Chapter 11: The Effects of General Fluctuations in Wages on the Prices of Production

Similar documents
Chapter 17: Commercial Profit

The Results of the Immediate Process of Production

Chapter 22: Division of Profit. Rate of Interest. Natural Rate of Interest

Chapter 17: The Circulation of Surplus-Value 1

Chapter 2: Algebraic summary: A macro-monetary interpretation of Marx s theory

Chapter 9: Formation of a General Rate of Profit (Average Rate of Profit), and Transformation of Commodity Values into Prices of Production

Demand-Led Growth Theory: An Historical Approach

Chapter 28: Means of Circulation and Capital. The Views of Tooke and Fullarton

THE CONTINUING SAGA OF THE FALLING RATE OF PROFIT - A REPLY TO MARIO COGOY. Susan Himmelweit

NOTES AND COMMENTS A note on the organic composition of capital and profit rates

TOTALITY, TAUTOLOGY, AND TRANSFORMATION: PERSPECTIVES ON THE MARXIAN TRANSFORMATION PROBLEM 1

The Exchange Rate and Canadian Inflation Targeting

International Economics

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

On The Principles of Political Economy and Taxation

Marx s Reproduction Schema and the Multisectoral Foundations of the Domar Growth Model

Chapter 2: The Circuit of Productive Capital

Chapter# The Level and Structure of Interest Rates

Marxist Economics. A Glossary of Terms, Part I: Basics By Marc Newman. Labour. Worker. Commodity. Labour Theory of Value. Relations of Production

INTRODUCTION TO MODELS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH:

6. Some countries like China use interest rates while others like Singapore choose exchange rates as their instrument for monetary policy.

International Linkages and Domestic Policy

2. A DIAGRAMMATIC APPROACH TO THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF PUBLIC INPUTS

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Pre-Classical Theory of International Trade. Adam Smith s Theory of Absolute Cost Difference. David Ricardo s Theory of Comparative Cost Advantage.

On The Principles of Political Economy and Taxation London: John Murray, Albemarle-Street, by David Ricardo, 1817 (third edition 1821) PREFACE

Is a Threat of Countervailing Duties Effective in Reducing Illegal Export Subsidies?

A GLOSSARY OF FINANCIAL TERMS MICHAEL J. SHARPE, MATHEMATICS DEPARTMENT, UCSD

Distortions in the tax treatment of rights issues

The Economic Ideas of. Marx s Capital. Steps towards post-keynesian economics. Ludo Cuyvers. Routledge R Taylor & Francis Group LONDON AND NEW YORK

CRS Report for Congress

Marx s Analysis of Ground-Rent: Theory, Examples and Applications

This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research. Volume Title: Education, Income, and Human Behavior

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy

ADAM SMITH S CONCEPT OF LABOUR: VALUE OR MEASURE?

Centre de Referència en Economia Analítica

Volume Title: The Demand for Health: A Theoretical and Empirical Investigation. Volume URL:

CRS Report for Congress

Marx s reproduction schemes and the Keynesian multiplier: a reply to Sardoni

STUDENTSFOCUS.COM BA ECONOMIC ANALYSIS FOR BUSINESS

3. Trade and Development

Project Evaluation and the Folk Principle when the Private Sector Lacks Perfect Foresight

n Answers to Textbook Problems

The Effects of Changes in Inflationary Expectations

THE USE OF MELT SHOULD BE ABANDONED BECAUSE MONEY DOES NOT MEASURE LABOUR TIME DIRECTLY.

Investment 3.1 INTRODUCTION. Fixed investment

Essays on Herd Behavior Theory and Criticisms

International Economics dr Wioletta Nowak. Lecture 2

1. For information about the Mid-Decade Review, see Mid-Decade Strategic Review of BEA s Economic Accounts: Maintaining and Improving

2015 EXAMINATIONS ECONOMICS - MSS J133 JOINT UNIVERSITIES PRELIMINARY EXAMINATIONS BOARD MULTIPLE CHOICE QUESTIONS

QUESTIONNAIRE B I. MULTIPLE CHOICE QUESTIONS (4 points each)

Chapter 9 The IS LM FE Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

Adam Smith, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, 1776, Edited by R.H. Campbell and A.S. Skinner, Oxford, 1976,

On the TSSI and the exploitation theory of profit. On the TSSI and the exploitation theory of profit

FINANCIAL ECONOMICS. The table below shows the distribution if candidates by scores: Grade Marks % of Candidates

Cambridge International Advanced Subsidiary and Advanced Level 9706 Accounting June 2016 Principal Examiner Report for Teachers

Volume Title: The Design of Economic Accounts. Volume Author/Editor: Nancy D. Ruggles and Richard Ruggles

Rents, Profits, and the Financial Environment of Business

CRS Report for Congress

AGGREGATE DEMAND, AGGREGATE SUPPLY, AND INFLATION. Chapter 25

Market Institutions and Income Inequality *

Cambridge International Advanced Subsidiary Level and Advanced Level 9706 Accounting November 2014 Principal Examiner Report for Teachers

LEADS AND LAGS IN OVERSEAS TRADE

Assignment 1 Deadline: June 25, 2005

Association of Accounting Technicians response to the Financial Reporting Council (FRC) consultation document Improving the Statement of Cash Flows

CHAPTER 13: Monetary Policy

The Changing Effects of Social Protection on Poverty

Comment Does the economics of moral hazard need to be revisited? A comment on the paper by John Nyman

LESSON - 26 FOREIGN EXCHANGE - 1. Learning outcomes

Test Yourself: Monetary Policy

Quarterly Spanish National Accounts. Base 2000

= C + I + G + NX = Y 80r

AGGREGATE DEMAND AGGREGATE SUPPLY

CEMARE Research Paper 167. Fishery share systems and ITQ markets: who should pay for quota? A Hatcher CEMARE

FEEDBACK TUTORIAL LETTER

All Value-Form, No Value-Substance: Comments on Moseley s New Book, Part 11. Andrew Kliman, August 22, 2016

1 The Exchange Economy...

TRANSFORMING VALUE INTO PRICES OF PRODUCTION WHICH YIELD AVERAGE RATES OF PROFIT NOT ON THE OLD CAPITAL, BUT ON THE NEWLY PRICED CAPITAL.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

VALUE ADDED TAX COMMITTEE (ARTICLE 398 OF DIRECTIVE 2006/112/EC) WORKING PAPER NO 883

ECO403 Macroeconomics Solved Online Quiz For Midterm Exam Preparation Spring 2013

The benefits of free trade: an introduction

International Accounting Standards. Financial Reporting in Hyperinflationary Economies Understanding IAS 29

Inflation can have two principal kinds of redistributive effects. Even when

Name: Days/Times Class Meets: Today s Date:

[No. 38.] Companies Act [2014.]

Modeling Interest Rate Parity: A System Dynamics Approach

PAPER ON THE ACCOUNTING ADVISORY FORUM FOREIGN CURRENCY TRANSLATION -- > -)( *** *** EUROPEAN COMMISSION

Chapter 3 Foreign Exchange Determination and Forecasting

Managerial Economics MBA 1

WikiLeaks Document Release

Learning Accountancy: The Novel Way

macro macroeconomics Government Debt (chapter 15) N. Gregory Mankiw

THE RATE OF PROFIT AND THE FUTURE OF CAPITALISM. by Fred Moseley. Mount Holyoke College (Massachusetts)

Demand-Led Growth Theory in a Classical Framework: Its Superiority, Its Limitations, and Its Explanatory Power

A STUDY ON UNEMPLOYMENT AND INFLATION IN INDIA: THE SHORT RUN PHILLIPS CURVE APPROACH

History of Economic Thought

POLICY BRIEF. Monetary Policy as a Jobs Guarantee. Joshua R. Hendrickson July 2018

On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation

This is Interest Rate Parity, chapter 5 from the book Policy and Theory of International Finance (index.html) (v. 1.0).

Transcription:

Chapter 11: The Effects of General Fluctuations in Wages on the Prices of Production To appreciate what Marx wants to achieve here, it is worth setting his argument in political economic context. Adam Smith had argued (although not consistently) that, since the value of a product of labour is given by the quantity of labour it commanded in exchange, any rise in wages would increase the value of the commodity product produced. Ricardo, correctly, opposed this view: There can be no rise in the value of labour [i.e., a rise in wages] without a fall of profits. [...] Suppose [...] that owing to a rise of wages, profits fall [...]. [T]he manufactured goods in which more fixed capital was employed, would fall relatively to [...] any other goods in which a less portion of fixed capital entered. The degree of alteration in the relative value of goods, on account of a rise or fall of labour, would depend on the proportion which the fixed capital bore to the whole capital employed. All commodities which are produced by very valuable machinery, or in very valuable buildings, or which require a great length of time before they can be brought to market, would fall in relative value, while all those which were chiefly produced by labour, or which would be speedily brought to market would rise in relative value. 1 Ricardo s theoretical interest was to decouple the prices of commodities from fluctuations in wages: not all commodities would be equally affected were wages to rise, and, relative to each other, a rise in wages could provoke the prices of some commodities to fall with respect to others. 2 1 David Ricardo, On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation <http://www.econlib.org/library/ricardo/ricp1.html>. Although Ricardo is right over Smith, Marx notes: Ricardo concludes quite wrongly, that because there can be no rise in the value of labour without a fall of profits, there can be no rise of profits without a fall in the value of labour. The first law refers to surplus-value. But since profit equals the proportion of surplus-value to the total capital advanced, profit can rise though the value of labour remains the same, if the value of constant capital falls. Altogether Ricardo mixes up surplus-value and profit. Hence he arrives at erroneous laws on profit and the rate of profit. Karl Marx, Theories of Surplus- Value vol. 2, in Karl Marx, Theories of Surplus-Value: Books I, II and III (Amherst, NY, 2000) [hereafter TSV2], p. 193. 2 [...] Ricardo s treatment of value [in the Principles] is directly traceable to the corn-law controversies of 1813-17 [...]. The [...] chapter On Value in the first edition [...] was [...] designed less as an independent exposition than as theoretical warrant for certain practical propositions advanced and defended by Ricardo from about 1813 on. [...] Ricardo believed [...] that lower profits could only result, in the long run, from higher wages; [...] [and] he refused all credence to the popular fear that the free importation of corn would be followed by a further disastrous fall in general prices. It was to give re-enforcement to such definite propositions that Ricardo developed and extended his original concept of value. The prime features of his modified exposition were disagreement with the doctrine that every rise in wages must necessarily be transferred to the price of commodities, and, second, demonstration of the converse dictum, that higher wages were actually compatible with lower prices. [...] Ricardo s starting-point was [...] that, as long as the relative values of commodities were measured by embodied labour, only an increase in the amount of labour necessary to produce them could augment their value, and only a decrease would lower it. A general rise or fall in wages caused no change in prices. If embodied labour could thus be established as a universal measure of value, Ricardo s purpose, to prove that prices did not necessarily rise or fall as wages rose or fall, was attained. [...] Two commodities respectively produced by different amounts of labour conjoined with identical amounts of capital exchanged [...] in proportion to embodied labour. Even if the capitals engaged were different in amount, but identical in durability [...], the two commodities would exchange in proportion to the total quantity of labour respectively necessary to manufacture them and bring them to market [...]. But the situation was otherwise, if the several commodities were produced with the aid of different proportions of fixed and circulating capital, or if the quotas of fixed capitals so employed were of different durability. In proportion, Ricardo explained, as circulating capital preponderated in a manufacture or in proportion to the less durability of its fixed capital and its approach to the nature of circulating capital, any increase in wages resulted in a rise in the value of such commodities relative to the value of other commodities produced with the aid of less circulating capital or more durable fixed capital. The relative values and, assuming an invariable money standard, the prices of all such commodities were inversely affected by every alteration in wages, and directly by every alteration in profits. Jacob H Hollander, The 1

However, Ricardo s demonstration of the point rested on the belief that amongst other factors a variation in the composition of capital would affect the value of the commodities produced by it (and hence that value itself had determinations other than the labour embodied in a commodity): difference[s] in the degree of durability of fixed capital [...] introduce another cause, besides the greater or less quantity of labour necessary to produce commodities, for the variations in their relative value [...]. 3 This conclusion was necessarily the case for Ricardo, insofar as he lacked a theory of surplus-value, and hence could not see how the price of a type of commodity could contain a quantity of profit surplus (unpaid) labour different from that actually produced in its production; and it was on this point that Marx s critique of Ricardo centred: Ricardo concludes quite wrongly, that because there can be no rise in the value of labour without a fall of profits, there can be no rise of profits without a fall in the value of labour. The first law refers to surplusvalue. But since profit equals the proportion of surplus-value to the total capital advanced, profit can rise though the value of labour remains the same, if the value of constant capital falls. Altogether Ricardo mixes up surplus-value and profit. Hence he arrives at erroneous laws on profit and the rate of profit. 4 Ricardo s error was based on an inability to see how a general rate of profit which obviously obtained could be formed: he just assumed its existence as given, and theoretically adjusted the other elements of his political economy accordingly. Hence his inability to see that commodities could and necessarily normally would have prices and values and values that diverged because of the distribution of surplus-value as profit: [C]apitals of equal size, containing [different] proportions of variable to constant capital, must result in commodities of unequal values and thus yield different profit; the levelling out of these profits must therefore result in cost-prices which differ from the values of the commodities. 5 Hence as we have seen for Marx: Given this: Capitals of equal size produce commodities of equal values, if the ratio of their organic component parts is the same; if equally large portions of them are expended on wages and on means of production. [...] On the other hand, capitals of equal size produce commodities of very unequal value, when their organic composition is different [...]. Firstly, only a part of the fixed capital enters into the commodity as a component part of value, consequently the magnitude of their values will greatly vary according to whether much or little fixed capital is employed in the production of the commodity. Secondly, the part laid out in wages calculated as a percentage on capital of equal size is much smaller, therefore also the total [newly added] labour embodied in the commodity, and consequently the surplus-labour (given a working-day of equal length) which constitutes the surplusvalue. If, therefore, these capitals of equal size whose commodities are of unequal values and these unequal values contain unequal surplus-values, and therefore unequal profits [...] are to yield equal profits, then the prices of commodities (as determined by the general rate of profit on a given outlay) must be very different from the values of the commodities. Hence it follows, not that the values have altered their nature, but that the prices are different from the values. 6 The value of [...] the product of a particular sphere of production is determined by the labour which is required in order to produce the [...] the total sum of the commodities appertaining to this sphere [...] and not by the particular labour-time that each individual capitalist or employer within this sphere of production requires. [...] The quantity of labour by which, for example, [the value of] a yard of cotton is determined is therefore not the quantity of labour it contains [...] but the average quantity with which all the cottonmanufacturers produce one yard of cotton for the market. 7 Development of Ricardo's Theory of Value, The Quarterly Journal of Economics 18(4) (August 1904), pp. 456-75. 3 Ricardo, Principles. 4 TSV2, p. 193. 5 TSV2, p. 184 (italicisation added). 6 TSV2, p. 198. 7 TSV2, p. 204. 2

This, we have to suppose, explains Marx s particular interest in demonstrating the effects of changes in wages within a given branch of production (producing the same kind of product with a common production price) in which there are capitals of differing value compositions (i.e. of different levels of productivity of labour) through the assumption of the operation of the generalisation of the rate of profit and the redistribution of surplus-value as average profit that this provokes. At the end of the chapter, indeed, Marx makes the following comment: In this entire chapter, we have assumed that the establishment of a general rate of profit, an average profit, and thus also the transformation of values into production prices, is a given fact. 8 All that has been asked is how a general rise or fall in wages affects the prices of production of commodities, prices we have assumed to be given in advance. This is a very secondary question compared with the other important points which have been dealt with in this Part. Yet it is the only question Ricardo deals with which is relevant here, and as we shall see he deals with it only in a one-sided and inadequate way. 9 Unlike Ricardo, Marx is as interested in what happens when wages fall, as when they rise. * * * * * Ceteris paribus, an overall rise in wages means a fall in surplus-value. If the average composition of social capital is 80 c + 20 v, and the rate of surplus-value is 100 %, the rate of profit is 20 % (and for the average capital, profit and surplus-value coincide). If wages rise by 25 %, that amount of labour that cost 20 to set in motion now costs 25. But, all else (including the size of the workforce and the productivity of labour) being equal, the same amount of new value is still created, i.e. v + s ( = 40) is unchanged. If v rises, s falls by the same amount: s now stands at 15, and the rate of profit = = 14 %. Since we are considering capital operating under average conditions, the production price (and value) of the commodity product is unchanged. All a rise in wages means, all else being equal, is a fall in profit, both in terms of its mass and its rate. For the same physical quantity of output produced by 100 capital before the rise in wages, profit, which was previously 20, is now 15, a fall of 25 %. Production price (p p ) = p c (1 + ), where p c = cost price ( = c + v) and = average profit. (Cost price is a variable magnitude differing according to the value of the means of production that go into the commodities and according to the amount of depreciation that the fixed capital employed in their production surrenders to the product. 10 ) Before the rise in wages, p p = p c (1 + ); after, p p = p c (1 + ). The original value composition was 80 c + 20 v ; after the rise in wages it stands at 80 c + 25 v, which, in percentage terms, is 76 c + 23 v. The value composition has changed; though, because the productivity of labour is 11 constant, not its organic composition. 8 Indeed, for this seems to contradict Marx s assumptions elsewhere that it is not competition within single sectors that brings about the equalisation of the rate of profit, but that between sectors. What competition brings about, first of all in one sphere, is the establishment of a uniform market value and market price out of the various individual values of commodities. But it is only the competition of capitals in different spheres that brings forth the production price that equalizes the rates of profit between those spheres. C3, p. 281; cf. TSV2, pp. 205-8. 9 C3, p. 306 (italicisation added). 10 Karl Marx, Capital volume 3 (Harmondsworth, 1981) [hereafter C3], p. 302. 11 In the previous chapter (C3, pp. 243-5) Marx made the distinction with regard to the ratio of value proportions between variable and constant capital between what he calls a technical relation, a relation between a definite quantity of living labour and a definite quantity of objectified labour in physical use-value form and a value relation, which expresses the relation between a definite quantity of living labour and a definite quantity of objectified labour as labour. The organic composition 3

Let us now look at a capital whose composition is lower than the average: 50 c + 50 v ; we shall assume that the entire fixed capital enters into the final annual product, and that the turnover time is the same as in the first case. The production price of the product of 100 capital before the rise in wages = 50 c + 50 v + 20 = 120. An increase of wages of 25 % would mean a rise in v from 50 to 62 ; selling at the old production price gives us 50 c + 62 v + 7 (= 120). But the new average rate of profit is 14 % ; if our capital of 50 c + 62 v is to make this profit, then, since p p = p c (1 + ), our new post wage increase production price (of the product of 50 c + 62 v = 112 capital laid out) is = 112 (1 + ) = 128, up from 120 for the same quantity of commodity product. Profit (at the general rate of 14 % ) on the 112 capital laid out = 16. For a given quantity of commodity product the production price has risen by 7.1 % 12 while the mass of profit on this product has fallen by 18.8 %. Let us now look at a capital with a higher value composition: 92 c + 8 v. Prior to the rise in wages, p p again = 92 c + 8 v + 20 = 120 ; after the rise, v = 10, so p c = 92 c + 10 v = 102, and the new p p of the commodity product of 102 capital laid out = 102 (1 + ) = 116, down from 120 for the same quantity of commodity product. Profit on the 102 capital (at the new general rate of 14 % ) = 14, down from 20. For a given quantity of physical output, the production price has fallen by 2.9 %, while the mass of profit has fallen by 27.1 %. Conclusions: if wages rise in a given branch of production, all else being equal, that capital operating under average conditions of value composition (and hence, by definition, the total social capital in the branch) experiences a fall in profit on a given quantity of physical output equal in magnitude to the rise in wages. The price of production of its commodity product (and hence, again, the total price of production of the total commodity product of the branch) all else being equal is unchanged. For capital operating at value composition conditions lower than the average i.e. at a lower level of labour productivity, where a greater mass of labour is required to set a given mass of means of production in motion the price of production of the commodity product rises, and profit falls. The rate of fall of profit is however less then the rate of rise of wages, and the rate of rise of the production price is less again. For capital operating at higher than average value composition conditions, i.e. with a higher level of labour productivity, profit falls, and by a greater rate than the rise in wages, but the price of production falls too, at a rate less than both the rise in wages and the fall in production price. If the production price for commodities [...] [where the value composition is lower] rises, while it falls [...] [where the value composition is higher], this opposite effect which is produced by the fall in the rate of surplus-value or the general rise in wages already shows how there can be no corresponding compensation in prices for the rise in wages, since in [...] [the latter case] the fall in the price of production can in no way compensate the capitalists for the fall in their profit, while in [...] [the former] the rise in price still does not prevent a fall in profit. In each case, rather, both where the price rises and where it falls, profit is the same as for the average capital, whose prices remain unaffected. [...] It follows from this that, if the price did not rise in [...] [the former case] and fall in [...] [the latter], [...] [in the former case product] would be sold at less than the new, lower, average profit, and [...] [in the latter product would be sold] at more than this. It is immediately clear that according to whether 50, 25 or 10 out of every 100 units of capital are laid out on labour, a rise in wages will necessarily have very different effects on a capitalist who lays out a tenth of his capital on wages, one who lays out a quarter, and one who lays out a half. The rise in the price of production on the one hand and its fall on the other, according to whether the capital involved has a lower or higher is the value composition where this is determined by the technical composition, i.e. by the productivity of labour. Here, the value composition has changed not because a given quantity of labour converts a lesser mass of means of production into product, but because the value of labour-power has changed (wages have risen). 12 All decimal figures, unless otherwise indicated, are rounded to one decimal place. 4

composition than the social average, is accomplished only by the process of equalisation at the new, lower, average rate of profit. 13 As might be expected, similar, but opposite, results obtain when wages fall. Let us assume that wages fall by a quarter: in the case of the average capital, the commodity product now = 80 c + 15 v + 25 s ( = 120). The rate of surplus value passes from 100 % to = 166 %. The rate of profit, which is the average rate of profit for the branch, stands at = 26 %. The new value composition of capital is 84 c + 15 v, i.e. the value composition has risen. The rate of rise in the mass of profit on a given quantity of output is the same as the rate of fall of wages. For our capital of lower than average value composition, the production price of the product formerly produced by 50c + 50v capital now stands at 50 c + 37 v + [ 87 ) ] = 50 c + 37 v + 23 = 110. For a given quantity of product, the production price has fallen by a rate of 7.9 % and the mass of profit realised has risen by 15.1 %. For our capital operating in conditions of higher than average composition, the production price of the product previously produced by the capital of 92 c + 8 v laid out before the fall in wages now stands at 92 c + 6 v + [ 98 ) ] = 82 c + 6 v + 25 = 123. For a given quantity of commodity product, the price of production has risen by 3.2 %, and the mass of profit by 28.9 %. [T]he conclusion is that a general fall in wages leads to a general rise in surplus-value, in the rate of surplusvalue, and with other things remaining equal, also in the profit rate, even if in a different proportion; it leads to a fall in production prices for the commodity products of capitals of lower than average composition and a rise in production prices for the commodity products of capitals of higher than average composition. Exactly the opposite result as that which arose from a general rise in wages. 14 What would be the conditions that would provoke a fall (or rise) in wages? Here we assume a constant working day and unchanging prices of means of subsistence; hence a rise in wages would occur if they were already below their normal value, or rose above it (and a fall is assumed to arise because wages stand above their normal value or are forced below it). Whether fluctuations in wages occur because the values (and therefore production prices) of those commodities that form workers means of subsistence have changed will not be discussed here (although Marx does promise to return to the matter) other than to note that only in the case that the commodities whose prices have changed also enter production as constant capital (and hence do not simply affect wages) does the analysis here set out need to be modified. 13 C3, p. 304. 14 C3, p. 305. 5