Handout on the OLG Model and Growth

Similar documents
1. How does an increase in the growth rate of noncapital income over the lifetime, X, affect the saving of young households? Explain.

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Final Exam II ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Macroeconomics. Lecture 5: Consumption. Hernán D. Seoane. Spring, 2016 MEDEG, UC3M UC3M

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Midterm Exam. Answers

Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

14.05: SECTION HANDOUT #4 CONSUMPTION (AND SAVINGS) Fall 2005

1 Multiple Choice (30 points)

Public versus Private Investment in Human Capital: Endogenous Growth and Income Inequality

Problem set 1 - Solutions

Exercises on chapter 4

Growth Theory: Review

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

INDIVIDUAL CONSUMPTION and SAVINGS DECISIONS

Set 3. Intertemporal approach to the balance of payments

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

Finance Solutions to Practice Midterm #1

1 A tax on capital income in a neoclassical growth model

Question 1 Consider an economy populated by a continuum of measure one of consumers whose preferences are defined by the utility function:

We are now introducing a capital, an alternative asset besides fiat money, which enables individual to acquire consumption when old.

Cash in Advance Models

Solving The Perfect Foresight CRRA Consumption Model

Capital Income Tax Reform and the Japanese Economy (Very Preliminary and Incomplete)

Cash-in-Advance Model

14.02 Principles of Macroeconomics Fall 2009

LECTURE 1 : THE INFINITE HORIZON REPRESENTATIVE AGENT. In the IS-LM model consumption is assumed to be a

A 2 period dynamic general equilibrium model

Introduction to economic growth (2)

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014

Problem set 1 ECON 4330

Aging and Pension Reform in a Two-Region World: The Role of Human Capital

Chapter 16 Consumption. 8 th and 9 th editions 4/29/2017. This chapter presents: Keynes s Conjectures

A MODEL OF SECULAR STAGNATION

Overlapping Generations Model: Dynamic Efficiency and Social Security

INTERMEDIATE MACROECONOMICS

5.1 Introduction. The Solow Growth Model. Additions / differences with the model: Chapter 5. In this chapter, we learn:

Consumption and Savings (Continued)

Consumption, Investment and the Fisher Separation Principle

ECONOMICS 723. Models with Overlapping Generations

Final Exam. Consumption Dynamics: Theory and Evidence Spring, Answers

Growth Theory: Review

. Fiscal Reform and Government Debt in Japan: A Neoclassical Perspective. May 10, 2013

5.1 Introduction. The Solow Growth Model. Additions / differences with the model: Chapter 5. In this chapter, we learn:

Introduction to Economic Analysis Fall 2009 Problems on Chapter 3: Savings and growth

Economics 456. International Macroeconomics and Finance: Section 5. Geoffrey Dunbar. UBC, Winter March 14, 2013

ECON 6022B Problem Set 2 Suggested Solutions Fall 2011

Intermediate Macroeconomics

Instruction to exam: Total points 40 points. To pass 24 points are required. To pass with distinction 30 points are required.

Solutions to Problem Set 1

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

Fiscal Reform and Government Debt in Japan: A Neoclassical Perspective

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

FINANCE THEORY: Intertemporal. and Optimal Firm Investment Decisions. Eric Zivot Econ 422 Summer R.W.Parks/E. Zivot ECON 422:Fisher 1.

11/6/2013. Chapter 17: Consumption. Early empirical successes: Results from early studies. Keynes s conjectures. The Keynesian consumption function

ECO209 MACROECONOMIC THEORY. Chapter 14

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism

EC 324: Macroeconomics (Advanced)

Ageing Population and Implications for Monetary Policy. By Sirawit Woramongkhon (Blink)

The extent to which they accumulate productive assets.

Inflation. David Andolfatto

GMM Estimation. 1 Introduction. 2 Consumption-CAPM

FISCAL POLICY AND THE PRICE LEVEL CHRISTOPHER A. SIMS. C 1t + S t + B t P t = 1 (1) C 2,t+1 = R tb t P t+1 S t 0, B t 0. (3)

2014/2015, week 6 The Ramsey model. Romer, Chapter 2.1 to 2.6

Economics 304 Fall 2013

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation.

1 Modelling borrowing constraints in Bewley models

Atkeson, Chari and Kehoe (1999), Taxing Capital Income: A Bad Idea, QR Fed Mpls

The Role of Physical Capital

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016

Consumption and Savings

Welfare Evaluations of Policy Reforms with Heterogeneous Agents

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Fiscal Reform and Government Debt in Japan: A Neoclassical Perspective

A numerical analysis of the monetary aspects of the Japanese economy: the cash-in-advance approach

Homework 1 Due February 10, 2009 Chapters 1-4, and 18-24

2. Find the equilibrium price and quantity in this market.

Money in OLG Models. Econ602, Spring The central question of monetary economics: Why and when is money valued in equilibrium?

Reviewing Income and Wealth Heterogeneity, Portfolio Choice and Equilibrium Asset Returns by P. Krussell and A. Smith, JPE 1997

ECO 4933 Topics in Theory

1 Dynamic programming

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE VALUE OF LIFE AND THE RISE IN HEALTH SPENDING. Robert E. Hall Charles I. Jones

ECON Chapter 6: Economic growth: The Solow growth model (Part 1)

Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics. Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle

1 The Solow Growth Model

Achieving Actuarial Balance in Social Security: Measuring the Welfare Effects on Individuals

Intermediate Macroeconomics, EC2201. L7: Government debt and sustainable fiscal policy

1 Chapter 1 Extra Questions and Answers

Class 3. Explaining Economic Growth. The Solow-Swan Model

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2007

ECON 6022B Problem Set 1 Suggested Solutions Fall 2011

In the Name of God. Macroeconomics. Sharif University of Technology Problem Bank

MACROECONOMICS II - CONSUMPTION

Methods Examination (Macro Part) Spring Please answer all the four questions below. The exam has 100 points.

(Incomplete) summary of the course so far

On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism

Part A: Answer Question A1 (required) and Question A2 or A3 (choice).

Transcription:

Handout on the OLG Model and Growth OLGModel Consider an overlapping generations economy in which each individual lives for two periods. Population is constant, N = 1; normalize it to L = 1 per generation. The individuals noncapital incomes in each period are exogenous. The first period noncapital income of an individual born at time t is equal to y 1,t, and the second-period noncapital income of the same individual is y 2,t+1 = Gy 1,t where G can be greater than or less than one. The consumer solves the optimization problem: max log(c 1,t ) + log(c 2,t+1 ) (1) s.t. (2) c 2,t+1 = R[y 1,t c 1,t ] + y 2,t+1. (3) Finally, between generations the first period noncapital incomes grow by a factor M = (1 + m) so that: y 1,t = My 1,t 1 For the purposes of this question, consider this to be an open economy so that the aggregate interest rate R and noncapital incomes y are fixed (that is, don t try to derive their values from an aggregate production function). 1. How does an increase in the growth rate of noncapital income over the lifetime, G, affect the saving of young households? Explain. c 1,t = y 1,t + y 2,t+1 /R (4) 1 + 1 + G/R = y 1,t (5) 1 + s 1,t = y 1,t c 1,t (6) [ = y 1,t 1 1 + G/R ] (7) 1 + G/R = y 1,t (8) 1 + So an increase in G reduces the saving of young households. Higher G reduces the need for saving to provide for consumption in the second period of life, because with higher G you will be richer in the second period of life anyway.

2. Calculate the level of aggregate saving S t = K t+1 K t as a function of y 1,t 1, and then calculate the aggregate saving rate out of noncapital income σ t = S t /Y t = S t /(y 1,t + y 2,t ). How is the aggregate saving rate related to the growth rate of income between generations, M? How and why does the answer depend on the relationship between and G/R? The aggregate capital stock in period t+1 is given by the saving of the young in period t: K t+1 = Ls 1,t = s 1,t (9) Aggregate saving is given by the change in the aggregate capital stock: S t = K t+1 K t (10) Using the expression for s 1,t derived above, this is: ( ) G/R S t = [y 1,t y 1,t 1 ] 1 + If y 1,t = My 1,t 1 this is: S t = (M 1)y 1,t 1 [ G/R 1 + ] (11) (12) Aggregate income is equal to the sum of the income of the young and the income of the old, Y t = y 1,t + y 2,t (13) = My 1,t 1 + Gy 1,t 1 (14) = y 1,t 1 [M + G] (15) Thus the aggregate saving rate σ t is ( ) M 1 G/R σ t = M + G 1 + How does the saving rate vary with M? dσ t (M + G) (M 1) G/R = dm (M + G) 2 1 + 1 + G G/R = (M + G) 2 1 + (16) (17) (18)

The sign of this relationship depends on whether > G/R or, equivalently, whether R > G. Recall that R is the growth rate of consumption over the lifetime and G is the growth rate of income. If the growth rate of consumption is greater than the growth rate of income, this means that the level of consumption in the first period of life must be below the level of income - that is, young people must be savers. The parameter M determines how much richer the young are than the old. If the young are savers, then making them richer than the old increases the aggregate saving rate. If the young are dissavers, then making them richer than the old reduces the aggregate saving rate. 3. Thus far in the problem, we have assumed that G is independent of M; that is, we have assumed that the rate at which income grows during your lifetime is unrelated to the rate at which each generation s income exceeds the income of the previous generation. Now assume that G = γm for some constant γ. Now when does an increase in M increase or reduce the aggregate saving rate? Substitute G = γm into equation (16): ( ) M 1 γm σ t = M + γm 1 + ( ) M 1 = (1 γm) M (1 + γ)(1 + ) ( ) M 1 + γm γm 2 = M (1 + γ)(1 + ) = (1 1/M + γ γm) (1 + γ)(1 + ) So the derivative of the saving rate with respect to M is dσ t dm = ( (1/M 2 ) γ ) (1 + γ)(1 + ) (19) (20) (21) (22) (23) which will be positive only if 1/M 2 > γ. 4. Empirical evidence shows that the ratio of the income of the old (people aged 55-85) to income of the young (people aged 25-55) is about 0.7 in both the US and in Japan. From the late 1940s to the late 1980s, Japan s economic growth rate was about 4 percent per year in per-capita terms.

Over the same period income growth in the US was about 1 percent per capita. Japan s aggregate saving rate was also much higher than the US saving rate during this period. Discuss whether the overlapping generations model can explain Japan s high saving rate as being the result of its rapid growth rate. (Hint: start by figuring out the OLG model s implications for the ratio of the income of the old to income of the young.) y 2,t = Gy 1,t 1 (24) = Gy 1,t /M (25) y 2,t y 1,t = G/M (26) The fact that the income of the old is about 0.7 times the income of the young implies that G = 0.7M in both countries. The US per capita growth rate of 1 percent per year implies an increase in per-capita income between generations of M = 1.01 30 1.35. The Japanese per capita growth rate translates to M = 1.04 30 3.24. [ σ US = (1 1/1.35 + 0.7 0.7 1.35) (1.7)(1 + ) = 0.014 [ σ Japan = (1 1/3.24 + 0.7 0.7 3.24) = 0.87 (1.7)(1 + ) (1.7)(1 + ) (1.7)(1 + ) ] (27) (28) ] (29) (30) Thus the Japanese saving rate should actually be strongly negative, and certainly much lower than the US saving rate. 1 You can also see that this must be true because from equation (23) if γ = 0.7 the derivative of the saving rate with respect to M is 1 You may wonder how the model can imply a negative steady-state saving rate forever. The reason this does not violate the economy s Intertemporal Budget Constraint is that the economy is growing so fast that it can always repay its borrowing in period t with some of its much greater period t + 1 income.

negative for any M such that 1/M 2 < 0.7 (31) 1/0.7 < M 2 (32) 1.19 < M. (33) Since we calculated M = 1.34 for the US and M = 3.24 for Japan, as we increase M from the US value to the Japanese value the saving rate must be steadily falling. The reason the model implies a negative saving rate for Japan is simple: the young Japanese consumers know that their incomes will be much higher when they are old than when they are young, so they borrow large amounts while young and repay those loans when old. Thus, the OLG model is not a good candidate for explaining why Japan s saving rate has been so high during its period of rapid growth.

200 180 160 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 Figure 4a Predicted C By Age In Steady State in the LC Model Across Countries With Different Rates of Growth of Income Growth Rate of Income 0.5% 1.0% 2.0% 3.0% 4.0% 5.0% 0 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 Age of Household Head Figure 4b Age/Consumption Cross-Section Data for the US, Canada, Japan, Britain, Denmark, and Norway 200 180 160 140 120 100 80 60 40 US Japan Canada Britain Denmark Norway 20 0 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65