The Asian Crisis: Causes and Cures IMF Staff

Similar documents
What is Wrong with Market-Oriented Policies?

Chapter Eleven. The International Monetary System

Developing Countries Chapter 22

Financial System Stabilized, but Exit, Reform, and Fiscal Challenges Lie Ahead

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY. Global Economic Environment

Globalization and Economic Crises in the Asia-Pacific: Imperatives on Statistics Management

Chapter 18. The International Financial System Intervention in the Foreign Exchange Market

East Asia in Crisis. Edited by Ross H. McLeod and Ross Garnaut. From being a miracle to needing one? London and New York

Currency Crises: Theory and Evidence

Export Group Meeting on the Contribution and Effective Use of External Resources for Development, in Particular for Productive Capacity Building

Economics of Money, Banking, and Fin. Markets, 10e (Mishkin) Chapter 18 The International Financial System

Ten Lessons Learned from the Korean Crisis Center for International Development, 11/19/99. Jeffrey A. Frankel, Harpel Professor, Harvard University

Asia s Debt Risks The risk of financial crises is limited, but attention should be paid to slowing domestic demand.

Chapter 22 (11) Developing Countries: Growth, Crisis, and Reform

Presentation. The Boom in Capital Flows and Financial Vulnerability in Asia

L-3: BALANCE OF PAYMENT CRISES IRINA BUNDA MACROECONOMIC POLICIES IN TIMES OF HIGH CAPITAL MOBILITY VIENNA, MARCH 21 25, 2016

OECD Interim Economic Projections Real GDP 1 Percentage change September 2015 Interim Projections. Outlook

Rich and Poor. Indicators of Economic Welfare for 4 groups of countries, 2003 GNP per capita (1995 US$)

Economics of Money, Banking, and Fin. Markets, 10e (Mishkin) Chapter 9 Financial Crises. 9.1 What is a Financial Crisis?

Economy Report - Mexico

International Monetary and Financial Committee

Growth and Inflation Prospects and Monetary Policy

SOUTH ASIA. Chapter 2. Recent developments

The Case for Chinese Capital Controls. Global Economics Monthly February 2016

Outlook for the Chilean Economy

Global Imbalances and Latin America: A Comment on Eichengreen and Park

4) The dark side of financial liberalization is. A) market allocations B) credit booms C) currency appreciation D) financial innovation

The Case of Poland. Edilberto L. Segura. The Early Economic Reform Program. August 2002

Indonesia: Changing patterns of financial intermediation and their implications for central bank policy

THE EAST ASIAN CRISIS: LESSONS FOR OIC COUNTRIES. Enver Hakan Konaç *

CRS Report for Congress

Avoiding Currency Crises * Martin Feldstein **

IMF Stabilisation and Structural Adjustment Programmes Colette Murphy Junior Sophister

Global Imbalances and Current Account Imbalances

Mr Thiessen converses on the conduct of monetary policy in Canada under a floating exchange rate system

Executive Directors welcomed the continued

The Asian Financial Crisis

Antonio Fazio: Overview of global economic and financial developments in first half 2004

East Asia Crisis of Econ October 8, Team 5 Bryan Darch Svend Egholm Paramdeep Singh Sarah Zullo

INDONESIAN ECONOMY Recent Developments and Challenges. BUDI MULYA Deputy Governor of Bank Indonesia

Prepared by Iordanis Petsas To Accompany. by Paul R. Krugman and Maurice Obstfeld

Volume Author/Editor: Takatoshi Ito and Anne O. Krueger, Editors. Volume URL:

Economic Growth of NIEs and ASEAN-4 in 1999 and 2000

The Asian Face of the Global Recession

Reconsidering the International Monetary System

POLICY PRESCRIPTIONS FOR EAST ASIA

Indonesia. Real Sector. The economy grew 3.7% in the first three quarters.

Malaysia. Real Sector. Economic recovery is gaining momentum.

World Economic outlook

International Monetary and Financial Committee

Neoliberalism, Investment and Growth in Latin America

The Importance of Developing Financial Safety Nets and the Role of Central Banks

FISCAL COUNCIL OPINION ON THE SUMMER FORECAST 2018 OF THE MINISTRY OF FINANCE

UPDATE ON GLOBAL PROSPECTS AND POLICY CHALLENGES

Case Study (Finance and Development in Emerging Asia I) Reading 02

Economic Dynamics and Integration in Eastern Europe and Asia Lecture Winter semester 2017/18

New Financial Architecture as a Global Public Good. Stephany Griffith-Jones

Japan s Economy: Monthly Review

Evaluation Only. Created with Aspose.Words. Copyright Aspose Pty Ltd. International Monetary Fund

All the BRICs dampening world trade in 2015

Fund Management Diary

Asian Financial Crisis. Jianing Li/Wei Ye/Jingyan Zhang 2018/11/29

Chapter two Overview of the Macroeconomic Situation and Outlook for Africa

Speech by Mr. Amando M. Tetangco, Jr. Governor, Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas

Twenty-First Meeting April 24, 2010

Indonesia Quarterly Economic Update Battening down the hatches

FINANCIAL SECURITY AND STABILITY

Chapter 18. The International Financial System

Ian J Macfarlane: Payment imbalances

Josef Bonnici: The changing nature of economic and financial governance following the euro area crisis

REMARKS ON THE EVOLUTION OF THE INTERNATIONAL FINANCIAL SYSTEM. As I recall, in the sixties and seventies, one used to stress :

POST-CRISIS GLOBAL REBALANCING CONFERENCE ON GLOBALIZATION AND THE LAW OF THE SEA WASHINGTON DC, DEC 1-3, Barry Bosworth

2012 Article IV Consultation with Spain Concluding Statement of IMF Mission Madrid, June, 14, 2012

Six recommendations for maintaining financial stability

POLI 12D: International Relations Sections 1, 6

Financial System Crisis Preparedness and Management. Prepared by D.S. Hoelscher and presented by David Walker, IADI

The IMF s Indonesian Myths

A Latin American View of IMF Governance

Global Update. 6 th October, Global Prospects. Contacts: Madan Sabnavis Chief Economist

Lars Heikensten: The Swedish economy and monetary policy

WORLD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK Interim Assessment

OVERVIEW OF MONETARY POLICY REGIMES. Jan Gottschalk, TAOLAM This activity is supported by a grant from Japan. Yangon October 2, 2014

6-8 September 2011, Manila, Philippines. Jointly organized by UNESCAP and BANGKO SENTRAL NG PILIPINAS. Country Experiences 3: Net Energy Exporters

Economic ProjEctions for

Economic policy-making in a small and open economy the case of Suriname

Global Business Economics. Mark Crosby SEMBA International Economics

Ten Years After The Asian Financial Crisis * Heh-Song Wang **

Introduction: addressing too big to fail

Toward A More Resilient Global Financial Architecture

Investment and its Financing: A Macro Perspective

1. Inflation target policy how does it work?

DEVELOPING COUNTRIES AND THE DOLLAR. C. P. Chandrasekhar and Jayati Ghosh

Challenges for Monetary Policy in Latin America and the Caribbean

Précis WORLD BANK OPERATIONS EVALUATION DEPARTMENT SUMMER 1998 N U M B E R 1 6 6

CENTRAL BANK OF SOLOMON ISLANDS 2004 MONETARY POLICY STANCE STATEMENT. Issued by Governor of the Central Bank of Solomon Islands

Banking on Turkey, October 21, 2008

The adaptation of monetary policy to the constraints of the global financial crisis by central banks of ASEAN-5 countries

STAFF REPORT FOR THE 2014 ARTICLE IV CONSULTATION AND SECOND REVIEW UNDER THE POLICY SUPPORT INSTRUMENT DEBT SUSTAINABILITY ANALYSIS

Monetary and financial trends in the fourth quarter of 2014

The Financial Crisis, Global Imbalances, and the

Transcription:

June 1998, Volume 35, Number 2 The Asian Crisis: Causes and Cures IMF Staff The financial crisis that struck many Asian countries in late 1997 did so with an unexpected severity. What went wrong? How can the effects of the crisis be mitigated? And what steps can be taken to prevent such crises from recurring in the future? THE EAST ASIAN countries at the center of the recent crisis were for years admired as some of the most successful emerging market economies, owing to their rapid growth and the striking gains in their populations' living standards. With their generally prudent fiscal policies and high rates of private saving, they were widely seen as models for many other countries. No one could have foreseen that these countries could suddenly become embroiled in one of the worst financial crises of the postwar period. What went wrong? Were these countries the victims of their own success? This certainly seems to have been part of the answer. Their very success led foreign investors to underestimate their underlying economic weaknesses. Partly because of the large-scale financial inflows that their economic success encouraged, there were also increased demands on policies and institutions, especially those safeguarding the financial sector; and policies and institutions failed to keep pace with these demands (see table). Only as the crisis deepened were the fundamental policy shortcomings and their ramifications fully revealed. Also, past successes may have led policymakers to deny the need for action when problems first appeared. Net capital flows (billion dollars) 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 Total Net private capital flows 1 Net direct investment Net portfolio investment Other net investment Net official flows Change in reserves 2 160.5 84.3 87.8-11.7-2.5-77.2 192.0 96.0 23.5 72.5 34.9-120.5 240.8 114.9 49.7 76.2-9.7-11 5.9 173.7 138.2 42.9-7.3 29.0-54.7 122.0 119.6 18.0-15.6 37.0-6 7.1 196.4 119.7 34.4 42.3-8.9-91.1 Developing countries Net private capital flows 1 Net direct investment Net portfolio investment Other net investment 136.6 75.4 85.0-23.8 156.1 84.3 20.6 51.2 207.9 105.0 42.9 60.0 154.7 119.4 40.6-5.3 99.5 99.1 19.4-19.0 168.6 99.1 32.2 37.3

Net official flows 9.1 Change in reserves 2-42. 4 27.4-65. 6-3.4-10 3.4 17.5-55.2 28.6-37. 3 5.7-80.8 Asia Net private capital flows 1 Net direct investment Net portfolio investment Other net investment Net official flows Change in reserves 2 63.1 43.4 11.3 8.3 6.2-39.7 91.8 49.7 10.8 31.3 5.1-29.0< BR> 102.2 58.5 10.2 33.5 9.3-48.9 38.5 55.4-2.2-14.7 17.7-17. 2 1.5 40.6-7.0-32.1 24.7-24.4 58.8 43.7 5.3 9.8 7.0-65.5 Source: IMF, World Economic Outlook, May 1998 (Washington). 1 Because of data limitations, other net investment may include some official flows. 2 A minus sign indicates an increase. Several factors both domestic and external probably contributed to the dramatic deterioration in sentiment by foreign and domestic investors: a buildup of overheating pressures, evident in large external deficits and inflated property and stock market values; the prolonged maintenance of pegged exchange rates, in some cases at unsustainable levels, which complicated the response of monetary policies to overheating pressures and which came to be seen as implicit guarantees of exchange value, encouraging external borrowing and leading to excessive exposure to foreign exchange risk in both the financial and corporate sectors; a lack of enforcement of prudential rules and inadequate supervision of financial systems, coupled with government-directed lending practices that led to a sharp deterioration in the quality of banks' loan portfolios; problems resulting from the limited availability of data and a lack of transparency, both of which hindered market participants from taking a realistic view of economic fundamentals; and problems of governance and political uncertainties, which worsened the crisis of confidence, fueled the reluctance of foreign creditors to roll over short-term loans, and led to downward pressures on currencies and stock markets. External factors also played a role, and many foreign investors suffered substantial losses: international investors had underestimated the risks as they searched for higher yields at a time when investment opportunities appeared less profitable in Europe and Japan, owing to their sluggish economic growth and low interest rates; since several exchange rates in East Asia were pegged to the U.S. dollar, wide swings in the dollar/yen exchange rate contributed to the buildup in the crisis through shifts in international competitiveness that proved to be unsustainable (in particular, the appreciation of the U.S. dollar from mid-1995, especially against the yen, and the associated losses of competitiveness in countries with dollarpegged currencies, contributed to their export slowdowns in 1996 97 and wider external imbalances) (see chart);

international investors mainly commercial and investment banks may, in some cases, have contributed, along with domestic investors and residents seeking to hedge their foreign currency exposures, to the downward pressure on currencies. To contain the economic damage caused by the crisis, the affected countries introduced corrective measures. In the latter part of 1997 and early 1998, the IMF provided $36 billion to support reform programs in the three worst-hit countries Indonesia, Korea, and Thailand. The IMF gave this financial support as part of international support packages totaling almost $100 billion. In these three countries, unfortunately, the authorities' initial hesitation in introducing reforms and in taking other measures to restore confidence led to a worsening of the crisis by causing declines in currency and stock markets that were greater than a reasonable assessment of economic fundamentals might have justified. This overshooting in financial markets worsened the panic and added to difficulties in both the corporate and financial sectors. In particular, the domestic currency value of foreign debt rose sharply. While uncertainties persisted longer in Indonesia, strengthened commitments were made elsewhere to carry out adjustment reforms. Appropriate strategies The strategies needed to restore confidence and support a resumption of growth include a range of measures, tailored to tackle the particular weaknesses of each country. These strategies are the basic ingredients of the IMF-supported programs in Indonesia, Korea, and Thailand.

Monetary policy must be firm enough to resist excessive currency depreciation, with its damaging consequences not only for domestic inflation but also for the balance sheets of domestic financial institutions and nonfinancial enterprises with large foreign currency exposures. As fundamental policy weaknesses are addressed and confidence is restored, interest rates can be allowed to return to more normal levels. Financial sector weaknesses are at the root of the Asian crisis and require particularly urgent attention. In many cases, weak but viable financial institutions must be restructured and recapitalized. Those that are insolvent need to be closed or absorbed by stronger institutions. Governance must be improved in the public and corporate sectors, and transparency and accountability strengthened. Many recent difficulties spring from extensive government intervention in the economy, as well as widespread political patronage, nepotism, and lax accounting practices. In order for confidence to be restored, political leaders must send unambiguous signals that such abuses will no longer be tolerated. Fiscal policies will need to focus on reducing countries' reliance on external savings and take account of the costs of restructuring and recapitalizing banking systems. Resources will need to be reallocated from unproductive public expenditures to those needed to minimize the social costs of the crisis and strengthen social safety nets. Prospects for recovery In all of the countries at the center of the financial turmoil, its consequences have taken the form of a substantial shrinkage of investment and consumption, coupled with a rapid improvement in trade positions. For 19 98 as a whole, the aggregate current account of Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, the Philippines, and Thailand is forecast to be $20 billion in surplus, compared with deficits of $27 billion in 1997 and $54 billion in 1996. This forced improvement in the external situation will help to offset declines in domestic demand, but output is expected to stagnate in Indonesia and Korea, and to fall slightly in Thailand. There have already been some recoveries of exchange rates and stock markets, and as the needed policies are carried out and external positions improve, confidence should recover further during 1998. This will pave the way for a moderate rebound of growth in 1999 and solid recovery by 2000. The experiences of Argentina and Mexico following the "tequila crisis" of 1994 95, as well as the experiences of many other countries in similar situations, demonstrate that when policymakers are prepared to address the root causes of a financial crisis, economic recovery is likely to begin a year or so after a crisis peaks. In the East Asian case, the severity and importance of the crisis in the financial sector and other structural weaknesses in the countries concerned mean that necessary corrective measures are likely to take longer to implement than in crises that can be resolved mainly by macroeconomic adjustment. At the same time, the deep declines that have occurred in currency and financial markets suggest there is scope for relatively sharp rebounds as confidence recovers.

Moral hazard Some commentators have argued that the international community's assistance to countries suffering from financial crises will only encourage more reckless behavior by borrowers, lenders, and investors a phenomenon that is known as "moral hazard." Such moral hazard exists when the provision of insurance against a risk encourages behavior that makes the risk more likely to occur. In the case of IMF lending, concern about moral hazard stems from a perception that such assistance might weaken policy discipline and encourage investors to take on greater risks in the belief that they will only partially suffer the consequences if their investments sour. In fact, though, one of the fundamental purposes of the IMF is to limit the economic and social costs of crises. The experience of the Great Depression taught policymakers that the damage caused by systemic financial crises can be devastating and can have a global impact. This justifies a public policy role in avoiding deep and damaging crises. Nonetheless, in some instances the fact that IMF financing is available could increase the incentive for risk-taking by both potential borrowers and lenders. Policymakers could pursue more risky policies, knowing that the IMF would be there if their policies failed. Likewise, lenders could take excessive risks if they believe that an IMF loan would enable a government or its banks to pay their debts if the country fell into financial trouble. In its policy advice, the IMF seeks to ensure that the parties to private transactions bear the costs of their actions. Policy advice on banking sector restructuring typically includes the closing of insolvent institutions and equity writedowns in institutions that are restructured. However, depositors may need to be protected up to certain limits, or safeguarded more broadly, if there is a risk of a general run on a banking system. It may therefore be difficult to avoid moral hazard altogether with respect to banks' foreign creditors, although there may be scope for arrangements in which these creditors roll over short-term loans at terms they would normally not choose to accept. Given the significant costs of financial crises for borrowers and lenders alike, it seems highly unlikely that imprudent lending and investment decisions are primarily the result of moral hazard created by the involvement of the IMF and other international financial bodies. Crises also reflect misjudgments or "irrational exuberance" that lead investors and banks to underestimate the risks in emerging markets (and then to overreact when sentiment begins to change). This underscores the need to ensure that investment decisions are supported by timely and accurate information to enable investors, lenders, and borrowers to be fully aware of a country's situation and vulnerabilities. Forestalling future crises The East Asian crisis of 1997 98 and the Mexican crisis of 1994 95 are the latest of a large number of crises in the past two decades. These crises have been costly for the countries directly affected both those where the crises began and those that might have

escaped them but for spillover and contagion effects. Obviously, in view of these costs, the foremost concern for policymakers and financial markets is how to identify the causes of crises and prevent them. It is, of course, impossible to predict crises reliably. Further, for crises arising from pure contagion effects, early warning signals may not be available because these crises arise from unpredictable market reactions. It is feasible, however, to identify the kinds of weaknesses that typically make economies vulnerable to financial crises, whether or not a crisis does in fact materialize. Analysis suggests that the chances of a currency or banking crisis are increased when the economy is overheated: inflation is high, the real exchange rate has appreciated, the current account deficit has widened, domestic credit has been growing rapidly, and asset prices have become inflated. An analysis further indicates that real appreciation of the domestic currency, an excessive expansion of domestic credit, and a rapidly rising ratio of broad money to international reserves are signals of vulnerability to pressures in currency markets. Equity price declines and deteriorations in the terms of trade can also signal vulnerability to a crisis, as can a rise in world interest rates. Indeed, a number of these variables indicated the emergence of vulnerabilities in the Asian countries most affected by the recent crisis. Indicators of vulnerability do give false signals, however, and they cannot predict crises. A key task for future policymakers is to identify and address vulnerability before crises erupt. While it may be impossible to detect and correctly interpret warning signals for all types of crises early enough, preemptive actions have meant that many potentially serious crises have been avoided in the past. In some cases, countries may need to adapt their exchange rate regime. Such mechanisms as currency pegs and currency unions have served many countries well and have helped to support their stabilization efforts. When countries adopt a pegged or fixed-rate arrangement, a number of preconditions must be met. For example, the anchor currency and the rate at which the peg is set have to be appropriate and policies must be attuned to maintaining the rate. For some economies, the balance of costs and benefits seems to be shifting in favor of greater exchange rate flexibility, partly in order to avoid the risk that a fixed exchange rate might lead to excessive foreign currency exposure. The decision to exit a fixed currency arrangement is difficult, however, and ideally should be taken in a period of calm. All countries benefit from access to global capital markets and from the improvement in resource allocation associated with market-based competition for financing. Among these benefits is the competition in domestic financial sectors that the entry of foreign firms allows. At the same time, there are important preconditions for an orderly liberalization of capital movements. These include, above all else, a robust financial system supported by effective regulation and supervision of financial institutions. During the transition to an open capital account regime with a liberalized domestic financial sector, market-based instruments such as reserve requirements on foreign currency deposits and short-term borrowing may help to moderate financial flows. Prudential limits on foreign currency exposure in the financial system are also essential. The liberalization of domestic

financial systems should precede or at least accompany the opening up to foreign investors, since this will promote the development of domestic capital markets. Such a step would reduce the risk that capital inflows would become a substitute for the mobilization and effective intermediation of domestic financial resources. This article is drawn from the IMF's World Economic Outlook, May 1998 (Washington).