Deferring Receipt of Public Pension Benefits: A Tool for Flexibility by

Similar documents
Plenary III Fast Forward to 2050: Retirement Redefined

Submission of the Canadian Institute of Actuaries to the Commission des affaires sociales

A STRONGER RETIREMENT INCOME SYSTEM MEETING THE EXPECTATIONS OF QUEBECERS OF EVERY GENERATION

Projection Assumption Guidelines

Mothers at Work: The Fiscal Implications of the Proposed Ontario Childcare Rebate

Projection Assumption Standards

Québec s Retirement System: An Overview and the Challenges

Projection Assumption Guidelines

A Look at Household Assets in Quebec: Their Room for Manoeuvre is There Sufficient?

Projection Assumption Guidelines

Province of British Columbia Ministry of Finance MECHANISMS FOR EXPANDING PENSION COVERAGE AND RETIREMENT INCOME ADEQUACY IN CANADA

Projection Assumption Standards

Projection Assumption Standards

Middle Class Retirement Incomes in Canada: Some Issues and Options

From: Pensions at a Glance 2013 OECD and G20 Indicators. Access the complete publication at:

Projection Assumption Guidelines

ACTUARIAL REPORT 12 th. on the

Making the Money Last: The Case for Offering Pure Longevity Insurance to Retiring Canadians

Kevin Milligan, Vancouver School of Economics and NBER Tammy Schirle, Wilfrid Laurier University

Re: Enhancing the efficiency of retirement income options for older Canadians

promoting phased retirement Budget

Securing Canada s Retirement Income System

The report of the Expert Panel on Older Workers: How should public pensions be improved?*

Simulated Replacement Rates for CPP Reform Options

Actuarial Funding Report as at January 1, 2018

CIA Pension Seminar Colloque sur les régimes de retraite

BUDGET Quebecers and Their Disposable Income. Greater Wealth

Living and Working Longer in an Aging Society: Towards Increasing Inequalities?

Amendments to the Canada Pension Plan to be phased in from 2011 to 2016

ACTUARIAL REPORT 25 th. on the

L Évolution récente des comportements de retraite au Canada

Optimal Funding of the Canada Pension Plan

P O L I C Y I S S U E S O N R E T I R E M E N T

OECD-SOCR metadata on income replacement programmes - Canada

PUBLIC POSITION. Meeting the Needs of Canada s Future Retirees A CALL TO TIMELY ACTION: NOVEMBER 10, 2015 SUMMARY OF CIA POSITION

Taking care of your future. Now.

Retirement income. LifeAnew A deferred life annuity that s 100% guaranteed for life

The Canada Pension Plan Retirement Pension

e-brief What s My METR? Marginal Effective Tax Rates Are Down But Not for Everyone: The Ontario Case April 27, 2011

Retirement Plan of the University of St. Michael s College

The French Pension Reform Five Years Later: Assessment and Pending Issues. by Anne Lavigne

ACTUARIAL REPORT 27 th. on the

WELCOME TO PENSION SERVICES GLOSSARY OF TERMS

Recent Amendments to Canada's Retirement Income Security System

' 1. HD C2q SURVIVOR BENEFITS UNDER THE CANADA. e,.,. _ PENSION PLAN. Consultation Paper September 1987.

The Fiscal Implications of Canadians Working Longer

An Improved Application of the Variable Annuity

Her Majesty the Queen in Right of Canada (2017) All rights reserved

What you need A PENSION PLAN FOR YOU. Information for new employees about the features of HOOPP

Will the Retirement of Canadian Baby Boomers Deflate Asset Values? Prepared By Doug Andrews, PhD, FCIA, FSA, FIA, CFA University of Kent

A guide to valuable workplace pensions

PENSION PLAN BASICS. Summary of The Canadian Christian School Pension Plan and Trust Fund. FSCO and CRA Registration No

Is There an Optimal Level of Pre-Funding? Optimal Funding of the Canada Pension Plan

GREYHOUND WESTERN EMPLOYEES RETIREMENT INCOME PLAN YOUR PENSION PLAN SUMMARY

This financial framework is responsible. Its goals are sound management of public finances, improved services and more money in the pockets of

CANADA PENSION PLAN SIXTEENTH ACTUARIAL REPORT

Assuming more responsibility for retirement: The reality of preparedness and building a sustainable income.

Budgetary Process and Documents

e-brief September 30, 2008

14-10 REFORMING OLD AGE SECURITY: EFFECTS AND ALTERNATIVES CAHIER DE RECHERCHE WORKING PAPER

GROUP SAVINGS & RETIREMENT. The basics of retirement planning. Plan for life

Workshop 4 Decumulating the Accumulation Changing CAP Behaviours

Major reform proposed to pension plan funding rules in Quebec

...a retirement with dignity and security is possible

COMMENTARY PENSION PAPERS

How can I obtain information relating to my pension investment?

Past Service Pension Adjustment Guide

DRAFT. A microsimulation analysis of public and private policies aimed at increasing the age of retirement 1. April Jeff Carr and André Léonard

The labour force participation of older men in Canada

THE QUÉBEC ECONOMIC PLAN. March Disposable Income BUDGET More Money for Each Quebecer

Pension Adjustment Guide

29 June The Honourable Lloyd Axworthy, P.C., M.P. Minister of Human Resources Development House of Commons Ottawa, Ontario K1A 0G5

PENSIONS AT A GLANCE 2009: RETIREMENT-INCOME SYSTEMS IN OECD COUNTRIES CANADA

For Your Name and Spouse Here. Presented by: Dolph Janis Clear Income Strategies Phone:

Canadian Labour Market and Skills Researcher Network

Business Tax Burdens in Canada s Major Cities: The 2017 Report Card

En cas d acquittement des droits des participants et des bénéficiaires au moyen d une subrogation en application de l article 61.0.

Older respondents expect to live longer

Actuarial Report (24 th ) supplementing the Actuarial Report on the CANADA PENSION PLAN

Issue Number 60 August A publication of the TIAA-CREF Institute

RREGOP. The Government and Public Employees Retirement Plan

Longevity and Retirement: Thinking Outside the Box on Canada s Retirement Income System

Later Retirement: the Win-Win Solution

Should I Buy an Income Annuity?

Re: Tax and Retirement Savings Innovations to Promote Retirement Income

THE RREGOP. The Government and Public Employees Retirement Plan JANUARY 2016

Are Today s Working Canadians Saving Enough for Tomorrow s Retirement?

BUDGET Quebecers and Their Retirement. Accessible Plans for All

THE RREGOP. The Government and Public Employees Retirement Plan

Quebec Expert Committee Report on a Sustainable Retirement System

Actuarial Valuation of the Canada Pension Plan

New CPP Enhancements: What do they

Old Age Security and the Canada Pension Plan

Enhancement of the Canada Pension Plan

Phased Retirement The CPP Experience La retraite progressive l expérience du régime de pensions du Canada (RPC)

TEACHERS RETIREMENT BOARD. REGULAR MEETING Item Number: 7 CONSENT: ATTACHMENT(S): 1. DATE OF MEETING: November 8, 2018 / 60 mins

14-06 AN ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF PROPOSALS TO IMPROVE COVERAGE OF LONGEVITY RISK CAHIER DE RECHERCHE WORKING PAPER

Planning for Income to Last

POLICY BRIEF. A Stronger Foundation. Pension Reform and Old Age Security. By Monica Townson. November 2009

Nova Scotia Teachers Pension Plan Guide Booklet. Nova Scotia Teachers Pension Plan Guide Booklet

Transcription:

Institut C.D. HOWE Institute Conseils indispensables sur les politiques ebrief June 26, 18 PENSION POLICY Deferring Receipt of Public Pension Benefits: A Tool for Flexibility by Antoine GenestGrégoire, Luc Godbout, René Beaudry, and Bernard Morency Under the Canadian public pension system, CPP and QPP benefits can start at any time between age 6 and 7 and Old Security benefits at any time between 65 and 7. benefits are reduced if they start before age 65, and all public benefits are enhanced if commencement is after age 65. There is no requirement to cease work or employment to start these benefits. This EBrief analyzes the implications of public pension deferral and opportunities to effectively convert private savings into secure, inflationindexed public pensions. We recommend that the permitted deferral period be extended, to allow middleand uppermiddle income Canadians greater retirement planning flexibility to the extent they have private savings and are willing to consume those savings more quickly. The proportion of retirement needs covered by public programs increases considerably when the benefits are taken later. The deferrals enhance the annual amounts of received, which in turn lowers the amount of savings required. Pension deferral is thus both an effective means of reducing the savings required overall and of reducing risk. A key and misunderstood aspect of retirement planning is the option Canadians have to defer the time when they start receiving public pension benefits. 1 Indeed, retirees may start collecting Old Security (), Quebec Pension Plan (QPP) and Canada Pension Plan (CPP) benefits as late as age 7. Public pension benefits increase with each year of deferral, allowing workers who have enough private savings considerable flexibility The authors thank Alexandre Laurin, Keith Ambachtsheer, Stephen Bonnar, Moshe Milevsky, James Pesando, James Pierlot, Tammy Schirle, members of the C.D. Howe Institute Pension Policy Council and anonymous reviewers for comments on an earlier draft. They retain responsibility for any errors and the views expressed. 1 The analysis presented here is drawn from a recent study (GenestGrégoire et al. 17) by the Research Chair in Taxation and Public Finance at Université de Sherbrooke, referred to as CFFP, its French acronym, hereafter.

2 ebrief to optimize the mix of public and privatesource retirement income. This flexibility can be a great help in protecting retirees against the inherently risky nature of financial markets (Wolfson 11) and the possibility of outliving their savings, an important risk in aging societies (OECD 16). This EBrief analyzes the implications of public pension deferral and opportunities to effectively convert private savings into secure, inflationindexed public pensions. We recommend that the permitted deferral period be extended, to allow middle and uppermiddle income Canadians greater retirement planning flexibility to the extent they have private savings and are willing to consume those savings more quickly. Structure of the Canadian Pension System The Canadian pension system has three components, which are often associated with the floors of a house or the pillars that support a structure. 1. Old Security () and Guaranteed Income Supplement: Provided by the federal government, and the Guaranteed Income Supplement (GIS) provide a basic income to Canadians 65 years or older. This basic income is higher for lowincome Canadians because of the GIS and slightly lower to nonexistent for highincome retirees. This program is funded directly from the federal government s general revenue and is indexed to inflation. Residency requirements apply to the accrual and payment of and GIS benefits. 2. Quebec Pension Plan and Canada Pension Plan (): These plans pay a lifetime pension to retirees based on their career incomes. Employees and employers contribute to the plans based on an indexed maximum employmentincome amount of $55,9 (18). The maximum pension paid at 65 years old currently corresponds to 25 percent of this amount, indexed to costofliving increases. 3. Private savings and pension plans: Retirement income also comes from money saved by retirees during the course of their career, either by themselves or with the support of their employer. These savings include such investments as company pension plans or financial assets held in an RRSP or other registered vehicles. Plan Flexibility The Canadian public pension system offers significant flexibility. benefits can start at any time between age 6 and 7 and benefits at any time between 65 and 7. 2 benefits are reduced if they start before age 65, and all public benefits are enhanced if commencement is after age 65. There is no requirement to cease work or employment to start these benefits. The Research Chair in Taxation and Public Finance (CFFP) simulator demonstrates the impact of deferral for persons with earnings equal to Yearly Maximum Pensionable Earnings (YMPE) in 16. All cases presented in this EBrief are of individuals who reached this income level, i.e., $54,9, with a target replacement rate of 6 percent of their last year of employment income (adjusted for inflation afterwards). Amounts are considered before taxes, as taxes vary among provinces. 2 All examples presented in this EBrief are based on 16 data.

ebrief 3 Table 1: Maximum Public Pension Plan Benefits, Based on Retirement, ($17) Total taken at 6 years and at 65 8,557 7,26 15,583 taken at 65 13,37 7,26,396 taken at 7 18,985 9,555 28,5 Source : Retraite Québec & Employment and Social Development Canada. Table 2: Comparisons Based on at Which Benefits Start after Retiring at 6 at which & are taken 6 65 65 7 Total private savings required to reach replacement rate objective ($) 435, 5, 391, Required annualized savings rate 17.1% 15.9% 15.4% Replacement rate guaranteed by the public plans at age 7 (objective: 6%) of the replacement objective guaranteed by the public plans at age 7 28% 35% 47% 46% 58% 78% Financial retirement needs depend on a retiree s income replacement target, but also on uncertain factors such as life expectancy. At 6 or 65 years old, few retirees can accurately anticipate their exact financial needs for the length of their retirement. This uncertainty pushes many of them to be overly prudent in their spending habits for fear of running out of money if they live too long or need expensive endoflife care. Studies have consistently shown that retirees hold on to their financial assets as long as they can to mitigate these risks, often causing impairment to their lifestyle (MacDonald 18). The Financial Planning Standards Council and the Institut québécois de planification financière recommend that retirees plan for capital depletion no earlier than at age 94 years (75 percent of men and 6 percent of women are deceased by that age). This precautionary rule is not without cost: dying early means an earlier unnecessary reduction in living standards, while those outliving their savings face a shortfall and lower living standards at the end of life. Efficient use of public pension benefit deferrals, however, can reduce the cost of this precautionary behaviour (Table 2). The proportion of retirement needs covered by public programs increases considerably when the benefits are taken later. The deferrals enhance the annual amounts of received, which in turn lowers the amount of savings required. Pension deferral is thus both an effective means of reducing the savings required overall and of reducing risk. In fact, the more you rely on private savings for retirement, the greater the risk you have to assume

4 ebrief Box 1: CFFP Simulator Model The CFFP simulator model calculates public benefits and the savings required to achieve a certain standard of living in retirement. It represents a simplified life trajectory for illustrative purposes and should not be considered financial planning advice on a personal basis. Optimal retirement planning requires personal knowledge about health, employment history and life objectives which we don t possess. The model includes: Simulations performed for 16; Simulated income level: $27,45, $54,9 and $82,35 (5 percent, 1 percent and 15 percent of the YMPE, constant for each year in the workforce); Simulated ages of retirement for 6 or 65 years; Simulated ages at which public pension benefits are taken: between 6 and 75 years for, and between 65 and 75 years for ; Targeted replacement income rate at retirement: 7 percent of last year of employment gross income for people earning 5 percent of the YMPE and 6 percent for those earning 1 percent or 15 percent of the YMPE; Start of employment at age 25; The effect of dropout provisions are integrated; Start of retirement savings at 3; Rate of return, net of management fees, at 5 percent; Projected inflation rate of 2.1 percent; and Capital depletion at 94 years (75 percent of men and 6 percent of women are deceased at this age, which is the standard of prudence used by the Financial Planning Standards Council and the Institut québécois de planification financière). because of market fluctuations both before and after retirement. Moreover, private savings can fall short if a person lives longer than anticipated. Deferring the start of benefits helps protect against this risk, because once public benefits are determined, they are guaranteed for life.

ebrief 5 Figure 1: of Targeted Retirement Income From Various Sources, Retirement at 6 Years Old 3, Salary at 6 and at 65 55 6 65 7 75 8 85 9 of career earnings(%) 1 8 6 and at 65 3, Salary 55 6 65 7 75 8 85 9 of career earnings(%) 1 8 6 and at 7 3, Salary 55 6 65 7 75 8 85 9 of career earnings(%) 1 8 6

6 ebrief Figure 2: of Targeted Retirement Income From Various Sources, Retirement at 65 Years Old 3, Salary and at 7 6 65 7 75 8 85 9 of career earnings or maximum YMPE (%) 1 8 6 reformed, and at 7 3, Salary 6 65 7 75 8 85 9 of career earnings (%) 1 8 6 Reforms Announced The are in the process of being reformed to increase coverage up to 33 percent (instead of 25 percent) of income up to a ceiling of $62,586 in 16 dollars. 3 Under such reforms, it becomes possible for a person who reaches the YMPE and who retires at 65 to attain a replacement rate guaranteed by the public plans of 6 percent of the YMPE and thus have full public coverage of their assumed needs through maximum deferral of the and the benefit. The reduced required savings rates that the reform allows are clearly associated with higher contribution rates to the during the retiree s career, which do not appear in Table 3. However, it is important to note that the savings rates are reduced more than the combined increase in contributions by the employer and employee, because the increased contributions are based on projected performances higher than our performance assumption for the private savings that the contributions replace. The enhancement of the pension plan thus results in public coverage at lower cost, even factoring in the additional contributions. 3 The reform will not be fully implemented until 65, but the numbers are converted to 16 amounts for comparison purposes.

ebrief 7 Table 3: Comparisons Based on at which Benefits Start, Before and After the Reform Retirement 65 65 at which and Are Taken 65 7 Before the Change Total private savings required ($) 265, 248, Required annualized savings rate 8.2% 7.7% Replacement rate guaranteed by the public plans at age 7 (objective: 6%) 37% 49% of the replacement objective guaranteed by the public plans at age 7 61% 82% After the Change Fully Implemented Total private savings required ($) 175, 156, Required annualized savings rate 5.4% 4.8% Replacement rate guaranteed by the public plans at age 7(objective: 6%) 45% 6% of the replacement objective guaranteed by the public plans at age 7 74% 1% Box 2: QPP and CPP, Cut from the Same Cloth The simulations presented in this EBrief are all based on the QPP rather than the CPP. Although the two plans are enhanced in the same way, there are differences between them. However, these differences are too subtle to change the simulation results presented here: they would not show up in Figures 1 and 2. The trends and findings identified are thus exactly the same, both under the QPP and CPP. Box 3: Sensitivity Analysis The trends presented in this EBrief hold even when underlying hypotheses are relaxed. For example, lowering the age of capital depletion from 94 to 89 years would reduce the amount of required savings for retirees whose income target is not fully covered by public benefits. For others, the guaranteed public benefits would cost the same but simply be offered for a shorter period.

8 ebrief Box 3: continued Figure 3 : Required Annualized Rate (%) Percent 18 Pensions taken at 6/65 16 14 Pensions taken at 7/7 12 1 8 6 7 72 74 76 78 8 82 84 86 88 9 92 94 96 98 1 at Capital Depletion Relaxing the assumed age of capital depletion highlights the fact that pension deferral lowers the cost of insuring against longevity. A person taking her retirement at 6 (and her and as soon as possible), under the current system, and dying before age 84 would not gain from pension deferral. But since most people live longer than that age, they can insure their target lifetime income at a lower cost through deferral (shown by the 7/7 curve in Figure 3). In a similar fashion, a delayed entry into the workforce or a delayed beginning of saving for retirement would lead to higher required savings. A lower rate of return on savings would have the same effect and make the goal of full public overage even more desirable, in comparison. The simulator is built such that savings adjust to fill the gap between public benefits and the target replacement rate. As such, the savings rate will always be the adjusting factor when hypotheses are relaxed.

ebrief 9 Another Potential Avenue for Enhancement The reform described above is to be implemented gradually, and not completed until 65, to ensure no intergenerational transfers. In addition, extending the allowable deferral period from the current 7 years old to, say, 75 years, would provide full coverage immediately. If the deferral helps increase the public coverage of retirees but does not allow them to attain a rate of 1 percent public coverage now, it is because deferral is limited to age 7. By allowing deferral up to age 75, for example, it would become possible for a person who reached the YMPE to obtain full public coverage even before the reform is implemented. Box 4: Enhancement Rate Past 7 The enhancement rate in case of deferral relies on an actuarial calculation. The benefits provided are more generous because they are provided, on average, for a shorter period of time if the person takes them later. The simulations presented here are based on the assumption that the enhancement rates from 7 to 75 years are the same as those in force between 65 and 7 years. However, from an actuarial standpoint, this enhancement rate should be even higher after 7 years. In this case, the savings required to take the pension at 75 years indicated in Table 4 would be less. Moreover, the public coverage rate for people who apply for deferral past 7 years would be even higher, and it would be possible for the person at the YMPE to attain full public coverage earlier than 75 years. Table 4: Comparisons Based on at which Benefits Start, with the Possibility of Deferring up to 75 Years, Retirement at 65 Years Old at which and Are Taken 65 7 75 Total savings required ($) 265, 248, 291, Required annualized savings rate 8.2% 7.7% 9.1% Replacement rate guaranteed by the public plans at age 75 (objective: 6%) of the replacement objective guaranteed by the public plans at age 75 37% 49% 62% 61% 82% 13%

1 ebrief Figure 4 : Extending the Deferral to 75. of Targeted Retirement Income From Various Sources, Retirement at 65 Years Old and at 65 3, Salary 6 65 7 75 8 85 9 of career earnings(%) 1 8 6 and at 75 3, Salary 6 65 7 75 8 85 9 of career earnings(%) 1 8 6 Box 5: Other Income Levels The CFFP simulator also covers workers who reached 5 percent of the YMPE (about $27,5) and those who reached 15 percent (nearly $82,5). Those whose income is equal to half the YMPE may currently attain full public coverage at retirement, especially because of the GIS from which they may benefit. In their case, pension deferral is less useful, unless they want an income replacement rate upon retirement that exceeds 7 percent. For those whose income was 15 percent of the YMPE, pension deferral allows them to increase the portion of their target retirement covered by public pensions. However, they cannot hope to attain full coverage by these means, primarily because their employment income is too high. The CPP and QPP are insurance programs that cover income up to a certain level, the YMPE. People whose income exceeds this threshold necessarily have a public pension that, proportional to their employment income, is less than those whose income is below it. However, it should be noted that the reform provides for a YMPE increase, which will improve the situation for these people.

ebrief 11 Implications for Public Policies The proposal to extend the deferral period from age 7 to 75 for and is made with a view to increasing flexibility to help Canadians get better value from public pension coverage, insofar as they are prepared to save the amounts required to access this option and to cash in their savings more quickly early in their retirement. It is a simple reform that can be implemented at very little cost to these plans. It is a proposal that would complement the announced reforms by increasing the options available to middle and upperclass income workers and, especially, by offering new options well before the more ambitious enhancements are completely implemented. Every retiree s situation varies depending on their health, work and saving history, but pension deferral is already a worthwhile option for a majority of them, and the proposed reforms would most likely make it more so. Many myths exist surrounding retirement planning, and it is a subject about which Canadians regularly say that they do not have all the knowledge required to make informed choices. It is thus important to point out that it would be useful to combine this increased flexibility with efforts to raise awareness and provide information. The simple fact of offering new opportunities does not greatly improve the situation of retirees if no one makes use of them. For example, the existing startingage flexibility of the plans is not used a great deal by retirees, as evidenced by the fact that only about 3 percent of new QPP beneficiaries and 6 percent of new CPP beneficiaries are over 65 years old. 4,5 The reform we propose, accompanied by education, would make the and respond better to seniors needs, especially those in the middletoupper income range. We expect that greater benefit flexibility and better understanding of public pension benefits will lead to increased public support for and a stronger feeling of ownership of these plans, which in turn will contribute to the soundness and sustainability of these important components of the Canadian social safety net. 4 See Retraite Québec (16), Statistiques 15 Régime de rentes du Québec [statistics on the Quebec pension plan], p. 64. 5 See Canada Pension Plan (CPP) Number of New Retirement Pension by, Gender and by Calendar Year. Available at: 15, https://open.canada.ca/data/en/dataset/ea75b9f443c48d75132cbbc7d.

12 ebrief References GenestGrégoire, Antoine, Luc Godbout, and Martin Dupras. 17. Régimes de retraite publics : Analyse de la flexibilité du système actuel et effets d une réforme possible. Université de Sherbrooke: Chaire en fiscalité et en finances publiques. Cahier de recherche 17/8. August. MacDonald, BonnieJeanne. 18. Headed for the Poorhouse: How to Ensure Seniors Don t Run Out of Cash before They Run Out of Time. Commentary 5. Toronto: C.D. Howe Institute. January. Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development. 16. OECD Pensions Outlook 16. Wolfson, Michael. 11. Projecting the Adequacy of Canadians Retirement Incomes : Current Prospects and Possible Reform Options. Institute for Research on Public Policy Study No 17. This EBrief is a publication of the C.D. Howe Institute. Antoine GenestGrégoire, is Senior Research Associate, Université de Sherbrooke. Luc Godbout, is Professor, Faculty of Business Administration, Université de Sherbrooke; Senior Fellow in Public Finance at the Research Chair in Taxation and Public Finance. René Beaudry, FSA, FCIA, is Partner, Normandin Beaudry, Consulting Actuaries Inc. Bernard Morency is Adjunct Professor at HEC Montréal and Senior Fellow at the C.D. Howe Institute. This EBrief is available at www.cdhowe.org. Permission is granted to reprint this text if the content is not altered and proper attribution is provided. The views expressed here are those of the authors. The C.D. Howe Institute does not take corporate positions on policy matters.