Part 1: q Theory and Irreversible Investment

Similar documents
Part 2: Monopoly and Oligopoly Investment

13.3 A Stochastic Production Planning Model

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Singular Stochastic Control Models for Optimal Dynamic Withdrawal Policies in Variable Annuities

1 Dynamic programming

Capacity Expansion Games with Application to Competition in Power May 19, Generation 2017 Investmen 1 / 24

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014

Stock Loan Valuation Under Brownian-Motion Based and Markov Chain Stock Models

Homework # 8 - [Due on Wednesday November 1st, 2017]

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

Notes on Differential Rents and the Distribution of Earnings

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Optimal Order Placement

The Neoclassical Growth Model

BACHELIER FINANCE SOCIETY. 4 th World Congress Tokyo, Investments and forward utilities. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

Homework 3: Asset Pricing

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Economic Growth: Lectures 2 and 3 The Solow Growth Model

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2009

Resolution of a Financial Puzzle

TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES. Lucas Island Model

14.05 Lecture Notes. Endogenous Growth

ECON 815. A Basic New Keynesian Model II

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation. Distributive politics

Rohini Kumar. Statistics and Applied Probability, UCSB (Joint work with J. Feng and J.-P. Fouque)

Credit Crises, Precautionary Savings and the Liquidity Trap October (R&R Quarterly 31, 2016Journal 1 / of19

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES

TAKE-HOME EXAM POINTS)

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis

Game Theory Fall 2003

FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008

Linear Capital Taxation and Tax Smoothing

ON MAXIMIZING DIVIDENDS WITH INVESTMENT AND REINSURANCE

Irreversible Investment in Oligopoly

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017

Luca Taschini. 6th Bachelier World Congress Toronto, June 25, 2010

THE OPTIMAL ASSET ALLOCATION PROBLEMFOR AN INVESTOR THROUGH UTILITY MAXIMIZATION

Exercises in Growth Theory and Empirics

MARGIN CALL STOCK LOANS

Portfolio Management and Optimal Execution via Convex Optimization

The Response of Catastrophe Insurance Markets to Extreme Events: A Real Option Approach

Lecture 7: Bayesian approach to MAB - Gittins index

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. September 2015

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

A Controlled Optimal Stochastic Production Planning Model

License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation.

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Microfoundations of DSGE Models: III Lecture

Economic Growth: Lectures 1 (second half), 2 and 3 The Solow Growth Model

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

Valuing volatility and variance swaps for a non-gaussian Ornstein-Uhlenbeck stochastic volatility model

Eco504 Spring 2010 C. Sims MID-TERM EXAM. (1) (45 minutes) Consider a model in which a representative agent has the objective. B t 1.

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

What do frictions mean for Q-theory?

Problem set Fall 2012.

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO CONTROL WITH TRADING STRATEGIES OF FINITE

American Foreign Exchange Options and some Continuity Estimates of the Optimal Exercise Boundary with respect to Volatility

Question 1 Consider an economy populated by a continuum of measure one of consumers whose preferences are defined by the utility function:

Economics Honors Exam 2008 Solutions Question 1

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Electricity Capacity Expansion in a Cournot Duopoly

Asymmetric Information: Walrasian Equilibria, and Rational Expectations Equilibria

Online Appendix to Financing Asset Sales and Business Cycles

Homework 2: Dynamic Moral Hazard

Optimal investments under dynamic performance critria. Lecture IV

Pricing in markets modeled by general processes with independent increments

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy. Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University)

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

Equity correlations implied by index options: estimation and model uncertainty analysis

Econ 101A Final Exam We May 9, 2012.

1 Maximizing profits when marginal costs are increasing

Investment, Capacity Choice and Outsourcing under Uncertainty

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

Chapter II: Labour Market Policy

CEREC, Facultés universitaires Saint Louis. Abstract

Topic 6. Introducing money

Course Handouts - Introduction ECON 8704 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS. Jan Werner. University of Minnesota

Chapter 6. Endogenous Growth I: AK, H, and G

Utility Indifference Pricing and Dynamic Programming Algorithm

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Lecture 2: The Neoclassical Growth Model

Advanced Macro and Money (WS09/10) Problem Set 4

Liquidity and Risk Management

ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Characterization of the Optimum

Consumption and Asset Pricing

Estimating Market Power in Differentiated Product Markets

Social Common Capital and Sustainable Development. H. Uzawa. Social Common Capital Research, Tokyo, Japan. (IPD Climate Change Manchester Meeting)

Transcription:

Part 1: q Theory and Irreversible Investment Goal: Endogenize firm characteristics and risk. Value/growth Size Leverage New issues,... This lecture: q theory of investment Irreversible investment and real options Value and risk under perfect competition Notation r = interest rate δ = depreciation rate K t = capital stock k = initial capital stock I t = investment rate θ(i, k) = investment cost B = BM under risk-neutral probability dx = µ(x) dt + σ(x) db π(x, k) = operating cash flow J(x, k) = market value of firm

Value of Firm J(k, x) = sup I E e rt [π(x t, K t ) θ(i t, K t )] dt subject to dk = I dt δk dt, K = k, X = x. Examples of investment cost θ Costless adjustment: θ(i, k) = ai for constant a. Quadratic (and linearly homogeneous): θ(i, k) = ai + bi 2 /k. Purchase price of capital different from resale price: θ(i, k) = ai + bi. Irreversible investment (zero resale price): θ(i, k) = ai +. Irreversible investment with fixed costs: θ(i, k) = ai + + f 1 {i>o}.

Operating Cash Flow Usual model: Assume there is a production function y = k α l β for α, β > with α + β 1. Labor is hired in a perfectly competitive market at wage rate w. The industry demand curve has constant elasticity: p = Xy 1/γ, where X is a GBM. Different versions are obtained from Constant (α + β = 1) or decreasing (α + β < 1) returns to scale. Perfect competition, monopoly, or Cournot oligopoly. We end up with something like π(x, k) = xk λ. Linearity/Concavity Operating cash flow is linear in capital (λ = 1) if there are constant returns to scale and perfect competition. Operating cash flow is strictly concave in capital (λ < 1) otherwise.

Basic q Theory Assume θ is linearly homogeneous, so θ(i, k) = kφ(i/k). If φ is differentiable and strictly convex, then the optimal investment-to-capital ratio is a function of the marginal value of capital (marginal q). In the quadratic case, the optimal investment-to-capital ratio is an affine function of the marginal value of capital. If π is linear in k, then the marginal value of capital equals the average value of capital (marginal q equals average q). In other words, J k (x, k) = J(x, k)/k. Proof HJB Equation: = sup [π(k, x) θ(i, k) rj(k, x) + J x µ + J k (i δk) + 12 ] J xxσ 2 i. First-order condition: θ i = J k φ (i/k) = J k. Strict convexity implies φ is strictly decreasing, hence invertible, so i/k = (φ ) 1 (J k ). If φ(y) = ay + by 2, then φ (i/k) = J k i/k = (J k a)/(2b). If π(k, x) = f (x)k, guess J(k, x) = g(x)k and verify. The HJB equation simplifies to = sup [f (x) φ(i/k) rg(x) + µg (x) + g(x)(i/k δ) + 12 ] g (x)σ 2. i/k This equation is independent of k. Solve it for g (given boundary conditions).

Nonlinear π Suppose π(x, k) = xk λ with λ < 1. Then average q is larger than marginal q. Suppose π(x, k) = xk c for a constant c. Then average q is less than marginal q. This is called operating leverage. Irreversible Investment Assume θ(i, k) = i + and π is monotone in k. Let I now denote cumulative investment instead of the investment rate. Then J(x, k) = sup I E e rt [π(k t, X t ) dt di t ] subject to dk = di δk dt, K = k, X = x, and subject to I being an increasing process.

Zero Depreciation. δ = K t = k + I t. Some references in which π depends directly on the control process: Karatzas, I. and S. E. Shreve, 1984, Connections between Optimal Stopping and Singular Stochastic Control I. Monotone Follower problems, SIAM J. Contr. Opt. 6, 856 877. Scheinkman, J. A. and T. Zariphopoulou, 21, Optimal Environmental Management in the Presence of Irreversibilities, J. Econ. Theory 96, 18 27. Bank, P., 25, Optimal Control under a Dynamic Fuel Constraint, SIAM J. Contr. Opt. 44, 1529 1541. Back, K. and D. Paulsen, 29, Open-Loop Equilibria and Perfect Competition in Option Exercise Games, Rev. Fin. Stud. 22, 4531 4552. Aguerrevere, F., 29, Real Options, Product Market Competition, and Asset Returns, J. Fin. 64, 957 983. Steg, J.-H., 212, Irreversible Investment in Oligopoly, Finance Stoch. 16, 27 224. Assets in Place and Growth Options Write π = π k and π(x, k) = π(x, k ) + k k π (X t, l) dl, so the objective function is E e rt π(x t, k ) dt + E e rt [ Kt k π (X t, k) dk dt di t ]. The first term is the value of assets in place. The maximized value of the second term is the value of growth options.

First-Order Condition Alternative to dynamic programming when δ =. See Bank and Riedel (AAP, 21), Bank (SIAM J. Contr. Opt., 25), Steg(FS, 212). Given K, define a gradient D by D τ = E τ e rt π (X t, K t ) dt e rτ for all stopping times τ. τ Given some technical conditions, a necessary and sufficient condition for K to be optimal is that D and D t dk t =. Real Options Rather than choosing the optimal capital stock K t at each date t, we can equivalently choose the optimal date t at which to invest the unit of capital k for each k k. In this formulation, the value of growth options is the integral of a continuum of call option values, indexed by the level k k of the capital stock. The equivalence is based on changing the order of integration and using τ k = inf{t K t > k}, which is the right-continuous inverse of the path t K t. From the optimal investment times τ k, we can recover the optimal capital stock process as K t = inf{k τ k > t}.

Real Options cont. The underlying asset for option k has price [ S(x, k) = E e r(u t) π (X u, k) du t ] X t = x. The benefit of investment is that you earn the marginal profit π in perpetuity after investment, which has value S(X t, k) at date t. The options are perpetual. The strikes equal 1 (the price of capital). The value of growth options is k sup τ k E [ e rτ k {S(X τk, k) 1} ] dk. Value Matching and Optimal Capital Define the value of option k: V (x, k) = sup τ E [ e rτ {S(X τ, k) 1} X = x ]. When it is optimal to invest, we must have value matching: V (X t, k) = S(X t, k) 1. In other words, the optimal exercise boundary is {(k, x) V (X t, k) = S(X t, k) 1}. Given x, the largest capital stock such that it would be optimal to invest is κ(x) def = sup {k V (x, k) = S(x, k) 1}. Hysteresis: The optimal capital stock process is K t = k sup κ(x s ). s t

Real Options and q Theory The value-matching condition can be expressed in the q language. The marginal value of investment (marginal q) is S(y, x) V (y, x). Investing earns the marginal cash flow π in perpetuity but extinguishes the option. Hence, the marginal value of investing is S V. In fact, a direct calculation shows that J k (x, k) = S(x, k) V (x, k). So, value matching can be expressed as: invest when marginal q equals 1. Perfect Competition Assume constant returns to scale and perfect competition, so π(x, y, k) = h(x, y)k for some h, where y denotes industry capital (which is exogenous from the point of view of any firm). The equilibrium condition for perfect competition is that investment occurs as soon as any investment option reaches the money (no barriers to entry). Because the options are never strictly in the money, growth options have zero value. The value of any firm is the value of its assets in place: [ ] J(x, y, k) = ke e rt def f (X t, Y t ) dt X t = x, Y t = y = kq(x, y).

Risk The return on the firm is its dividend yield plus capital gain: π dt dk t + dj J Because J = Kq and K is continuous with finite variation, dj J = dk K + dq q. Because the firm only invests when q = 1 J = K, we have dk /K = dk /J, so the return is π dt J + dq q. If investment were perfectly reversible, industry capital would adjust to maintain q = 1, and we would have π/j = r. With irreversibility, fluctuations in q (the market-to-book ratio) add risk. Example The production function is f (k) = k. The industry output price is P t = X t Y 1/γ t, where X is a GBM with coefficients µ and σ, where µ < r. Let β denote the positive root (guaranteed to be larger than one) of the quadratic equation 1 2 σ2 β 2 + (µ 12 ) σ2 β = r.. The investment options reach the money when P t reaches ( ) pc def β = (r µ). β 1 In equilibrium, P is a GBM reflected at p c.

Example cont. Marginal q = Average q = β P t β 1 pc 1 ( ) β Pt β 1 pc. The stochastic part of dq/q is ( 1 (Pt /pc) β 1 ) β (P t /pc) β 1 βσ db. Note that risk decreases as P t increases towards p c, vanishing at P t = p c. ARTICLE IN PRESS 422 L. Kogan / Journal of Financial Economics 73 (24) 411 431.25.2 Conditional volatility, σ R.15.1.5.2.3.4.5.6.7.8.9 1 1.1 Tobin's q Fig. 1. Conditional volatility of stock returns. s R denotes the conditional volatility of stock returns of firms in the second sector. The argument is the average q of firms in the second sector, defined as the ratio of their market value to the replacement cost of their capital. The subjective time preference rate is r ¼ :5; the expected return and the volatility of the production technology of the first sector are given by a ¼ :7 and s ¼ :17; respectively, and the depreciation rate of capital in the second sector is d ¼ :5: The preference parameter b is assumed to be small. The three lines correspond to the preference parameter g of 1 2 (dash), 1 (solid), and 3 2 (dash-dot). Kogan, L., 24, Asset Prices and Real Investment, JFE 73, 411 431. The three lines correspond to different levels of risk aversion of the representative investor.

Explanation The risk comes from the dependence of q on X. When X changes, the demand for capital changes. Suppose the demand for capital increases. If the supply of capital were perfectly elastic, then the quantity supplied would increase with no change in q. If the supply of capital were perfectly inelastic, then q would increase with no change in the quantity supplied. Perfectly reversible investment implies a perfectly elastic supply of capital. Irreversibility implies that supply is elastic only at q = 1. Bounded Investment Rate A simple example of convex adjustment costs is if i, θ(i, k) = i if i i max, otherwise. This is equivalent to the constraint di t /dt i max. At the optimum, the firm will invest at the maximum rate whenever q > 1.

ARTICLE IN PRESS L. Kogan / Journal of Financial Economics 73 (24) 411 431 425.25.2 Conditional volatility, σ R.15.1.5.5 1 1.5 Tobin's q Fig. 4. Conditional volatility of stock returns, bounded investment rate. s R denotes the conditional volatility of stock returns of firms in the second sector. The argument is the average q of firms in the second sector, defined as the ratio of their market value to the replacement cost of their capital. The subjective time preference rate is r ¼ :5; the expected return and the volatility of the production technology of the first sector are given by a ¼ :7 and s ¼ :17; respectively, and the depreciation rate of capital in the second sector is d ¼ :5: The maximum investment rate is i max ¼ :2: The preference parameter b is assumed to be small. The three lines correspond to three values of the risk-aversion parameter g: 1 2 (dash), 1 (solid), and 3 2 (dash-dot). Kogan, L., 24, Asset Prices and Real Investment, JFE 73, 411 431. We expect similar figures for more general convex adjustment costs: risks are high when the adjustment costs are particularly constraining. now q can exceed one and volatility is no longer a monotonic function of q: Qualitatively, the state space can be partitioned into the followingthree regions: First region (Low values of q: q51): Firms do not invest and irreversibility prevents them from disinvesting. Thus, the elasticity of supply is relatively low and stock returns are relatively volatile. Second region (Intermediate values of q: qc1): Firms are either about to invest, followingan increase in q; or are already investingat the maximum possible rate and are about to stop, followinga decline in q: The elasticity of supply is relatively high and, as a result, q is not sensitive to shocks and does not contribute much to stock returns. Third region (High values of q: qb1): The industry is expanding. Firms are investingat the maximum possible rate and are likely to continue investingduringan extended period of time. Demand shocks do not immediately change the rate of entry into the industry, the elasticity of supply is low, and demand shocks are offset mostly by changes in the output price. Thus, q is relatively volatile and so are stock returns. When the rate of investment is allowed to be very high, q rarely exceeds one. Thus, the third regime can be observed only infrequently, during periods of active growth in the industry. In the extreme case of instantaneous adjustment, as in the basic