What Explains the U-Shape Form of Women s Labor Force Participation Rate?

Similar documents
In Search of Market Access: Why the Doha Plan B for December 2011 is likely to fail Effective Market Access (Part I)

Empowering marginalized people: An Overview of BRAC s Development Experience and Lessons for Policy

Access to Infrastructure and Women s Time Allocation: Evidence and a Framework for Policy Analysis *

Women, Work, and the Economy: Macroeconomic Gains from Gender Equity

L Évolution récente des comportements de retraite au Canada

Women, Work, and the Economy: Macroeconomic Gains from Gender Equity

Macroprudential Regulation and Economic Growth in Low-Income Countries: Lessons from ESRC-DFID Project ES/L012022/1

Women and Men in the Informal Economy: A Statistical Brief

Deep Determinants. Sherif Khalifa. Sherif Khalifa () Deep Determinants 1 / 65

Measuring Financial Inclusion:

WOMEN AND FINANCIAL INCLUSION: Results from the Global Findex Asli Demirguc-Kunt, Leora Klapper, & Dorothe Singer

Toward Active Participation of Women as the Core of Growth Strategies. From the White Paper on Gender Equality Summary

Youth unemployment in Neighbourhood countries

INNOVATIONS FOR POVERTY ACTION S RAINWATER STORAGE DEVICE EVALUATION. for RELIEF INTERNATIONAL BASELINE SURVEY REPORT

Macroeconomic Policy and Employment Generation: Gender Dimensions

Oil contracts and government take : Issues for Senegal and developing countries

Who is Poorer? Poverty by Age in the Developing World

An integrated approach for the extension of social protection and the promotion of employment in Burkina Faso

Changing Population Age Structures and Sustainable Development

Female Labor Force Participation in Economic Development Process: The Case of Turkey

OPPORTUNITIES AND CHALLENGES OF GLOBAL ECONOMIC CHANGES

Married Women s Labor Supply Decision and Husband s Work Status: The Experience of Taiwan

2000 HOUSING AND POPULATION CENSUS

Response of the Equality and Human Rights Commission to Consultation:

Has structural economic vulnerability decreased in Least Developed Countries? Lessons drawn from retrospective indices

The paradox of tax exemptions of Official Development Assistance in developing countries

What is So Bad About Inequality? What Can Be Done to Reduce It? Todaro and Smith, Chapter 5 (11th edition)

Chapter 02. Labor Supply. Multiple Choice Questions. 1. Who is not counted in the U.S. labor force?

Migration Responses to Household Income Shocks: Evidence from Kyrgyzstan

Answers To Chapter 7. Review Questions

Personal Income Tax Cuts and the new Child Care Subsidy: Do They Address High Effective Marginal Tax Rates on Women s Work?

Her Majesty the Queen in Right of Canada (2017) All rights reserved

SECTION - 13: DEVELOPMENT INDICATORS FOR CIRDAP AND SAARC COUNTRIES

SECTION - 13: DEVELOPMENT INDICATORS FOR CIRDAP AND SAARC COUNTRIES

Facts and Features of the U.S. Labor Market

Business Cycles II: Theories

PUBLIC HEALTH CARE SPENDING AS A DETERMINANT OF HEALTH STATUS: A PANEL DATA ANALYSIS OF SSA AND MENA

Ghana: Promoting Growth, Reducing Poverty

Poverty After 50 in Canada: A Recent Snapshot

INEQUALITIES IN ACCESS TO PAID MATERNITY & PATERNITY LEAVE & FLEXIBLE WORK

GLOBAL EMPLOYMENT TRENDS 2014

Does Female Empowerment Promote Economic Development? Matthias Doepke (Northwestern) Michèle Tertilt (Mannheim)

TAX REFORM, DEMOGRAPHIC CHANGE AND RISING INEQUALITY

Scarcity at the end of the month

Married Women s Labor Force Participation and The Role of Human Capital Evidence from the United States

the working day: Understanding Work Across the Life Course introduction issue brief 21 may 2009 issue brief 21 may 2009

Recommendation for a COUNCIL RECOMMENDATION. on the 2017 National Reform Programme of Germany

We are now introducing a capital, an alternative asset besides fiat money, which enables individual to acquire consumption when old.

Saving for Old Age around the World: Evidence from the Global FINDEX

The impact of tax and benefit reforms by sex: some simple analysis

THE SOCIAL COST OF UNEMPLOYMENT (A SOCIAL WELFARE APPROACH)

Appendix 2 Basic Check List

All social security systems are income transfer

IOPS COUNTRY PROFILE: BELGIUM

Equity and Development: Through a Gender Lens

Alice Nabalamba, Ph.D. Statistics Department African Development Bank Group

Reasons for China's Changing Female Labor Force Participation Rate Xingxuan Xi

Profile of the Francophone Community in CHAMPLAIN 2010

HOW DOES WOMEN WORKING AFFECT SOCIAL SECURITY REPLACEMENT RATES?

The Changing Participation Rate of Canadians: New Evidence from a Panel of Demographic Groups

The Melbourne Institute Report on the 2004 Federal Budget Hielke Buddelmeyer, Peter Dawkins, and Guyonne Kalb

Labor Economics. Unit 8. Labor supply 2

Minimum Wages: Institutional aspects

Measuring Financial Inclusion: The Global Findex Dataset

Harnessing Demographic Dividend: The Future We Want

Labor Participation and Gender Inequality in Indonesia. Preliminary Draft DO NOT QUOTE

A Lost Decade for Equality, Development and Human Rights? Assessing austerity and its alternatives 10 years after the global financial crisis

Québec s Economy and Public Finances

Fiscal Space for Social Protection: Harmonization of Contributory and Non-Contributory programmes

FEPS(( STUDY( FEB"2017" Investments(in(green(and(social(sectors(can( create(2.8(million(jobs(in(the(eu( ( ( Lars(Andersen( Signe(Dahl( Thea(Nissen(

Budget Brief 2017: Social Protection

THE BENEFITS OF EXPANDING THE ROLE OF WOMEN AND YOUTH IN ECONOMIC ACTIVITIES

GLOBAL INVESTMENTS IN R&D

Employment and wages rising in Pakistan s garment sector

Topic 2.2c - Labour Force Participation. Professor H.J. Schuetze Economics 370

Social-economic Analysis on Gender Differences in Time Allocation. A Comparative Analysis of China and Canada. Sonja Linghui Shan

Subject: Methodology for country allocations: European Development Fund and Development Cooperation Instrument

What Firms Know. Mohammad Amin* World Bank. May 2008

QUESTIONNAIRE A. I. MULTIPLE CHOICE QUESTIONS (2 points each)

Does health capital have differential effects on economic growth?

Test Bank Labor Economics 7th Edition George Borjas

Fiscal Spending and Economic Growth: Some Stylized Facts *

The Great Recession: Economic and Social Impact in Eastern Europe and Central Asia

Estimating NTTA for Brazil from a single piece of housework time information

5 SAVING, CREDIT, AND FINANCIAL RESILIENCE

Chapter 6 Micro-determinants of Household Welfare, Social Welfare, and Inequality in Vietnam

FUTURE OF BUSINESS SURVEY

The Role of Fertility in Business Cycle Volatility

About 80% of the countries have GDP per capita below the average income per head

The social and budgetary impacts of recent social security reform in Belgium

International Comparison Program (ICP)

HUMAN GEOGRAPHY. By Brett Lucas

Gender, age, and economic activity

The Effect of NZ Superannuation eligibility age on the labour force participation of older people

Women s economic empowerment in the changing world of work:

How Oil Revenues Have Translated Into A Sustainable Improvement In Social Welfare In Algeria:

INCOME DISTRIBUTION AND INEQUALITY IN LUXEMBOURG AND THE NEIGHBOURING COUNTRIES,

Demographic Situation: Jamaica

The Gender Pay Gap in Belgium Report 2014

Fiscal Policy and Long-Term Growth

Transcription:

fondation pour les études et recherches sur le développement international What Explains the U-Shape Form of Women s Labor Force Participation Rate? Pierre-Richard Agénor Pierre-Richard Agénor is Professor of International Macroeconomics and Development Economics, at the University of Manchester. He is also codirector of the Centre for Growth and Business Cycle Research. He is Senior Fellow at Ferdi since 2011. LA FERDI EST UNE FONDATION RECONNUE D UTILITÉ PUBLIQUE. ELLE MET EN ŒUVRE AVEC L IDDRI L INITIATIVE POUR LE DÉVELOPPEMENT ET LA GOUVERNANCE MONDIALE (IDGM). ELLE COORDONNE LE LABEX IDGM+ QUI L ASSOCIE AU CERDI ET À L IDDRI. A well-established fact pertaining to women s labor supply is a U-shaped relationship between women s labor force participation and the level of development (as measured by income per capita), with participation being the highest in the poorest and richest countries. 1 / policy brief 49 April 2012 note brève 1. An early study documenting this U-shape pattern is Mammen and Paxson (2000). More recent studies include Tam (2011) and World Bank.

Figure 1 illustrates well this relationship. Labor participation rate, women age 15-64, 1960-1980 1 0,9 0,8 0,7 0,6 0,5 0,4 0,3 0,2 0,1 Log real GDP per capita 1960-1980 0 5,5 6 6,5 7 7,5 8 8,5 9 9,5 Policy brief n 49 Pierre-Richard Agénor 3 Figure 1. Women s Labor Supply and Economic Development This note reviews standard explanations for this pattern and discusses whether an alternative channel, based on the link between women s access to infrastructure and labor supply may not be an equally plausible explanation. Standard Explanations Various explanations have been offered for the existence of the U-shaped relationship depicted in Figure 1. A first explanation related to changes in access to technology and the availability of unearned incomes (be it income generated by her husband if she is married, or income from other family members). For very poor countries, female labor force participation is high, and women work mainly in labor-intensive farm or non-farm family enterprises possibly with less access than men to inputs relevant to farming activities and other productive assets such as labor-saving technologies. Women enter the labor force even at fairly low wages because unearned incomes are also low. Development initially moves women out of the labor force, partly because of the rise in men s wages and earnings (which therefore raise unearned income) and partly because of social barriers against women entering the paid labor force. However, as countries continue to develop, women s education levels rise, and women move back into the labor force as paid employees. Thus, at low levels of income, they work more than they would like. As income increases, female labor force participation decreases. Eventually, capital per capita is high enough to induce women to join the labor force again. As income rises, women move from work in family enterprises to work as paid employees. 1 A second explanation is based on changes, in the course of development of substitution and income effects associated with changes in wages. A woman s decision to enter the labor market depends in general on two key components. The first is the opportunity cost of her time; a higher wage induces a substitution effect that makes working away from home, and working for a longer period of time, more attractive. As long as this substitution effect dominates the 1. This pattern also has implications for the behavior of fertility over the course of development.

Policy brief n 49 Pierre-Richard Agénor 4 offsetting income effect, higher wages (which tend to promote investment in human capital and the acquisition of market-related transferable skills) would tend to increase female labor participation, as suggested by the empirical evidence. The second is income that is not earned directly, as referred to earlier. This exerts only income effects, therefore depressing female labor participation rates. Thus, the U-shaped pattern alluded to earlier could result from the fact that, at low and high levels of economic development, unearned income is low. Alternatively, the (negative) income effect may dominate the (positive) substitution effect initially, with a reversal at higher levels of development. Indeed, as income increases initially, and with female educational levels relatively low, the demand for children may also increase, causing female participation rates to decrease due to a negative income effect. Over time, as income continues to increase, and with opportunities for women to invest in education and engage in paid work improving, there may be a substitution of quality for quantity in the desired number of children, leading to a stronger substitution effect. A third explanation is that the U-shaped relationship depicted in Figure 1 is the result of cultural, religious, and social norms, which restrict employment opportunities for women. Indeed, at low levels of income women (who often do not hold any land) may have no choice but to engage in family farm activities or agriculture more generally. If the structure of production changes over time, with a shift first from agriculture to male-labor intensive manufacturing (associated with the expansion of markets and the creation of new technologies), and subsequently a change in the composition of manufacturing toward female-labor intensive industries (such as textiles or light electronics), coupled with a shift toward services and improved opportunities for women to educate themselves), a U-shaped relationship may emerge. The fact that cultural and religious factors may be important in determining women s labor force participation rate is well illustrated by comparing rates for the Middle East and North Africa with other developing regions (see Table 1). An Alternative Explanation? Another possible explanation for the excistence of a U-shaped relationship between women s labor force participation rate and economic development is that it may result from a nonlinear relationship between time allocated to market work and access to infrastructure. In the early stages of economic development, public capital is typically insufficient, constraining private activities and opportunities for market work for both men and women (see Agénor (2012) and Agénor and Canuto (2012)). For instance, the lack of roads may prevent farmers from investing in transportation equipment. In addition, women must allocate a large fraction of their time to home production. Thus, time devoted to market work is limited and women participate mostly in family farm activities. As access to public capital improves, and (complementary) private capital expands possibly as a result of a switch to more efficient production techniques, because public capital raises the rate of return on physical capital labor productivity and thus labor demand increase, while time allocated to farm activities and home production falls. But initially women may allocate most of the resulting time savings to their children s health and their own health care (as shown in Agénor and Agénor (2009), and Agénor et al. (2009)) or possibly also to the acquisition of skills. The former effect would occur if, initially, the preference for children s health is very high. As a result, the effective female labor force participation rate (including both farm and off-farm activities) may fall. Over time, as access to public capital continues to improve, women may choose to allocate more of their time savings to market work if their preferences toward children

Table 1. Labor Force Participation Rates by Sex, World and Regions, 2000-2011 (in percent) Males 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011* World 78.6 78.4 78.2 78.0 78.0 78.0 77.8 77.6 77.5 77.3 77.1 77.1 Developed Economies and European Union Central and South-Eastern Europe (non-eu) and CIS 70.2 69.8 69.4 69.1 69.0 69.0 69.1 69.1 69.0 68.4 68.0 67.9 69.4 68.6 68.1 67.5 67.8 68.2 68.3 68.9 69.5 69.7 70.0 70.3 East Asia 82.1 81.7 81.5 81.2 80.9 80.7 80.5 80.3 80.0 79.8 79.6 79.6 South-East Asia and the Pacific 82.8 83.1 82.8 83.1 83.2 82.7 82.4 82.1 81.9 81.8 81.9 81.8 South Asia 83.3 83.3 83.3 83.3 83.3 83.4 83.1 82.6 82.2 81.7 81.4 81.3 Latin America and the Caribbean 80.7 80.5 80.3 80.0 80.2 80.2 80.1 79.9 80.0 79.7 79.8 79.7 Middle East 74.0 73.8 73.7 73.8 73.8 74.0 73.6 73.5 72.8 73.1 73.6 74.0 North Africa 74.9 74.2 74.1 74.5 75.0 75.2 74.1 74.1 74.1 74.1 74.1 74.1 Sub-Saharan Africa 77.0 76.7 76.5 76.2 75.9 75.9 75.9 76.0 76.2 76.1 76.1 76.2 Females 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011* World 52.0 52.0 52.1 52.1 52.2 52.4 52.2 52.0 51.7 51.4 51.2 51.1 Developed Economies and European Union Central and South-Eastern Europe (non-eu) and CIS 51.8 51.7 51.7 51.9 52.0 52.2 52.5 52.7 53.0 53.0 53.0 53.1 49.4 49.0 49.4 48.6 48.3 48.5 48.8 49.1 49.2 49.6 49.7 49.9 East Asia 69.7 69.4 69.1 68.7 68.3 68.0 67.8 67.7 67.2 67.0 66.9 66.7 South-East Asia and the Pacific 58.5 58.8 58.4 58.4 58.4 58.5 58.3 58.5 58.7 58.5 58.6 58.7 South Asia 35.0 35.4 35.8 36.3 36.8 37.4 36.3 35.1 33.9 32.8 31.7 31.8 Latin America and the Caribbean 48.1 48.7 49.6 49.8 50.8 51.3 51.5 51.8 52.1 52.6 53.2 53.5 Middle East 16.3 16.7 17.2 17.8 18.4 19.0 18.7 18.5 17.7 17.8 18.1 18.4 North Africa 22.1 21.7 21.2 21.9 22.4 22.6 22.7 23.6 23.7 23.8 24.0 24.2 Sub-Saharan Africa 62.7 63.1 63.5 63.8 64.0 64.1 64.2 64.2 64.4 64.4 64.4 64.5 Source: ILO, Global Employment Trends (January 2012, p. 96). Policy brief n 49 Pierre-Richard Agénor 5 diminish and their preference for current and future consumption of market goods increases. Thus, despite the fact that the marginal productivity effect of public capital on labor diminishes over time, female labor force participation rates may increase again gradually. As a result, the overall female labor participation rate (again, including both farm and off-farm activities) may exhibit the U-shape pattern documented earlier with participation in market work alone taking more the form of a J-shaped or simply monotonic curve, the latter possibly concave, rather than convex, in nature. Testing this relationship may be difficult for a number of other reasons. First, at low levels of income, one constraint on women s time allocation is the lack of availability of child care. If so, even when access to infrastructure improves, it may not lead to increased participation rates due to social norms. Second, time allocated to market work is lumpy, rather than continuous. For instance, a woman may not be able to work an extra 30 minutes a week because of improved access to water. Thus, unless there is a very large reduction in time allocated to household chores, women may well allocate the time savings to activities other than market work. In other words, there is a nonlinearity (or discon-

Policy brief n 49 Pierre-Richard Agénor 6 tinuity) associated with time savings, which could be difficult to detect in the data. At the same time, however, even though there is a discontinuity at the individual level, it may not persist at the aggregate level. A preliminary study by Baah (2011) provides some encouraging results for this alternative explanation. Using cross-section data for a large group of developed and developing countries, she tested whether the U-shape relationship illustrated in Figure 1 exists with respect to access to infrastructure. Her results suggest that the hypothesized U-shape relationship does indeed exist with respect to energy and transport (proxied in the first case by kwh per capita, and in the second the density of the road networks, itself measured in terms of km per capita), with each variable having an independent effect on women s labor participation rates, above and beyond the effect of these variables on the level of economic development. Further studies along these lines, based perhaps on more comprehensive panel datasets, would be useful to better understand the relationship between women s labor supply, infrastructure, and the process of economic development. References Agénor, Pierre-Richard, Public Capital, Growth and Welfare, forthcoming, Princeton University Press (Princeton, New Jersey: 2012). Agénor, Pierre-Richard, and Madina Agénor, Infrastructure, Women s Time Allocation, and Economic Development, Working Paper No. 116, Centre for Growth and Business Cycle Research, University of Manchester (March 2009). Agénor, Pierre-Richard, Otaviano Canuto, Access to Infrastructure and Women s Time Allocation: Evidence and a Framework for Policy Analysis, Discussion Paper No. -, FERDI (April 2012). Agénor, Pierre-Richard, Otaviano Canuto, and Luiz Pereira da Silva, On Gender and Growth: The Role of Intergenerational Health Externalities and Women s Occupational Constraints, unpublished, University of Manchester (March 2012). Baah, Belinda L., Women s Labour Supply and Economic Growth: The Effects of Infrastructure on Female Labour Participation Rates, unpublished, University of Manchester (September 2011). Mammen, Kristin, and Christina Paxson, Women s Work and Economic Development, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14 (March 2000), 141-64. Tam, Henry, U-Shaped Female Labor Participation with Economic Development: Some Panel Data Evidence, Economics Letters, 110 (February 2011), 140-42. World Bank, Gender Equality and Development, World Development Report 2012 (Washington DC: 2011).

Créée en 2003, la Fondation pour les études et recherches sur le développement international vise à favoriser la compréhension du développement économique international et des politiques qui l influencent. Contact www.ferdi.fr contact@ferdi.fr +33 (0)4 73 17 75 30 policy brief 49 April 2012 note brève