISSION AND BANK LENDING IN SOUTH KOREA AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS. Yu Hsing

Foreign exchange rate and the Hong Kong economic growth

Monetary Economics Semester 2, 2003

No Matthias Neuenkirch. Monetary Policy Transmission in Vector Autoregressions: A New Approach Using Central Bank Communication

The source of real and nominal exchange rate fluctuations in Thailand: Real shock or nominal shock

Oil Shocks and the Zero Bound on Nominal Interest Rates

THE CONCEPT OF globalization has recently been the subject of considerable. International Evidence on the Determinants of Trade Dynamics

If the Fed sneezes, who gets a cold?

Structural Cointegration Analysis of Private and Public Investment

Not-for-Publication Appendix to:

Is the Exchange Rate a Shock Absorber or a Source of Shocks? New Empirical Evidence

International Economics Fall 2011 Exchange Rate and Macro Policies. Paul Deng Oct. 4, 2011

Financial Factors in Business Cycles

Identifying Monetary Policy in. Open Economies

ECON : Topics in Monetary Economics

Transcription:

Economics Letters 71 (2001) 197 203 www.elsevier.com/ locate/ econbase Effects of monetary policy shocks on the trade balance in small open European countries Soyoung Kim* Department of Economics, 225b DKH, University of Illinois at Urbana Champaign, 1407 W. Gregory Dr., Urbana, IL 61801, USA Received 17 April 2000; accepted 7 November 2000 Abstract The effects of monetary policy shocks on trade balance (in volume, unit value, and total nominal value) are examined in France, Italy, and the UK using VAR models. The results are consistent with the expenditureswitching effect, but there is little evidence of the J-curve effect. 2001 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. Keywords: Monetary policy shocks; Expenditure-switching effect; VAR; Trade balance; Terms of trade JEL classification: C30; E52; F41 1. Introduction This paper documents empirical evidence of the effects of monetary policy shocks on the trade balance in small open European countries (Italy, France, and the UK) for the recent period. First, we document empirical evidence of the effects of monetary policy shocks on the trade balance over time. Second, we examine the effects of monetary policy shocks on related variables such as terms of trade, real exchange rate, and nominal exchange rate to better understand detailed monetary transmission mechanisms. Third, we examine the magnitude of the contribution of monetary policy shocks to trade statistics. Finally, based on the evidence, we address several questions of interests to academics in the field of open economy macro and monetary economics and to policy makers. There have been many empirical investigations in this area. However, the evidence is based on specific theoretical models, which may not serve as data-oriented empirical evidence or the evidence *Tel.: 11-217-356-9291; fax: 11-217-333-1398. E-mail address: kim11@uiuc.edu (S. Kim). 0165-1765/ 01/ $ see front matter 2001 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. PII: S0165-1765(01)00364-0

198 S. Kim / Economics Letters 71 (2001) 197 203 1 provides the limited evidence on the detailed transmission mechanism. In addition, there is little empirical evidence on small open economies such as Italy, France, and UK. Regarding empirical methodology, newly developed models in the VAR literature on identifying monetary policy shocks are employed. Specifically, we modify the VAR models which have been successful in identifying monetary policy shocks in small open economies such as in the work of Kim (1999) and Kim and Roubini (2000). These models employ minimal identifying restrictions which do not depend on specific theoretical models. Consequently, we are able to document data-oriented evidence on international monetary transmissions. Section 2 explains the empirical model. Section 3 discusses the empirical evidence of the effects of the monetary policy shocks on the trade balance. Section 4 summarizes the results. 2. Empirical model In the model, the data vector is hr, M, CPI, IP, WR, CMPW, X1, X2j, where R is the short term interest rate, M is a monetary aggregate, CPI is the consumer price index, IP is industrial production, WR is the world short-term interest rate, CMPW is the world export commodity price index in terms 2 of domestic currency, and X1 and X2 are trade statistics. The first four variables are essential in identifying monetary policy shocks. The next two variables are included in order to control for the systematic component of the policy rule (inflationary and world shocks) and isolate exogenous 3 monetary policy changes. The empirical model imposes (non-recursive) zero restrictions on the contemporaneous structural parameters. For the restrictions on the contemporaneous structural parameters, we follow the general idea of Kim (1999) and Kim and Roubini (2000). Note that we do not impose any restrictions on lagged structural parameters. The following equations summarize our identification scheme. 1 g12 0 0 g15 g16 0 0 R R er g 1 g g 0 0 0 0 M M e 21 23 24 M 0 0 1 g g 0 0 0 CPI CPI e 34 35 CPI 0 0 0 1 g 0 0 0 IP IP e 45 5 G(L) 1 IP (1) 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 WR WR e WR g61 g62 g63 g64 g65 1 0 0 CMPW CMPW ecmpw g71 g72 g73 g74 g75 g76 1 0 X1 X1 ex1 g81 g82 g83 g84 g85 g86 g87 1 X2 X2 ex2 1 Examples of past works are studies in Bryant et al. (1988), Betts and Devereux (2000), Kim and Roubini (2000), Clarida and Gali (1994), among many others. 2 We use M02 for the UK and M1 for France and Italy. We use the average of the US Federal Funds rate and the German short-term interest rate as the proxy for the world interest rate. As suggested by Kim and Roubini (2000) and Clarida et al. (1997), it is important to control for the US and German monetary policy for these European countries. 3 In selecting the empirical model, we experiment with several identification schemes that were suggested by previous researchers (such as Sims (1992), Christiano et al. (1998), Kim (1999), and Kim and Roubini (2000)), and then select the identification scheme which does not produce any puzzling impulse responses of the first six variables as impulse responses to monetary policy shocks.

S. Kim / Economics Letters 71 (2001) 197 203 199 where e, e, e, e, e, e, e, and e are structural disturbances. In particular, e is R M CPI IP WR CMPW X1 X2 R interpreted as monetary policy shocks. The first equation in (1) is the monetary reaction function. The monetary authority is assumed to set the interest rate after observing the current value of money, CMPW, and the world interest rate but not the current values of output nor the price level. This assumption is based on the fact that we assume information delays, such that data on money, commodity price, and the world interest rate are 4 available within a month, but data on output and the price level are not. The second equation is a money demand equation, representing that the demand for real money balances depends on real income and the nominal interest rate. The fifth equation assumes that the world interest rate is contemporaneously exogenous to all variables in the system, that is, an individual small open economy cannot affect the world interest rate contemporaneously. The third and fourth equations represent the sluggish real sector. Real activity is 5 assumed to respond to monetary policy and financial signals only with a lag. The sixth, seventh, and eight equations are (normalized) blocks of equations that are contemporaneously affected by all variables in the system. The world export commodity price equation is assumed to be an arbitrage equation, which describes a kind of financial market equilibrium. We do not impose any restrictions on the equations for X1 and X2 since we are interested in how X1 and X2 respond. Data are gathered monthly. They are found in the IFS database except for M02 of the UK, which is from the Bank of England s Web page. The estimation periods are 1976:9 1996:6 for France, 6 1981:6 1996:12 for Italy, and 1979:1 1996:12 for the UK. All variables were used in logarithm form except for interest rates. Complete seasonal dummies are used in all estimations. Six lags were assumed. We skip the detailed estimation method on the structural VAR model since it is well- 7 documented in the past studies. Impulse responses of the first six variables to monetary policy shocks in our system do not show any puzzling responses (such as price puzzle). In addition, the likelihood ratio test of the overidentifying restrictions suggests that the over-identifying restrictions are not rejected at any conventional significance level in each case. 3. International monetary transmission mechanism We employ the dataset which decomposes the total nominal values (in terms of each country s currency) of exports and imports into the volumes and the unit values. Three different pairs of X1 and 4 For France and Italy, we give another zero restriction on g 12, as Kim and Roubini (2000) suggest. 5 This assumption has been widely used by previous researchers, for example, Sims and Zha (1996), Kim (1999), Christiano et al. (1998), Gordon and Leeper (1994), Kim and Roubini (2000). Additional restrictions of g3550 and g3550 do not affect the results much. 6 For France, we choose the starting date of 1976:9, when the Barre plan of price stabilization starts (see Melitz, 1991). We also estimated the model from 1979:3 when the ERM launched, but the results are similar. For Italy, we choose the starting date of 1981:6, when the Bank of Italy divorces from the Treasury (see Passacantando, 1996). We also estimated the model from 1979:3, but the results are similar. For the UK, we choose the starting date of 1979:1, around when Thatcher assumed power, fighting inflation became a clear policy objective, and the ERM launched. We also estimated the model starting from 1979:6 and 1979:3, which are the exact dates of those events, but the results are similar. 7 For example, refer to Kim (1999) and Kim and Roubini (2000).

200 S. Kim / Economics Letters 71 (2001) 197 203 X2 are included. The first includes the volumes, the second includes the unit values, and the third includes the nominal values. Both exports (X1) and imports (X2) are included in each system. The difference between exports and imports is reported in each case. All variables are included in the form of a logarithm. We proxy the differences in the volumes of exports and imports as the trade balance in real terms and the differences in the unit values as the terms of trade (export price/import price). Finally, to infer detailed mechanisms, we include another pair of variables, nominal (X1) and real 8 (X2) exchange rates, in a separate system. Fig. 1 reports the impulse responses to one standard-deviation monetary policy shocks (expansion) in each country with one standard error band over 4 years. In each graph, vertical lines are inserted each year after the shocks. First, the volume of the trade balance (the real value) increases initially, but returns to the initial level in about a year. The peak increase is found within 6 months. Second, the unit value of the trade balance (the terms of trade) decreases. The responses are slightly different in each country. Third, the responses of the total nominal values of the trade balance are much different Fig. 1. Impulse responses to monetary policy shocks. 8 The exchange rates are effective exchange rates against 17 industrial countries. They are defined as indirect terms; an increase implies an appreciation.

S. Kim / Economics Letters 71 (2001) 197 203 201 across countries, depending on the size and the persistency of the volume and the value effects. In general, they are small, reflecting the opposite movements of the value and the volume effects. Finally, the nominal and real exchange rates depreciate. Note that the responses of the nominal and real exchange rates are similar while the responses of two exchange rates and the terms of trade are somewhat different. The terms of trade decrease is more delayed than the exchange rate depreciation. The peak exchange rate depreciation is found in 2 5 months while the peak decrease in the terms of trade is found in 6 months to 1 year. First, we compare the impulse responses with theoretical predictions. The basic predictions of the traditional Mundell Flemming Dornbusch (MFD) model are the following. A monetary expansion leads to a depreciation in the nominal exchange rate and a deterioration of the terms of trade, which results in an improvement of the trade balance the expenditure-switching effect. However, a monetary expansion also stimulates domestic demand, which may lead to an increase in imports and a worsening of the trade balance the income-absorption effect. These two effects move the trade balance in opposite directions. The movements of the trade balance are determined by the dominant 9 effect. In general, the expenditure-switching effect seems to dominate the income-absorption effect. The impulse responses are consistent with the expenditure-switching effect. A monetary expansion leads a nominal exchange rate depreciation and a deterioration of the terms of trade (the unit value). As a result, the volume of the trade balance increases. We find little evidence of the J-curve effect. The J-curve effect suggests that an exchange rate depreciation may result in an initial nominal trade balance deficit (in terms of the domestic currency) since the value effects are immediate but the volume effects are delayed. The impulse responses suggest that the volume effects are not much delayed while the value effects are not immediate. The volume of the trade balance starts to increase immediately, and the peak increase is found in 2 5 months. The value of the trade balance also starts to increase immediately, but the peak increase is found only in about 6 months to 1 year. Though the exchange rate response is more immediate, the terms of trade reflects the nominal exchange rate change with a delay, which may be one reason that the J-curve effect is not found. Next, we discuss the implications of our results on theoretical modeling. First, to explain the negative correlation between trade balance and output (for example, see Backus and Kehoe (1992) and Baxter (1996)), it is important to introduce structural shocks other than monetary shocks in a theoretical model since monetary shocks generate the positive correlation. Second, a separate modeling of the real exchange rate and the terms of trade may be important in analyzing the international monetary transmission (for example, Obstfeld and Rogoff (1995) and Betts and Devereux (2000)) since the responses of the real exchange rate and the terms of trade are somewhat different. We also compare the results for the US with the results for the small open European economies studied here. Kim (2000) reports that a typical US monetary expansion leads to a short-run worsening of the trade balance (in real terms or the volume measure), but a long-run persistent (up to 5 6 years) improvement of the trade balance. In contrast, the trade balance (the volume measure) improves within a few months, but the improvement is short-lived (about 1 year) in these European countries. 9 Intertemporal sticky price (or sticky wage) models (such as Svensson and Van Wijnbergen (1989) and Obstfeld and Rogoff (1995)) suggest similar channels as international monetary transmission mechanisms.

202 S. Kim / Economics Letters 71 (2001) 197 203 Table 1 Forecast error variance decomposition due to monetary policy shocks Horizon (months) France Italy UK Volume 6 8.0 (4.0) 11.4 (4.7) 10.7 (5.0) TB 12 8.2 (4.1) 10.9 (4.7) 11.0 (4.9) 48 9.6 (4.6) 11.3 (5.3) 10.8 (4.9) Unit value 6 13.3 (6.7) 8.7 (5.1) 2.6 (2.4) TB 12 16.5 (9.4) 8.9 (6.1) 5.2 (4.6) 48 20.6 (11.6) 11.1 (7.6) 6.7 (5.6) Total 6 3.8 (1.8) 3.3 (1.7) 4.5 (2.3) TB 12 6.4 (4.1) 5.3 (2.6) 5.1 (2.5) 48 7.6 (5.2) 7.1 (4.2) 5.7 (3.0) One difference in the transmission mechanism is due to the persistency of the terms of trade deterioration. In the Kim (2000) results, the terms of trade deterioration is persistent in response the US expansionary monetary policy shocks, but it is short-lived in response to these European 10 countries expansionary monetary policy shocks. Table 1 reports the forecast error variance decomposition of the unit value, the volume, and the total nominal value of the trade balance in each country. The numbers in the parentheses are standard errors. In general, the contribution of monetary policy shocks to each measure of the trade balance is small in most cases. Since the role of monetary policy shocks is limited in explaining the observed high volatility of the trade balance and the terms of trade (for example, see Baxter (1996) and Backus et al. (1992)), introducing monetary policy shocks in the theoretical model do not seem to be the best way to match the high volatility in the data. Finally, we may loose some information on the interactions among trade statistics based on our estimation methods since we include only two trade statistics each time. By changing combinations of trade statistics, we examine the importance of these interactions. In most cases, the impulse responses are similar. 4. Conclusion In France, Italy, UK, the effects of monetary policy shocks on trade balance are consistent with expenditure-switching effect, but there is little evidence of J-curve effect. Acknowledgements I thank Andre Baretto and Min Jung Chae for research assistance. I acknowledge financial support from UIUC Research Board. I thank Hyungsoo Park for useful suggestions. Some parts of this 10 The short lived response of the terms of trade deterioration in the European economies studied here may be due to one characteristic of these small open economies, exchange rate stabilization, especially during the ERM period.

S. Kim / Economics Letters 71 (2001) 197 203 203 research was conducted while I was a visiting research fellow at the Bank of Korea. The usual disclaimer applies. References Backus, D.K., Kehoe, P.J., 1992. International evidence on the historical properties of business cycles. American Economic Review 82, 864 888. Backus, D.K., Kehoe, P.J., Kydland, F.E., 1992. International real business cycles. Journal of Political Economy 100, 745 775. Baxter, M., 1996. International trade and business cycles. In: Grossman, G., Rogoff, K. (Eds.). Handbook of International Economics, Vol. III. North Holland, Amsterdam. Betts, C., Devereux, M.B., 2000. Exchange rate dynamics in a model of pricing-to-market. Journal of International Economics 50, 215 244. Bryant, R., Hooper, P., Mann, C., 1988. Empirical Macroeconomics For Independent Economies. Brookings, Washington, DC. Christiano, L., Eichenbaum, M., Evans, C., 1998. Monetary Policy Shocks: What Have We Learned and To What End. NBER Working Paper No. 6400. Clarida, R., Gali, M., 1994. Sources of Real Exchange Rate Fluctuations: How Important Are Nominal Shocks. Carnegie Rochester Series on Public Policy. Clarida, R., Gali, J., Gertler, M., 1997. Monetary Policy Rules in Practice: Some International Evidence. NBER Working Paper No. 6254. Gordon, D.B., Leeper, E.M., 1994. The dynamic impacts of monetary policy: An exercise in tentative identification. Journal of Political Economy 102, 228 247. Kim, S., 1999. Do monetary policy shocks matter in the G-7 countries? Using common identifying assumptions about monetary policy across countries. Journal of International Economics 48, 387 412. Kim, S., 2000. International transmission of the US monetary policy shocks: Evidence from VARs. Journal of Monetary Economics 45 (forthcoming). Kim, S., Roubini, N., 2000. Exchange rate anomalies in the industrial countries: A solution with a structural VAR approach. Journal of Monetary Economics 45, 561 586. Melitz, J., 1991. Monetary Policy in France. CEPR Discussion Paper No. 509. Obstfeld, M., Rogoff, K., 1995. Exchange rate dynamics redux. Journal of Political Economy 103, 624 660. Passacantando, F., 1996. Building an Institutional Framework For Monetary Stability: The Case of Italy. BNL Quarterly Review. Sims, C.A., 1992. Interpreting the macroeconomic time series facts: The effects of monetary policy. European Economic Review 36, 975 1000. Sims, C.A., Zha, T., 1996. Does Monetary Policy Generate Recessions? Using Less Aggregate Price Data To Identify Monetary Policy. Working Paper. Yale University, Connecticut. Svensson, L., Van Wijnbergen, S., 1989. Excess capacity, monopolistic competition and international transmission of monetary disturbances. Economic Journal 99, 785 805.