Characteristic time scales of tick quotes on foreign currency markets: an empirical study and agent-based model

Similar documents
Non-linear logit models for high frequency currency exchange data

Graduate School of Information Sciences, Tohoku University Aoba-ku, Sendai , Japan

Dynamics of the return distribution in the Korean financial market arxiv:physics/ v3 [physics.soc-ph] 16 Nov 2005

arxiv:cond-mat/ v1 [cond-mat.stat-mech] 7 Apr 2003

Agents Play Mix-game

The rst 20 min in the Hong Kong stock market

Market dynamics and stock price volatility

EMH vs. Phenomenological models. Enrico Scalas (DISTA East-Piedmont University)

Execution and Cancellation Lifetimes in Foreign Currency Market

Power law in market capitalization Title and Shanghai bubble periods. Mizuno, Takayuki; Ohnishi, Takaaki; Author(s) Tsutomu

The distribution and scaling of fluctuations for Hang Seng index in Hong Kong stock market

arxiv:cond-mat/ v1 [cond-mat.stat-mech] 22 Nov 2000 Universal Structure of the Personal Income Distribution Wataru Souma

Power laws in market capitalization during the Dot-com and Shanghai bubble periods

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.gn] 27 Sep 2007

COMPARISON OF GAIN LOSS ASYMMETRY BEHAVIOR FOR STOCKS AND INDEXES

Modeling the extremes of temperature time series. Debbie J. Dupuis Department of Decision Sciences HEC Montréal

Quantitative relations between risk, return and firm size

STATISTICAL ANALYSIS OF HIGH FREQUENCY FINANCIAL TIME SERIES: INDIVIDUAL AND COLLECTIVE STOCK DYNAMICS

Bubbles in a minority game setting with real financial data.

MODELING FINANCIAL MARKETS WITH HETEROGENEOUS INTERACTING AGENTS VIRAL DESAI

This article appeared in a journal published by Elsevier. The attached copy is furnished to the author for internal non-commercial research and

arxiv:cond-mat/ v3 [cond-mat.stat-mech] 1 Mar 2002

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.st] 3 Aug 2007

Minority games with score-dependent and agent-dependent payoffs

Expectations and market microstructure when liquidity is lost

Dynamical Volatilities for Yen-Dollar Exchange Rates

arxiv:cond-mat/ v1 [cond-mat.stat-mech] 6 Jan 2004

Power-Law Networks in the Stock Market: Stability and Dynamics

An Introduction to Market Microstructure Invariance

A statistical analysis of product prices in online markets

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2012, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

PRICE BEHAVIOR AND HURST EXPONENTS OF TICK-BY-TICK INTERBANK FOREIGN EXCHANGE RATES. John Moody and Lizhong Wu

HSC Research Report. Hurst analysis of electricity price dynamics HSC/00/01. Rafał Weron* Beata Przybyłowicz*

arxiv:cond-mat/ v1 [cond-mat.stat-mech] 1 Aug 2003

arxiv:cond-mat/ v1 [cond-mat.stat-mech] 28 Feb 2001

S9/ex Minor Option K HANDOUT 1 OF 7 Financial Physics

Emergence of Key Currency by Interaction among International and Domestic Markets

The statistical properties of the fluctuations of STOCK VOLATILITY IN THE PERIODS OF BOOMS AND STAGNATIONS TAISEI KAIZOJI*

arxiv:physics/ v1 [physics.soc-ph] 11 Nov 2005

How to determine what thresholds to avoid in Directional Changes

Idiosyncratic risk and the dynamics of aggregate consumption: a likelihood-based perspective

arxiv:cs/ v2 [cs.it] 2 Aug 2006

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2011, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam.

Group Polarization, Transition Points and Coherent Market Model

Application of multi-agent games to the prediction of financial time-series

Intraday Volatility Forecast in Australian Equity Market

Supplementary Appendix for Liquidity, Volume, and Price Behavior: The Impact of Order vs. Quote Based Trading not for publication

Statistical properties of agent-based models in markets with continuous double auction mechanism

THE WORKING OF CIRCUIT BREAKERS WITHIN PERCOLATION MODELS FOR FINANCIAL MARKETS

arxiv:cond-mat/ v1 [cond-mat.stat-mech] 23 Jan 2004

arxiv:physics/ v2 11 Jan 2007

Corporate Investment and Portfolio Returns in Japan: A Markov Switching Approach

Bin Size Independence in Intra-day Seasonalities for Relative Prices

Intraday arbitrage opportunities of basis trading in current futures markets: an application of. the threshold autoregressive model.

Semi-Markov model for market microstructure and HFT

Effects of Exchange Rate Change on Domestic Price Level: an Empirical Analysis

Econophysics on Interactions of Markets

Lecture 9: Markov and Regime

Multivariable Modeling on Complex Behavior of a Foreign Exchange Market

Agent based modeling of financial markets

Simple Formulas to Option Pricing and Hedging in the Black-Scholes Model

Estimating Bivariate GARCH-Jump Model Based on High Frequency Data : the case of revaluation of Chinese Yuan in July 2005

Power Laws and Market Crashes Empirical Laws on Bursting Bubbles

arxiv:physics/ v1 [physics.soc-ph] 19 Aug 2006

Econophysics V: Credit Risk

Power-Law and Log-Normal Distributions in Firm Size Displacement Data

Sharpe Ratio over investment Horizon

Lecture 8: Markov and Regime

High-Frequency Data Analysis and Market Microstructure [Tsay (2005), chapter 5]

arxiv:physics/ v1 [physics.soc-ph] 29 May 2006

PERCOLATION MODEL OF FINANCIAL MARKET

The informational efficiency of the Romanian stock market: evidence from fractal analysis

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.gn] 18 Jul 2015

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.gn] 3 Aug 2013

ESTIMATION OF UTILITY FUNCTIONS: MARKET VS. REPRESENTATIVE AGENT THEORY

A Directional-Change Events Approach for Studying Financial Time Series

MARKET DEPTH AND PRICE DYNAMICS: A NOTE

Quantifying fluctuations in market liquidity: Analysis of the bid-ask spread

Exam in TFY4275/FY8907 CLASSICAL TRANSPORT THEORY Feb 14, 2014

Prerequisites for modeling price and return data series for the Bucharest Stock Exchange

Richard Olsen The democratization of the foreign exchange market

arxiv: v2 [physics.soc-ph] 4 Jul 2010

Portfolio Management and Optimal Execution via Convex Optimization

Empirical Analysis of the US Swap Curve Gough, O., Juneja, J.A., Nowman, K.B. and Van Dellen, S.

Factors in Implied Volatility Skew in Corn Futures Options

Electrodynamical model of quasi-efficient financial market

Price Discovery in Agent-Based Computational Modeling of Artificial Stock Markets

Analysis of Realized Volatility for Nikkei Stock Average on the Tokyo Stock Exchange

Optimal Dynamic Asset Allocation: A Stochastic Invariance Approach

Market Microstructure Invariants

Analysis of Volatility Spillover Effects. Using Trivariate GARCH Model

Measuring and explaining liquidity on an electronic limit order book: evidence from Reuters D

Origins of scaling in FX markets

arxiv:cond-mat/ v2 [cond-mat.stat-mech] 3 Jun 2003

arxiv:cond-mat/ v3 [cond-mat.stat-mech] 11 May 1998

Stochastic Cellular Automata Model for Stock Market Dynamics arxiv:cond-mat/ v2 [cond-mat.dis-nn] 24 Nov Abstract

Multifractal Detrended Cross-Correlation Analysis of. Agricultural Futures Markets

Two-Period-Ahead Forecasting For Investment Management In The Foreign Exchange

Optimal Investment for Worst-Case Crash Scenarios

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics

Transcription:

arxiv:physics/05263v2 [physics.data-an] 9 Jun 2006 Characteristic time scales of tick quotes on foreign currency markets: an empirical study and agent-based model Aki-Hiro Sato Department of Applied Mathematics and Physics, Graduate School of Informatics, Kyoto University, Kyoto 606-850, Japan December 7, 207 Abstract Power spectrum densities for the number of tick quotes per minute (market activity) on three currency markets (USD/JPY, EUR/USD, and JPY/EUR) for periods from January 999 to December 2000 are analyzed. We find some peaks on the power spectrum densities at a few minutes. We develop the double-threshold agent model and confirm that stochastic resonance occurs for the market activity of this model. We propose a hypothesis that the periodicities found on the power spectrum densities can be observed due to stochastic resonance. tick quotes, foreign currency market,, double-threshold agent model, stochastic resonance PACS 89.65.Gh, 87.5.Ya, 02.50.-r Introduction In the past few years there has been increasing interest in the investigation of financial markets as complex systems in statistical mechanics. The empirical analysis of the high frequency financial data reveals nonstationary statistics

of market fluctuations and several mathematical models of markets based on the concept of the nonequilibrium phenomena have been proposed [, 2]. Recently Mizuno et al. investigate high frequency data of the USD/JPY exchange market and conclude that dealers perception and decision are mainly based on the latest 2 minutes data [3]. This result means that there are feedback loops of information in the foreign currency market. As microscopic models of financial markets some agent models are proposed [4, 5, 6, 7]. Specifically Ising-like models are familiar to statistical physicists and have been examined in the context of econophysics. The analogy to the paramagnetic-ferromagnetic transition is used to explain crashes and bubbles. Krawiecki et al. consider the effect of a weak external force acting on the agents in the Ising model of the financial market and conclude that apparently weak stimuli from outside can have potentially effect on financial market due to stochastic resonance [8]. This conclusion indicates that it is possible to observe the effect ofthe external stimuli fromthe market fluctuations. Motivated by their conclusion we investigate high-frequency financial data and find a potential evidence that stochastic resonance occurs in financial markets. In this article the results of data analysis are reported and the agent-based model is proposed in order to explain this phenomenon. 2 Analysis We analyze tick quotes on three foreign currency markets(usd/jpy, EUR/USD, and JPY/EUR) for periods from January 999 to December 2000 [9]. This database contains time stamps, prices, and identifiers of either ask or bid. Since generally market participants (dealers) must indicate both ask and bid prices in foreign currency markets the nearly same number of ask and bid offering are recorded in the database. Here we focus on the ask offering and regard the number of ask quotes per unit time (one minute) A(t) as the market activity. The reason why we define the number of ask quotes as the market activity is because this quantity represents amount of dealers responses to the market. In order to elucidate temporal structure of the market activity power spectrum densities of A(t), estimated by S(f) = 2π lim T A(τ)e 2πifτ dτ 2, () T T 0 2

where f represents frequency, and T a maximum period of the power spectrum density, are calculated. Figs., 2, and 3 show the power spectrum densities for three foreign currency markets (USD/JPY, UER/USD, and EUR/JPY) from January 999 to December 2000. It is found that they have some peaks at the high frequency region. There is a peak at 2.5 minutes on the USD/JPY market, at 3 minutes on the EUR/USD market, and there are some peaks on the JPY/EUR. We confirm that these peaks appear and disappear depending on observation periods. On the USD/JPY market there is the peak for periods of January 999 July 999, March 2000 April 2000, and August 2000 November 2000; on the EUR/USD market July 999 September 999; and on the EUR/JPY market January 999 March 999, April 999 June 999, November 999, and July 2000 December 2000. These peaks mean that market participants offer quotes periodically and in synchronization. The possible reasons for these peaks to appear in the power spectrum densities of the market activity are follows:. The market participants are affected by common periodic information. 2. The market participants are spontaneously synchronized. In the next section the double-threshold agent model is introduced and explain this phenomenon on the basis of the reason (). 0000 999 0000 2000 000 000 00 0 00 0 0. 0 0.05 0. 0.5 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5 frequency [/min] 0. 0 0.05 0. 0.5 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5 frequency [/min] Figure : Semi-log plots of power spectrum densities for time series of the number of ask quotes per minute on the USD/JPY market on 999 (left) and 2000 (right). These power spectrum densities are estimated by averaging power spectrum densities for intraday time series of the number of ask quotes per minute over day for each year. 3

000 999 000 2000 00 0 00 0 0. 0 0.05 0. 0.5 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5 frequency [/min] 0. 0 0.05 0. 0.5 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5 frequency [/min] Figure 2: Semi-log plots of power spectrum densities for time series of the number of ask quotes per minute on the EUR/USD market on 999 (left) and 2000 (right). 3 Double-threshold agent model Here we consider a microscopic model for financial markets in order to explain the dependency of the peak height on observation periods. We develop the double-threshold agent model based on the threshold dynamics. In foreign exchange markets the market participants attend the markets with utilizing electrical communication devices, for example, telephones, telegrams, and computer networks. They are driven by both exogenous and endogenous information and determine their investment attitudes. Since the information to motivate buying and one of selling are opposite to each other we assume that the information is a scaler variable. Moreover the market participants perceive the information and determine their investment attitude based on the information. The simplest model of the market participant is an element with threshold dynamics. We consider a financial market consisting of N market participants having three kinds of investment attitudes: buying, selling, and doing nothing. Recently we developed an array of double-threshold noisy devices with a global feedback [0]. Applying this model to the financial market we construct three decision model with double thresholds and investigate the dependency of market behavior on an exogenous stimuli. The investment attitude of the ith dealer y i (t) at time t is determined by his/her recognition for the circumstances x i (t) = s(t)+z i (t), where s(t) represents the investment environment, and z i (t) the ith dealer s prediction 4

0000 999 0000 2000 000 000 00 0 00 0 0. 0 0.05 0. 0.5 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5 frequency [/min] 0. 0 0.05 0. 0.5 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5 frequency [/min] Figure 3: Semi-log plots of power spectrum densities for time series of the number of ask quotes per minute on the EUR/JPY market on 999 (left) and 2000 (right). from historical market data. y i (t) is given by (x i (t)+ξ i (t) B i (t)) : buy y i (t) = 0 (B i (t) > x i (t)+ξ i (t) > S i (t)) : inactive (x i (t)+ξ i (t) S i (t)) : sell, (2) whereb i (t)ands i (t)represent thresholdvaluestodetermine buyingattitude and selling attitude at time t, respectively. ξ i (t) is the uncertainty of the ith dealer s decision-making. For simplicity it is assumed to be sampled from an identical and independent Gaussian distribution, p(ξ i ) = exp ( ξ2 ) i, (3) 2πσξ 2σξ 2 where σ ξ (> 0) is a standard deviation of ξ i (t). Of course this assumption can be weakened. Namely we can extend the uncertainty in the case of non-gaussian noises and even correlated noises. The excess demand is given by the sum of investment attitudes over the market participants, N r(t) = N y i (t), (4) which can be an order parameter. Furthermore the market price P(t) moves to the direction to the excess demand i= lnp(t+ t) = lnp(t)+γr(t), (5) 5

where γ represents a liquidity constant and t is a sampling period. r(t) may be regarded as an order parameter. The dealers determine their investment attitude based on exogenous factors (fundamentals) and endogenous factors (market price changes). Generally speaking, the prediction of the ith dealer z i (t) is determined by a complicated strategy described as a function with respect to historical market prices, F i (s,p(t),p(t t),...). Following the Takayasu s first order approximation [] we assume that z i (t) is given by z i (t) = a i (t)(lnp(t) lnp(t t)) = γa i (t)r(t t), (6) where a i (t) is the ith dealer s response to the market price changes. It is assumed that the dealers response can be separated by common and individual factors, a i (t) = ζ(t)+η i (t), (7) where ζ(t) denotes the common factor, and η i (t) the individual factor. Generally these factors are time-dependent and seem to be complicated functions of both exogenous and endogenous variables. For simplicity it is assumed that these factors vary rapidly in the limit manner. Then this model becomes well-defined in the stochastic manner. We assume that ζ(t) and η i (t) are sampled from the following identical and independent Gaussian distributions, respectively: P ζ (ζ) = P η (η i ) = exp ( (ζ a)2), (8) 2πσζ 2πση exp ( η2 i 2σ 2 η 2σ 2 ζ ), (9) where a represents a mean of ζ(t), σ ζ (> 0) a standard deviation of ζ(t), and σ η a standard deviation of η(> 0). Since we regard the market activity as the number of tick quotes per unit time it should be defined as the sum of dealers actions: q(t) = N N y i (t). (0) i= The market activity q(t) may be regarded as an order parameter. 6

4 Numerical Simulation This agent model has nine model parameters. We fix N = 00, B i = 0.0, S i = 0.0, γ = 0., σ η = 0.0, and a = 0.0 throughout all numerical simulations. It is assumed that an exogenous periodic information to the market is subject to s(t) = q 0 sin(2π tft) at q 0 = 0.00, f = 0.8 and t =. We calculate the signal-to-noise ratio (SNR) of the market activity as a function of σ ξ. The SNR is defined as SNR = log 0 S N, () where S represents a peak height of the, and N noise level. From the numerical simulation we find non-monotonic dependency of the SNR of q(t) on σ ξ. Fig. 4 shows a relation between the SNR and the noise strength σ ξ. It has an extremal value around σ ξ = 0.0035. Namely the uncertainty of decision-making plays a constructive role to enhance information transmission. If there are exogenous periodic information and the uncertainty of decision-making we can find the peak on power spectrum densities at appropriate uncertainty of decision-making due to stochastic resonance [2]. 5 Conclusion We analyzed time series of the number of tick quotes (market activity) and found there are short-time periodicities in the time series. The existence and positions of these peaks of the power spectrum densities depend on foreign currency markets and observation periods. The power spectrum densities have a peak at 2.5 minutes on the USD/JPY market, 3 minutes on the EUR/USD. There are some peaks at a few minutes on the JPY/EUR. We developed the double-threshold agent model for financial markets where the agents choose three kinds of states and have feedback strategies to determine their decision affected by last price changes. From the numerical simulation we confirmed that the information transmission is enhanced due to stochastic resonance related to the uncertainty of decision-making of the market participants. We propose a hypothesis that the periodicities of the market activity can be observed due to stochastic resonance. Appearance and disappearance of these peaks may be related to the efficiency of the markets. The efficiency market hypothesis [3] says that prices 7

0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 SNR 0.4 0.3 0.2 0. 0 0.002 0.0025 0.003 0.0035 0.004 0.0045 σ ξ Figure 4: Signal-to-noise ratio(snr) obtained from power spectrum densities of q(t) for the double-threshold agent model is plotted against the uncertainty of decision-making of agents at N = 00, B i = 0.0, S i = 0.0, γ = 0., σ η = 0.0, a = 0.0, σ ζ = 0.3, q 0 = 0.00, f = 0.8, and t =. reflect information. Because quotes make prices tick frequency can reflect information. If the peaks of the power spectrum densities come from exogenous information then SNR is related to the efficiency of the market. Namely the market may be efficient when the peaks appear. The author thanks Prof. Dr. T. Munakata for stimulative discussions and useful comments. This work is partially supported by the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science, Grant-in-Aid for Scientific Research # 7760067. References [] R.N. Mantegna and H.E. Stanley, An Introduction to Econophysics: Correlations and Complexity in Finance, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge (2000). [2] M.M. Dacorogna, R. Gençay, U. Müller, R.B. Olsen and O.V. Pictet, An Introduction to High-Frequency Finance, Academic Press, San Diego (2000). 8

[3] T. Mizuno, T. Nakano, M. Takayasu, and H. Takayasu, Physica A, 344 (2004) 330. [4] A.-H. Sato and H. Takayasu, Physica A 250 (998) 23. [5] T. Lux and M. Marchesi, Nature, 397 (999) 498 500. [6] D. Challet, M. Marsili and Yi-Cheng Zhang, Physica A, 294 (200) 54 524. [7] P. Jefferies, M.L. Hart, P.M. Hui and N.F. Johnson, The European Physical Journal B, 20 (200) 493 50. [8] A. Krawiecki and J.A. Ho lyst, Physica A, 37 (2003) 597. [9] The data is provided by CQG International Ltd. [0] A.-H. Sato, K. Takeuchi, and T. Hada, Physics Letters A, 346 (2005) 27. [] H. Takayasu, and M. Takayasu, Physica A, 269 (999) 24. [2] L. Gammaitoni, P. Hänggi, P. Jung, and F. Marchesoni, Review of Modern Physics, 70 (998) 223. [3] E. Fama, Journal of Finance, 46 (99) 575. 9