International Money and Banking: 15. The Phillips Curve: Evidence and Implications

Similar documents
Analysing the IS-MP-PC Model

Advanced Macroeconomics 4. The Zero Lower Bound and the Liquidity Trap

Chapter 24. The Role of Expectations in Monetary Policy

The Model at Work. (Reference Slides I may or may not talk about all of this depending on time and how the conversation in class evolves)

1 The empirical relationship and its demise (?)

International Money and Banking: 14. Real Interest Rates, Lower Bounds and Quantitative Easing

TOPIC 7. Unemployment, Inflation and Economic Policy

Cost Shocks in the AD/ AS Model

The Short-Run Tradeoff Between Inflation and Unemployment

Objectives for Chapter 24: Monetarism (Continued) Chapter 24: The Basic Theory of Monetarism (Continued) (latest revision October 2004)

What is Equilibrium for the Economy?

Macroeconomic Issues and Policy. Stabilization Policy. Time Lags Regarding Monetary and Fiscal Policy

International Money and Banking: 8. How Central Banks Set Interest Rates

EC3115 Monetary Economics

Macroeconomics. The Short-Run Trade-off Between Inflation and Unemployment. Introduction. In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:

To sum up: What is an Equilibrium?

THE SHORT-RUN TRADEOFF BETWEEN INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT

International Money and Banking: 6. Problems with Monetarism

Notes VI - Models of Economic Fluctuations

Advanced Macroeconomics 6. Rational Expectations and Consumption

EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE PHILLIPS CURVE

The Economist March 2, Rules v. Discretion

Macroeconomics, Cdn. 4e (Williamson) Chapter 1 Introduction

13.2 Monetary Policy Rules and Aggregate Demand Introduction 6/24/2014. Stabilization Policy and the AS/AD Framework.

Session 9. The Interactions Between Cyclical and Long-term Dynamics: The Role of Inflation

Advanced Macroeconomics 5. Rational Expectations and Asset Prices

Macroeconomics in the World Economy: Theory and Applications Topic 7: Unemployment & Inflation: Policy in Action

The Short-Run Tradeoff Between Inflation and Unemployment

Notes 6: Examples in Action - The 1990 Recession, the 1974 Recession and the Expansion of the Late 1990s

3.36pt. Karl Whelan (UCD) Term Structure of Interest Rates Spring / 36

Taylor and Mishkin on Rule versus Discretion in Fed Monetary Policy

Module 31. Monetary Policy and the Interest Rate. What you will learn in this Module:

To sum up: What is an Equilibrium?

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 11. The Smets-Wouters Model

MA Advanced Macroeconomics 3. Examples of VAR Studies

Macro theory: A quick review

ECON 110, Professor Hogendorn. Problem Set 7

: Monetary Economics and the European Union. Lecture 5. Instructor: Prof Robert Hill. Inflation Targeting

Suggested answers to Problem Set 5

Policy in the AS/AD Model Revised: January 9, 2012

The Short-Run Tradeoff between Inflation and Unemployment. Chapter 33

Improving the Use of Discretion in Monetary Policy

International Money and Banking: 3. Liquidity and Solvency

Francis Cairncross: Professor Friedman, in recent years, we have seen an acceleration in inflation all over the world. What has caused that?

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy Lecture 11: Zero Lower Bound and Unconventional Monetary Policy. Martin Blomhoff Holm

Low Inflation and the Symmetry of the 2 Percent Target

Inflation Targeting and Inflation Prospects in Canada

Chapter Eighteen 4/19/2018. Linking Tools to Objectives. Linking Tools to Objectives

Charles I Plosser: Strengthening our monetary policy framework through commitment, credibility, and communication

Chapter 10. Conduct of Monetary Policy: Tools, Goals, Strategy, and Tactics. Chapter Preview

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA Economics 134 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Spring 2018 Professor David Romer NOTES ON THE MIDTERM

International Money and Banking: 13. Default Risk and Collateral

Strengthening Our Monetary Policy Framework Through Commitment, Credibility, and Communication

Expectations Theory and the Economy CHAPTER

Rational Expectations and Consumption

ECON 110, Professor Hogendorn. Problem Set 8

Lecture 4: A Science of Monetary Policy?

Simple Notes on the ISLM Model (The Mundell-Fleming Model)

Key Idea: We consider labor market, goods market and money market simultaneously.

Exam #3 (Final Exam) Solution Notes Spring, 2011

Solutions to PSet 5. October 6, More on the AS/AD Model

Review: Markets of Goods and Money

ECONOMICS U$A 21 ST CENTURY EDITION PROGRAM #24 FEDERAL DEFICITS Annenberg Foundation & Educational Film Center

Money and Monetary Policy. Economic Forces in American History

Re-Normalize, Don t New-Normalize Monetary Policy. John B. Taylor. Economics Working Paper 14109

SNS - Ricerca di base - Programma Manuela Moschella

Yes, We Can Reduce the Unemployment Rate

Macroeonomics. 22 this chapter, look for the answers to these questions: The Phillips Curve. Introduction. N. Gregory Mankiw

Chapter 12: Unemployment and Inflation

Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment. Noah Williams

If a model were to predict that prices and money are inversely related, that prediction would be evidence against that model.

Commentary: Challenges for Monetary Policy: New and Old

Introduction. Learning Objectives. Chapter 17. Stabilization in an Integrated World Economy

Potential Output in Ireland Presentation at TCD-DEW Conference

Econ 110: Introduction to Economic Theory. 35th Class 4/25/11. Keynes vs. Hayek rap:

The Phillips Curve. The Phillips Curve. Hypothetical Example. The original Phillips Curve. PC u% 3. Coach Burnett AP Macroeconomics

Advanced Macroeconomics 8. Growth Accounting

Overview. Stanley Fischer

From The Collected Works of Milton Friedman, compiled and edited by Robert Leeson and Charles G. Palm.

ECON MACROECONOMIC THEORY Instructor: Dr. Juergen Jung Towson University

Comments on Foreign Effects of Higher U.S. Interest Rates. James D. Hamilton. University of California at San Diego.

Money Demand. ECON 40364: Monetary Theory & Policy. Eric Sims. Fall University of Notre Dame

AGGREGATE SUPPLY, AGGREGATE DEMAND, AND INFLATION: PUTTING IT ALL TOGETHER Macroeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.)

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research. Volume Title: The Inflation-Targeting Debate

Macroeconomics: Policy, 31E23000, Spring 2018

Monetary Policy Revised: January 9, 2008

Aggregate demand. Short run aggregate demand (AD) function: Monetary rule followed by the government: Short run aggregate supply (AS) function:

Chapter 16. MODERN PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS Third Edition

Inflation and Unemployment

The future of inflation targeting?

So far in the short-run analysis we have ignored the wage and price (we assume they are fixed).

Real Business Cycle Model

Laurence Ball Johns Hopkins University March 25, 2010 TESTIMONY BEFORE THE HOUSE COMMITTEE ON FINANCIAL SERVICES

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 12. Default Risk, Collateral and Credit Rationing

1. Introduction to Macroeconomics

Your Name: Final Exam: 18 Dec 2003 Econ 200 David Reiley

Midsummer Examinations 2013

Tradeoff Between Inflation and Unemployment

Lecture 13: The Great Depression

Haruhiko Kuroda: Moving forward Japan s economy under Quantitative and Qualitative Monetary Easing

Transcription:

International Money and Banking: 15. The Phillips Curve: Evidence and Implications Karl Whelan School of Economics, UCD Spring 2018 Karl Whelan (UCD) The Phillips Curve Spring 2018 1 / 26

Monetary Policy and Tradeoffs We have seen how monetary policy is a powerful tool that can affect the economy by influencing all the key interest rates that affect spending decisions. So, why don t central banks always intervene to keep interest rates low and growth high? You probably have an idea of the answer already: There s no such thing as a free lunch. Life is full of tradeoffs. For monetary policy, the problem is that stimulating the economy too much tends to boost inflation. We have seen how central banks that create a lot of money tend to produce inflation but we have also seen that, at low-to-medium levels of inflation, the relationship between money growth and inflation is not a strong one. To understand the limits to monetary policy, we need to study the link between the real economy and inflation. We will do that now, starting with some background on how thinking about inflation has evolved since the 1960s. Karl Whelan (UCD) The Phillips Curve Spring 2018 2 / 26

Part I The Phillips Curve Karl Whelan (UCD) The Phillips Curve Spring 2018 3 / 26

The Phillips Curve What are the tradeoffs facing a central bank? A 1958 study by the LSE s A.W. Phillips seemed to provide the answer. Phillips documented a strong negative relationship between wage inflation and unemployment: Low unemployment was associated with high inflation, presumably because tight labour markets stimulated wage inflation. A 1960 study by MIT economists Solow and Samuelson replicated these findings for the US and emphasised that the relationship also worked for price inflation. The Phillips curve tradeoff quickly became the basis for the discussion of macroeconomic policy. Policy faced a tradeoff: Lower unemployment could be achieved, but only at the cost of higher inflation. However, Milton Friedman s 1968 presidential address to the American Economic Association produced a well-timed and influential critique of the thinking underlying the Phillips Curve. Karl Whelan (UCD) The Phillips Curve Spring 2018 4 / 26

One of A. W. Phillips s Graphs Karl Whelan (UCD) The Phillips Curve Spring 2018 5 / 26

Solow and Samuelson s Description of the Phillips Curve Karl Whelan (UCD) The Phillips Curve Spring 2018 6 / 26

The Expectations-Augmented Phillips Curve Friedman pointed out that it was expected real wages that affected wage bargaining. If low unemployment means workers have strong bargaining position, then high nominal wage inflation on its own is not good enough: They want nominal wage inflation greater than price inflation. Assuming wage inflation gets passed through to price inflation, this gives us the following model of price inflation, known as the expectations-augmented Phillips curve: π t = π e t γ(u t U ) Friedman pointed out if policy-makers tried to exploit an apparent Phillips curve tradeoff, then the public would get used to high inflation and come to expect it: πt e would drift up and the tradeoff between inflation and output would worsen. In the long-run, you can t fool the public (π e t π t ) so you can t keep unemployment away from its natural rate U t U. Karl Whelan (UCD) The Phillips Curve Spring 2018 7 / 26

The Demise of the Basic Phillips Curve US monetary and fiscal policy in the 1960s were very expansionary. At first, the Phillips curve seemed to work: Inflation rose and unemployment fell. However, as the public got used to high inflation, the Phillips tradeoff got worse. By the late 1960s inflation was still rising even though unemployment had moved up. This stagflation combination of high inflation and high unemployment got even worse in the 1970s. This was exactly what Friedman predicted would happen. Today, the data no longer show any sign of a negative relationship between inflation and unemployment. If fact, the correlation is positive: The original formulation of the Phillips curve is widely agreed to be wrong. And the 1960s are now seen as an example of what goes wrong when monetary policy pursues the wrong goals. Karl Whelan (UCD) The Phillips Curve Spring 2018 8 / 26

The Evolution of US Inflation and Unemployment Karl Whelan (UCD) The Phillips Curve Spring 2018 9 / 26

The Failure of the Phillips Curve Karl Whelan (UCD) The Phillips Curve Spring 2018 10 / 26

The Accelerationist Phillips Curve What determines inflationary expectations? Friedman argued they are determined adaptively. For instance, people use last year s inflation rate as a guide to what to expect this year. In this case, this would mean π e t = π t 1, so the expectations-augmented Phillips curve becomes π t = π t 1 γ(u t U ) This relates the change in inflation to the gap between unemployment and its natural rate. When unemployment is below its natural rate, inflation will be increasing; when it is above it, it will be decreasing. Because it relates the rate of acceleration of the price level to unemployment, this is known as the accelerationist Phillips curve. This model fits the data pretty well. Karl Whelan (UCD) The Phillips Curve Spring 2018 11 / 26

The Success of the Accelerationist Phillips Curve Karl Whelan (UCD) The Phillips Curve Spring 2018 12 / 26

Real-World Complications The accelerationist Phillips curve relationship between the change in inflation and the unemployment rate seems to offer a key tool to central bankers, and it is indeed useful. However, as with all models, the real world is a bit more complicated than the simple model. Two complications are worth noting: 1 Supply shocks: The economy is constantly being hit with shocks that temporarily shift the inflation-output tradeoff, so that it becomes π t = γ(u t U ) + s t Bad supply shocks are ones that raise inflation even though the unemployment rate hasn t changed (oil price shocks are a good example). 2 The natural rate, U, is not a universal constant. It changes over time and, at any point in time central bankers must guess it. For instance in Europe the natural rate rose substantially in the 1980s and 1990s. More generally, central bankers are usually unsure of how fast the economy can grow without triggering inflationary pressures. Karl Whelan (UCD) The Phillips Curve Spring 2018 13 / 26

Tradeoffs Offered by The Accelerationist Phillips Curve Over the short-term, the accelerationist model describes a new tradeoff for central bankers. For instance, they can choose to keep the unemployment rate below the natural rate for a while at the expense of increasing inflation. But it doesn t really offer an exploitable long-run tradeoff. Even if central bankers wanted to be popular and maintain unemployment below the natural rate, the cost of seeing ever-increasing inflation would be too high. Policy-makers thus have to accept that, over the long run, unemployment will be close to its natural rate. Also, if they did decide to exploit this relationship, people would recognise it, take it into account, and then they probably wouldn t set π e t = π t 1 anymore, so the relationship would break down. Note, though, this tension between something that can be exploited in the short run but not in the long run. We will come back to this in the second part of these notes. Karl Whelan (UCD) The Phillips Curve Spring 2018 14 / 26

Long-Run Benefits of Low Inflation Because central banks now believe they can t really control the unemployment rate or the growth rate for long periods of time, they tend to focus a lot on what they can control: Inflation. In particular, most central banks in recent years have aimed for keeping inflation low and stable as their main goal. Ben Bernanke (see his speech, The Benefits of Price Stability ) argues that the mandated goals of price stability and maximum employment are almost entirely compatible. Low inflation helps to boost economic growth over the long run by 1 Saving the time and energy associated with dealing with high inflation: Having to reset prices regularly, re-write contracts to deal with inflation. 2 Facilitating long-run decision making, with consumers and businesses not having to worry about uncertainty about the future price level. 3 Enhancing the price signals and thus the functioning of the market system. But it is hard to argue on these grounds that, for example, there is a large welfare gain going from 4% inflation to 2% inflation. Karl Whelan (UCD) The Phillips Curve Spring 2018 15 / 26

Part II Credibility and Commitment Karl Whelan (UCD) The Phillips Curve Spring 2018 16 / 26

The Barro-Gordon Model of Central Bank Decision-Making We have described the expectations-augmented Phillips curve. We discussed how, in the short run when the public has a particular expectation of inflation, a central bank could choose to stimulate the economy and obtain lower unemployment at the cost of higher inflation. But in the longer run, the public s expectations of inflation would adapt and the central bank could only keep unemployment below the natural rate at the expense of ever-increasing inflation. This tension between what can be done in the short run and what should be done in the long run is important. It has a significant influence on how modern central banks behave. We will now discuss a simplified formal model that explains these issues. The model is discussed in full in UC Berkeley professor Brad DeLong s notes, linked to on the website. It is a simplified version of the models of Kydland and Prescott (JPE, 1977) and Barro and Gordon (JPE, 1983). It is most like the latter, so I will call it the Barro-Gordon model. Karl Whelan (UCD) The Phillips Curve Spring 2018 17 / 26

The Model s Assumptions Assume that inflation is determined by an expectations-augmented Phillips curve: π = π e β(u u ) The central bank acts so as to maximize its perception of the social welfare function defined by S = u ω 2 π2 1 Social welfare depends negatively on unemployment, and also on inflation. 2 The square of inflation is used because the costs of inflation increase more than proportionately as inflation rises, e.g. 4% inflation is annoying, 20% inflation is very harmful, 100% inflation highly destructive. The model simplifies the transmission mechanism of monetary policy substantially by assuming that the central bank s control over monetary policy allows it to simply choose the current inflation rate. Karl Whelan (UCD) The Phillips Curve Spring 2018 18 / 26

What Does the Central Bank Do? We assume that π e has been set by the time the central bank gets to make its decisions. What inflation rate will they pick? Let s simplify their problem by re-arranging the Phillips curve to describe unemployment as a function of inflation and two other parameters (π e and u ) that are fixed. u = u + πe π β So the central bank s problem reduced to picking the π that maximizes S = u πe β + π β ω 2 π2 Optimisation implies taking the derivative of S with respect to π, setting it equal to zero, and solving for the implied inflation rate: ds dπ = 1 β ωπ = 0 π = 1 ωβ Karl Whelan (UCD) The Phillips Curve Spring 2018 19 / 26

Expected Inflation and Social Welfare If the public understands how the central bank makes its decisions by solving this optimisation problem, then they will set their expectations to the correct value: π e = 1 ωβ Note that because π e = π, the expectations-augmented Phillips curve tells us that u = u. And social welfare is S = u ω 2 ( ) 2 1 = u 1 ωβ 2ωβ 2 Despite the central bank s best intentions, it turns out that it could perhaps do better than this. Karl Whelan (UCD) The Phillips Curve Spring 2018 20 / 26

Committing to an Inflation Rate Suppose that instead of picking the optimal inflation rate each period, the central bank could credibly commit to a particular inflation rate, π c, knowing that this rate would then be expected by the public. In this case, they would know that π e = π c and u = u and social welfare would be S = u ω 2 π2 c In this case, committing to zero inflation, π c = 0, provides the best outcome of S = u. Remember that, in the previous example, where the central bank did not committ and took the expectations as outside its control, social welfare was S = u 1 2ωβ which is lower. 2 The ability to pre-commit provides a better outcome than that obtained by picking an optimal inflation rate each period, taking expectations as given. Karl Whelan (UCD) The Phillips Curve Spring 2018 21 / 26

So Why Not Just Commit? Suppose the central bank convinced the public that it will set the inflation rate equal to zero. If it then decided to pick the optimal rate, contingent on taking the zero inflation expectations as given, it would again pick π = 1 ωβ. In this case, the inflation surprise would be engineered by having unemployment below the natural rate And social welfare turns out to be u = u 1 ωβ 2 S = u + 1 2ωβ 2 which is an even better outcome than obtained under commitment. So, having made the commitment, the central bank (and society) would be better off this period if it broke the commitment. This may make the public skeptical about the central bank s commitment. Karl Whelan (UCD) The Phillips Curve Spring 2018 22 / 26

Implications for Central Bank Institutional Design A better outcome is obtained if the central bank can commit to a low inflation, and this commitment be believed by the public. This suggests the following ways of achieving the best outcome: 1 Political Independence: A central bank that plans for the long-term (and does not worry about economic performance during election years) is more likely to stick to a low inflation commitment. So, independence from political control is an important way to reassure the public about the bank s credibility. 2 Conservative Central Bankers: If the central banker has a high ω really doesn t like inflation and the public believes this, the economy gets closer to the ideal low inflation outcome even without commitment. So the government may choose to appoint a central banker who is more inflation-averse than they are (Paul Volcker s appointment as Fed chair in 1979 might be an example of this happening.) 3 Consequence for Bad Inflation Outcomes: Introducing laws so that bad things happen to the central bankers when inflation is high is one way to make the public believe the they will commit to a low inflation rate. Karl Whelan (UCD) The Phillips Curve Spring 2018 23 / 26

Influence of this Research This research has had a considerable influence on the legal structure of central banks around the world: 1 Political Independence: There has been a substantial move around the world towards making central banks more independent. Close to home, the Bank of England was made independent in 1997 (previously the Chancellor of the Exchequer had set interest rates) and the ECB/Eurosystem is highly independent from political control. 2 Conservative Central Bankers: All around the world, central bankers talk much more now about the evils of inflation and the benefits of price stability. Mainly, this is because they believe this to be the case. But there is also a marketing element. Perhaps they can face a better macroeconomic tradeoff if the public believes the central bank s commitment to low inflation. 3 Consequence for Bad Inflation Outcomes: Many central banks now have legally imposed inflation targets and bad things happen when the inflation target is not met. For instance, the Governor of the Bank of England has to write a letter to the Chancellor explaining why the target was not met. Karl Whelan (UCD) The Phillips Curve Spring 2018 24 / 26

Problems with a Low Inflation Target Most central banks have adopted a target inflation rate of about 2 percent over the past two decades. And inflation is been kept in check in most advanced countries since the mid-1980s. More recently, there has been a debate about whether 2 percent is too low an inflation target. When inflation averages two percent, then relatively small shocks can bring the economy close to deflation. Perhaps with a higher inflation target, economies would be less likely to fall into liquidity trap conditions and central banks would have more room to cut interest rates before hitting lower bounds on policy rates and conducting unorthodox policies like QE. See the IMF paper called Rethinking Macroeconomic Policy for a discussion of the potential benefits of higher inflation targets. There are also some signs now that some policy makers are reconsidering the idea of focusing purely on inflation targeting. The New Zealand central bank, the first pure inflation targeter back in the 1990s, was given a changed mandate on March 26, 2018 to also take employment into account when making monetary policy decisions. Karl Whelan (UCD) The Phillips Curve Spring 2018 25 / 26

Recap: Key Points from Part 15 Things you need to understand from these notes: 1 The original Phillips curve and its demise. 2 The expectations-augmented Phillips curve. 3 The accelerationist Phillips curve. 4 Tradeoffs implied by the expectations-augmented Phillips curve. 5 Benefits from low inflation. 6 Problems caused by a low inflation target. 7 The assumptions of the Barro-Gordon model. 8 The model s predictions for outcomes with and without commitment. 9 Implications of Barro-Gordon for central bank institutional design. 10 The influence Barro-Gordon-style research has had on central banks. Karl Whelan (UCD) The Phillips Curve Spring 2018 26 / 26