BACKGROUNDER. The Economic and Fiscal Effects of Eliminating the Federal Death Tax. Key Points. John L. Ligon, Rachel Greszler, and Patrick D.

Similar documents
BACKGROUNDER. The Economic and Fiscal Effects of the Obama Tax Plan

Obama s Tax Hikes on High-Income Earners Will Hurt the Poor and Everyone Else

A Report of The Heritage Center for Data Analysis

ISSUE BRIEF. How the GOP Tax Bill Will Affect the Economy. Parker Sheppard and David Burton

WebMemo22. The End of Pro-Growth Tax Policy: How the Rangel Tax Bill Could Affect the U.S. Economy. Published by The Heritage Foundation

The Economic Effects of the Estate Tax

Obamacare Tax Subsidies: Bigger Deficit, Fewer Taxpayers, Damaged Economy

BACKGROUNDER. Social Security s main program, also known as Old-Age and Survivors. Social Security: $39 Billion Deficit in 2014, Insolvent by 2035

BACKGROUNDER. A lthough often brushed aside as the lesser of our nation s. Raising the Social Security Payroll Tax Cap: Solving Nothing, Harming Much

WebMemo22. Reduced Job Creation Not Increased Layoffs Explains High Unemployment. Published by The Heritage Foundation.

ESTATE TAXES, DEFICITS and BUDGET IMPLICATIONS

SPECIAL REPORT. Death and Taxes: The Economics of the Federal Estate Tax By Andrew Chamberlain Economist

Using Social Security Personal Retirement Accounts to Create Family Nest Eggs

ESTATE TAXES, DEFICITS, AND BUDGET IMPLICATIONS

The Economic Effects of Capital Gains Taxation

Obama Tax Hikes: Bad for All Americans

A Housing Market Without Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac: Economic Effects of Eliminating Government-Sponsored Enterprises in Housing

ALLOWING HIGH-INCOME TAX CUTS TO EXPIRE ON SCHEDULE WOULD BE SOUND ECONOMIC AND FISCAL POLICY By Chuck Marr

ISSUE BRIEF. The House and Senate each passed slightly different. Improving the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act: A Path for the Conference Committee

2010 Social Security Trustees Report: Reform Needed Now

THE ESTATE TAX: MYTHS AND REALITIES

ISSUE BRIEF. The Tax Cuts and Jobs Act is the most sweeping. Analysis of the 2017 Tax Cuts and Jobs Act. Adam N. Michel

A Look at the End-of-Life Financial Situation in America, p. 2

BACKGROUNDER. Social Security s Disability Insurance (SSDI) program has existed. Improving Social Security Disability Insurance with a Flat Benefit

Two Americas: One Rich, One Poor? Understanding Income Inequality in the United States

Effects of Estate Tax Reform on Charitable Giving

Dynamic Scoring of Tax Plans

Growth Consequences of Estate Tax Reform: Impacts on Small and Family Businesses

NEW ESTATE TAX RULES SHOULD EXPIRE AFTER 2012 Shrinking the Tax Beyond the 2009 Level Is Unaffordable and Unnecessary By Gillian Brunet

CTJ. State-by-State Estate Tax Figures: Number of Deaths Resulting in Estate Tax Liability Continues to Drop. Citizens for Tax Justice

The Economic Program. June 2014

Economic Effects of a New York Minimum Wage Increase: An Econometric Scoring of S6413

Modeling the Estate Tax Proposals of 2016

ISSUE BRIEF. The Congressional Budget Office (CBO) has. CBO Report on Distribution of Income and Taxes Shows Taxes Matter. Curtis S.

Tax Rates and Economic Growth

July 31, First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC Tel: Fax:

BACKGROUNDER. Social Security began as an anti-poverty insurance program, Is Social Security Worth Its Cost? Key Points

Obama s Capital Gains Tax Hike Unlikely to Increase Revenues

ISSUE BRIEF. Both the House of Representatives and the Senate National Defense Authorization Act: Stuck on Compensation and Retirement Reform

Testimony to the President s Tax Reform Panel

ISSUE BRIEF. Unlike traditional attorney-client relationships. Time to Cut Out the SSA as Middleman in SSDI Representation.

Improving Social Security s Progressivity and Solvency with Hybrid Indexing

Estate Taxes: An Historical Perspective

Alice Levy, The George Washington University

Good Intentions Are Not Enough: Why Congress Should Not Raise the Minimum Wage

The Effect of Base-Broadening Measures on Labor Supply and Investment: Considerations for Tax Reform

BACKGROUNDER. U.S. Government Increases National Debt and Keeps 128 Million People on Government Programs

The Economic Benefits of Tax Reform in Louisiana

Increasing the Social Security Payroll Tax Base: Options and Effects on Tax Burdens

Federal Employees Retirement System: Budget and Trust Fund Issues

Updated May 11, of Economic Research, August First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC Tel: Fax:

TOWARD A CONSUMPTION TAX, AND BEYOND

STATES CAN RETAIN THEIR ESTATE TAXES EVEN AS THE FEDERAL ESTATE TAX IS PHASED OUT. By Elizabeth C. McNichol, Iris J. Lav and Joseph Llobrera

Does the Budget Surplus Justify Large-Scale Tax Cuts?: Updates and Extensions

WebMemo22. New CBO Budget Baseline Shows that Soaring Spending Not Falling Revenues Risks Drowning America in Debt

Obamacare: Impact on Taxpayers

Choosing Between an Estate Tax and a Basis Carryover Regime: Evidence from 2010

WebMemo22. Congress Should Repeal or Fix Section 404 of the Sarbanes Oxley Act to Help Create Jobs. Published by The Heritage Foundation

WHAT THE NEW TRUSTEES REPORT SHOWS ABOUT SOCIAL SECURITY By Jason Furman and Robert Greenstein

What The New CBO Report Shows Budget And Economic Outlook Has Not Improved by James Horney and Richard Kogan

Revenue and Incentive Effects of Basis Step-Up at Death: Lessons from the 2010 Voluntary Estate Tax Regime

Why America s Debt Burden Is Declining

WILL THE ADMINISTRATION S TAX CUTS GENERATE SUBSTANTIAL ECONOMIC GROWTH? by Richard Kogan

A R HERITAGE CENTER ANALYSIS REMOVING SOCIAL SECURITY S TAX CAP ON WAGES WOULD DO MORE HARM THAN GOOD D. MARK WILSON. CDA01-07 October 18, 2001

CBO Report Echoes Trustees on Medicare, Social Security

William R. Emmons October 18, 2011

SMALLER DEFICIT ESTIMATE NO SURPRISE New OMB Estimates Do Not Support Claims About Tax Cuts By James Horney

TRENDS AND ISSUES. Do People Save Enough for Retirement?

Robbing Peter to Pay Uncle Sam?

A Dynamic Analysis of President Obama s Tax Initiatives

IRET Congressional Advisory

INTRODUCTION: ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF TAX EXPENDITURES

Evaluating the Economic Impact of Additional Government Infrastructure Spending

BACKGROUNDER. More than 57 million Americans draw on Social Security benefits. Social Security Benefits and the Impact of the Chained CPI.

BACKGROUNDER. In February, the chairman of the House Ways and Means Committee, Chairman Camp s Tax Reform Plan Keeps Debate Alive Despite Flaws

WHY STATES SHOULD ACT NOW TO PRESERVE THEIR ESTATE AND INHERITANCE TAXES. By Elizabeth C. McNichol and Joseph Llobrera

THE US FISCAL GAP AND RETIREMENT SAVING

BALANCING THE FEDERAL BUDGET: ECONOMIC RATIONALE AND ISSUES

The Legacy of the 2001 and 2003 Bush Tax Cuts

Options for Fiscal Consolidation in the United Kingdom

Summary The Administration s 2010 and 2011 budget outlines contain a proposal to cap the value of itemized deductions at 28%, for high-income taxpayer

TAX POLICY CENTER BRIEFING BOOK. Background. Q. What are tax expenditures and how are they structured?

Revenue Analysis Of Options to Reform The Federal Estate, Gift and Generation Skipping Transfer Taxes

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE CONFERENCE AGREEMENT FOR H.R. 1, THE TAX CUTS AND JOBS ACT

WHAT IT TAKES TO SOLVE THE U.S. GOVERNMENT DEFICIT PROBLEM

CBPP S UPDATED LONG-TERM FISCAL DEFICIT AND DEBT PROJECTIONS

Employer-Based Health Insurance: Why Congress Should Cap Tax Benefits Consistently

The Beacon Hill Institute

SPECIAL REPORT. The Excess Burden of Taxes and the Economic Cost of High Tax Rates

ANOTHER ROUND OF ECONOMIC STIMULUS? Hurricane Reconstruction and Relief is the Right Medicine

February 15, Honorable Kent Conrad Chairman Committee on the Budget United States Senate Washington, DC Dear Mr.

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE TAX CUT AND JOBS ACT AS ORDERED REPORTED BY THE SENATE COMMITTEE ON FINANCE ON NOVEMBER 16, 2017

Capital Cost Recovery across the OECD, 2018

The Effect of the Tax Cuts on After-Tax Incomes

THE STATE OF THE ECONOMY

BACKGROUNDER. Policymakers Need to Know: What Is the True Cost of a Butch Lewis Act Pension Bailout? Key Points. Rachel Greszler

The Hidden Cost of. Federal Tax Policy JASON J. FICHTNER & JACOB M. FELDMAN. Arlington, Virginia

BACKGROUNDER. A fter five consecutive years of deficits, the Social Security Disability

HOW MUCH TO SAVE FOR A SECURE

Removing Inflation from the Base is Fair, Pro-Growth Concept

Transcription:

BACKGROUNDER No. 2956 The Economic and Fiscal Effects of Eliminating the Federal Death Tax John L. Ligon, Rachel Greszler, and Patrick D. Tyrrell Abstract The federal estate tax ( known as the death tax) is a tax on a person s lifetime accumulated property. In 2014, the death tax applies a 40 percent tax to all accumulated wealth above $5.34 million. While the death tax applies to relatively few Americans and raises only tiny amounts of revenue for the federal government, it imposes substantial costs on the American economy in terms of lost jobs and reduced growth rates. It has been devastating to family businesses and the communities in which they operate. The Heritage Foundation estimates that eliminating the federal estate tax (and related gift taxes) would boost U.S. economic growth by more than $46 billion over the next 10 years and generate an average of 18,000 private-sector jobs annually. Eliminating the federal death tax would create economic opportunities for American families and free up financial assets for private-sector investment and income growth. The federal estate tax (often referred to as the death tax) is a tax on a person s lifetime accumulated property. In 2014, the death tax applies a 40 percent tax to all accumulated wealth above $5.34 million. 1 While the death tax applies to relatively few Americans and raises only tiny amounts of revenue for the federal government, it imposes substantial costs on the American economy in terms of lost jobs and reduced growth rates. It can be and has been devastating to family businesses and the communities in which they operate. The Heritage Foundation estimates that eliminating the federal estate tax (and related gift taxes) would boost U.S. economic growth by more than $46 billion over the next 10 years and generate an average of 18,000 private-sector jobs annually. Eliminating the fed- This paper, in its entirety, can be found at http://report.heritage.org/bg2956 The Heritage Foundation 214 Massachusetts Avenue, NE Washington, DC 20002 (202) 546-4400 heritage.org Nothing written here is to be construed as necessarily reflecting the views of The Heritage Foundation or as an attempt to aid or hinder the passage of any bill before Congress. Key Points nnone of the worst features of the federal death tax is its effect on family-owned businesses. When a business owner dies and heirs are forced to pay 40 percent of the business value, they often have to sell assets, or even the entire business. nnafter paying the death tax, many businesses have a substantially reduced ability to expand hiring and investment. The Heritage Foundation estimates that because of the death tax, the American economy generates 18,000 fewer jobs each year than it otherwise would. nnthe Heritage Foundation estimates that eliminating the death tax (and related gift taxes) would boost U.S. economic growth by more than $46 billion over the next decade. The increased economic activity would generate offsetting revenue, with a total reduction in tax receipts of just 0.5 percent of federal revenue. nnfederal policymakers should eliminate the death tax. The economic harm imposed by the death tax is not worth the small amount of revenue it might generate.

eral death tax would create economic opportunities for American families and free up financial assets for private-sector investment and income growth. It is time to eliminate the death tax. Not only would the economy reap significant gains, but the resulting loss in federal tax revenues would be significantly lower than supporters of the death tax fear it would be. A macroeconomic simulation of estatetax repeal estimates that the resulting job growth and increased economic activity would generate offsetting revenue, and that the total remaining reduction in tax receipts would amount to only 0.5 percent of federal revenue. The Death Tax Kills Many Family Businesses One of the worst features of the death tax is the effect it has on U.S. family-owned businesses. Many estates subject to the death tax are small or family businesses that are asset rich but cash poor; that is, their wealth is not sitting in liquid assets, such as stocks and bonds, but consists of physical assets, such as buildings, land, and machinery. 2 When the owner of a business dies and the heirs are forced to cough up 40 percent of the business s value, they often have to sell off assets, or even the entire business. 3 These businesses are often sold to large corporations with weak ties to the local business community which has resulted in disastrous consequences for the people who live in those communities. 4 A previous Heritage Foundation study documented some of the devastating effects the estate tax has on individuals and communities. 5 Companies under threat of being destroyed by the death tax range from a minority-owned shrimp business in Biloxi, Mississippi, to one of the best-managed and most popular Section 8 housing properties in New Orleans. Jobs and vital community investments are likely to disappear when companies such as Hancock Lumber, a sixth-generation family business in Casco, Maine, or the Drummond mining company in Sipsey, Alabama, are forced to pay the death tax. Even if a family does come up with the money to pay the estate tax, family members are left with significantly less capital to sustain and grow their business. Businesses that cannot expand cannot hire or invest. The result is fewer jobs, lower productivity, and smaller incomes for American workers. The burden of taxation on U.S. small businesses is already extraordinarily high. The majority of U.S. business owners face very high marginal tax rates during their working years, often close to 50 percent when counting payroll taxes. 6 A 40 percent tax on what is left when an owner dies is just piling on even more. Not Just a Tax on the Wealthy It is not just the wealthy who are harmed by death taxes. Capital is a key component of workers productivity. The death tax, by reducing the level of capital available to workers, means that workers will have less opportunity to increase their own productivity, income, and wealth over their lifetimes. Although the death tax is defended at times on the grounds that it reduces income inequality in the U.S., it actually has a negligible impact on income inequality and other forms of inequality. A recent report by the Joint Economic Committee points to the following studies and findings: Alan Blinder, former Vice Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, found that only about 2 percent of income inequality can be explained by inherited wealth; of the 400 wealthiest people on Forbes s 2011 list, about 70 percent of those individuals were self-made, meaning 1. A $5 million exemption was established in 2011. The exemption was later adjusted for inflation each year thereafter. The exemption applies to each individual, so the estates of married couples can receive two times the exemption level, assuming proper planning and timely filing action. 2. Repealing the death tax does not mean that assets transferred at death would be tax free. Rather, heirs would pay capital gains taxes on inherited assets when they decide to sell them. 3. William W. Beach, Seven Reasons Why Congress Should Repeal, Not Fix, the Death Tax, Heritage Foundation WebMemo No. 2688, November 9, 2009, http://www.heritage.org/research/reports/2009/11/seven-reasons-why-congress-should-repeal-not-fix-the-death-tax. 4. For examples of such consequences, see, Patrick F. Fagan, How the Death Tax Kills Small Businesses, Communities and Civil Society, Heritage Foundation Backgrounder No. 2438, July 26, 2010, http://www.heritage.org/research/reports/2010/07/how-the-death-tax-kills-small-businesses-communities-and-civil-society. 5. Ibid. 6. Curtis S, Dubay, The Economic Case Against the Death Tax, Heritage Foundation Backgrounder No. 2440, July 20, 2010, http://www.heritage.org/research/reports/2010/07/the-economic-case-against-the-death-tax. 2

Special Interests Want to Keep the Death Tax Certain special interest groups like the death tax because it benefits them financially. n n n estate-tax lawyers and planners make a living helping individuals and businesses legally minimize the effect of the death tax on their estates. Life insurance companies collect expensive premiums from family business owners who buy insurance to help their heirs pay the death tax. Large businesses such as multinational corporations face less competition because the death tax encourages smaller, often family-owned businesses to stay small in order to avoid the death tax or to sell their business before they die. Family-owned businesses that do have to pay the death tax are often reduced in size and competitiveness. For every special interest that benefits from the death tax, however, there are individuals and families who are substantially harmed. they built their own fortunes, rather than having had help from family or inheritances; and, according to the 2011 U.S. Trust Survey, 73 percent of individuals with over $3 million in net worth did not accumulate any of their wealth through inheritance. 7 The death tax also encourages Americans to consume more and invest less. Why save if the government is ultimately going to confiscate 40 percent of your estate? All told, lower savings and investment lead to a less dynamic U.S. economy. The immediate consumption and foregone savings means that private businesses have less money to invest, which results in fewer American jobs and lower wages. Little Bang for the Buck Estimates of the impact of the death tax on federal revenue vary significantly. Static estimates that include only the direct receipts from the tax itself show a small positive revenue gain. The Congressional Budget Office, for example, projects that the federal estate (and related gift taxes) will generate a modest 0.65 percent of federal tax revenues between 2015 and 2024 under this scoring method. 8 On the other hand, dynamic models that take into account distortions in economic activity caused by the tax show smaller net receipts from the tax or even negative impacts on federal revenue. The American Family Business Foundation found, for example, an $89 billion loss in revenue over the 2011 2021 period due to the existence of the death tax. 9 This Backgrounder concludes that the true figure almost certainly lies somewhere between these two estimates. Using dynamic scoring that incorporates only one transmission channel (the impact of the death tax on the cost of capital and thus on future investment and job growth), we estimate that death tax receipts under current law will account for only 0.5 percent of federal revenue between 2015 and 2024. 10 What all these studies conclude is that the revenue impact of the death tax is negligible. At best, the tax delivers little bang for the buck; at worst, it costs the federal government more than it gains. While the death tax accomplishes little in the way of revenue or income redistribution, it does generate significant economic harm. At a minimum, the 7. Joint Economic Committee Republicans, Cost and Consequences of the Federal Estate Tax, An Update, July 25, 2012, http://www.jec.senate.gov/republicans/public/?a=files.serve&file_id=bc9424c1-8897-4dbd-b14c-a17c9c5380a3 (accessed September 10, 2014). 8. Congressional Budget Office, An Update to the Budget and Economic Outlook: 2014 to 2024, August 2014, http://www.cbo.gov/publication/45653 (accessed September 15, 2014). 9. Stephen J. Entin, A Score of the Death Tax Repeal Permanency Act, American Family Business Foundation, April 5, 2011, http://nodeathtax.org/uploads/view/2502/a_score_of_the_death_tax_repeal_permanency_act.pdf (accessed September 10, 2014). 10. See Appendix for full results and methodology of this estimate. 3

death tax reduces savings and investment and leads to lower levels in the overall stock of capital in the economy. It also destroys small and family enterprises, at the least reducing their size and ability to grow, both reducing jobs and potentially increasing inequality. 11 This Heritage study estimates that because of the death tax, the American economy generates 18,000 fewer jobs each year than it would if the tax were repealed. Repeal the Death Tax, Expand Economic Opportunity Federal policy leaders should eliminate the death tax. The economic harm imposed by the continuation of the federal death tax is not worth the small amount of revenue it might generate. Ideally, of course, Congress would reform the entire tax system and eliminate all taxes on capital, including capital gains and dividends. Absent that, repeal of the death tax is an important intermediate improvement of the tax code. John L. Ligon is Senior Policy Analyst and Research Manager, Rachel Greszler is Senior Policy Analyst in Economics and Entitlements, and Patrick D. Tyrrell is Research Coordinator, in the Center for Data Analysis, of the Institute for Economic Freedom and Opportunity, at The Heritage Foundation. 11. The death tax induces substantial compliance costs that generate extensive and expensive estate planning to reduce individuals death tax burdens. Numerous studies have posited that the compliance costs of the death tax exceed the revenue it generates. Henry J. Aaron and Alicia H. Munnell, Reassessing the Role for Wealth Transfer Taxes, National Tax Journal, Vol. 45, No. 119 (June 1992); B. Douglas Bernheim, Does the Estate Tax Raise Revenue? Tax Policy and the Economy, Vol. 1 (1987), pp. 113 138; and Alicia H. Munnell, Wealth Transfer Taxation: The Relative Role for Estate and Income Taxes, New England Economic Review, Vol. 19 (November/December 1988). 4

Appendix Simulation Conclusions and Methodology Heritage Foundation economists in the Center for Data Analysis (CDA) estimated the impact of a full repeal of the federal estate tax (and related gift taxes), effective January 1, 2015, on the economy and federal budget over a 10-year forecast horizon, from 2015 to 2024. To conduct this simulation analysis, CDA economists employed the IHS Global Insight (GII) September 2014 Quarterly Macroeconomic Model. The GII model is widely used by Fortune 500 companies, prominent federal agencies, and economic forecasting departments. The methodologies, assumptions, conclusions, and opinions in this analysis are entirely the work of CDA economists and do not necessarily reflect the views of the owners of the model. To begin, CDA economists used estimates by the nonpartisan Congressional Budget Office (CBO) of federal estate and gift taxes from 2015 to 2024, which average $26.1 billion. 12 Thus, repeal of the federal estate and gift taxes are expected to reduce static federal revenues by an average of $26.1 billion over the 2015 2024 period (beginning as $21.5 billion in 2015 and rising to $30.5 billion in 2024). The estate tax is a tax on capital. To capture the macroeconomic impact of eliminating the estate and gift tax, CDA economists simulated the reduction in taxes as a reduction in corporate interest rates as measured by the yield on AAA-rated corporate bonds and BAA-rated corporate bonds. Previous studies show a direct link between wealth-transfer taxes and investment yields: A 2000 study by MIT economist James Poterba estimated that federal estate and transfer taxes add at least 1.3 percent to the cost of owning capital in the United States; 13 a 1996 study by former CDA director William Beach estimated that the federal estate and transfer taxes add 3 percent to the cost of owning capital. 14 Based on current estate-tax-law parameters, CDA economists targeted adjustments to the add factors 15 on the series on AAA-rated corporate bonds and BAArated corporate bonds by 2.5 basis points. Using the add-factor adjustment to these economic series allows the series to remain endogenous to the model as it solves. This parameter value lies between the estimates by James Poterba 16 and William Beach 17 relating to the economic effect that the federal estate tax likely has on the cost of capital. According to the GII model, a full repeal of the federal estate tax (and related gift taxes) would result in a stronger U.S. economy over the forecast horizon. The policy change is assumed to be implemented in 2015, and over a 10-year forecast horizon (2015 2024) induces $46 billion in inflation-adjusted economic growth. The stronger economy would generate an average of 18,000 private-sector jobs annually in the U.S. Beyond a top-line stronger U.S. economy, overall real net worth of American households would increase a little more than $300 billion annually over the 10-year policy forecast horizon. 18 Nearly all of this increase in household wealth would occur in household holdings of financial assets. Over the forecast period there is an average annual increase in real private-sector domestic investment of nearly $3 billion, and an average annual increase in the real capital stock of $14 billion. The macroeconomic simulation does not model the impact of additional federal policy reform that could lead to a stronger economy. This scenario simulates the likely economic effects of this one particular policy change assuming no other changes 12. Congressional Budget Office, An Update to the Budget and Economic Outlook: 2014 to 2024, Table H-2: Revenues, by Major Source, Since 1974, http://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/cbofiles/attachments/45010-outlook2014_feb.pdf (accessed September 16, 2014). 13. James M. Poterba, Estate Tax and After-Tax Investment Returns, in Joel M. Slemrod, ed., Does Atlas Shrug? (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2000), p. 339. 14. William W. Beach, The Case for Repealing the Estate Tax, Heritage Foundation Backgrounder No. 1091, August 21, 1996, http://www.heritage.org/research/reports/1996/08/bg1091nbsp-the-case-for-repealing-the-estate-tax. 15. Add factors are adjustments applied to equation residuals in the forecast modeling system. These adjustment factors are applied to account for possible over-predictions or under-predictions on forecasted time-series variables. 16. Poterba, Estate Tax and After-Tax Investment Returns. 17. Beach, The Case for Repealing the Estate Tax. 18. This is only 0.36 percent of the average annual household inflation-adjusted net worth in the forecast scenario without a federal death tax. 5

to federal policy. Thus, any changes in government spending that may occur as a result of changes in the economy are not included. Likewise, although the model shows an increase in non-estate and gift tax revenues, we do not model the effect of those revenues as a change in the federal spending or taxation. As mentioned, the CBO has estimated that, on a static basis, the repeal would result in a loss of $261 billion in federal tax receipts over 10 years. The results of the dynamic simulation, which only include the direct impact of repeal on the cost of capital, show an offsetting increase of $33 billion over the 10-year period. Although this still suggests a $228 billion reduction in federal revenues, the simulation does not attempt to quantify the additional federal tax revenues that would be gained as a result of more capital being subject to the capital gains tax or the additional federal tax revenues that would be gained as a result of reduced distortions currently generated by the death tax. Federal government spending is estimated to increase slightly relative to the baseline due to the growing economy, but this spending is offset by the additional federal tax revenues. Potential Shortcomings in Simulation Modeling As with all economic forecasts, this analysis is an estimate, and ultimately cannot predict the precise impact of a full repeal of the estate tax. The findings of this dynamic simulation analysis are consistent with economic theory and empirical findings in both expected and actual sign changes on macroeconomic variables, even though for all intents and purposes the exact magnitude of changes in economic variables may be higher or lower. While some weaknesses are inherent in any forecast, this particular estimate may overestimate or underestimate true economic effects in the following ways: nn nn The analysis incorporates the added capital gains tax revenues that would come from the increase in capital stock, but it does not incorporate other added capital gains tax revenues that would come from some capital being taxed at the capital gains tax rate that would otherwise have been taxed at the estate tax rate. Because capital passed on at death is often not realized in the short term, it is difficult to estimate the size or timing of eventual capital gains tax revenues that will accrue from such taxes. In this respect, this analysis overstates the net change in federal tax revenues (the net loss would be lower than the projected decline of $228 billion, or 0.57 percent of federal tax revenues). This analysis estimates a repeal of the federal estate and gift taxes with no change in the current carryover treatment of inherited capital. This would leave an inequity in capital gains taxation between inherited and non-inherited capital. Inheritances subject to the estate tax currently receive a step-up in basis, meaning that the basis for inheritors paying the tax is set at the current market price, as opposed to the price paid by the deceased owner. This prevents another layer of double taxation on transferred assets. However, if the estate tax were eliminated, policymakers may replace the current step-up in basis with a carryover basis, meaning that inheritors would pay capital gains taxes (when they choose to sell their inherited assets) based on the original purchase price of the assets, as opposed to the value when they inherit them. If policymakers were to replace the step-up in basis with a carryover basis, the actual loss in revenue from eliminating the death tax would be significantly lower than projected by this analysis and might, very well, even result in a net increase in tax revenues. 6

AppeNDIX table 1 The Economic and Fiscal Effects of Eliminating the Federal Estate and Gift Tax (page 1 of 3) ECONOMIC INDICATORS 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 Average, 2015 2024 Gross Domestic Product (Billions of Inflation-Adjusted 2009 Dollars) Forecast 16,515.7 17,037.2 17,575.2 18,020.6 18,477.9 18,946.5 19,402.1 19,859.2 20,325.2 20,806.3 18,696.6 Baseline 16,513.9 17,035.1 17,571.9 18,016.4 18,472.4 18,940.7 19,396.1 19,853.2 20,319.4 20,800.5 18,692.0 Difference 1.8 2.2 3.3 4.2 5.4 5.8 5.9 5.9 5.8 5.8 4.6 Total Employment Forecast 141,326,400 143,769,500 146,000,400 147,396,600 148,451,000 149,678,700 150,537,300 151,384,700 152,236,000 153,121,900 148,390,250 Baseline 141,314,100 143,756,300 145,984,400 147,377,400 148,427,700 149,654,700 150,515,500 151,366,400 152,221,600 153,111,100 148,372,920 Difference 12,250 13,200 16,025 19,200 23,300 24,000 21,800 18,275 14,400 10,775 17,323 Private-Sector Employment Forecast 119,323,900 121,622,300 123,612,400 124,749,600 125,585,900 126,426,100 127,184,300 127,782,500 128,378,500 129,015,500 125,368,100 Baseline 119,312,800 121,610,400 123,597,200 124,731,200 125,563,000 126,402,100 127,161,600 127,762,500 128,361,500 129,001,400 125,350,370 Difference 11,025 11,875 15,200 18,375 22,850 24,000 22,675 20,000 17,000 14,175 17,718 Civilian Unemployment Rate (Percent) Forecast 5.80 5.54 5.22 5.12 5.09 5.03 5.00 5.02 5.03 4.99 5.19 Baseline 5.81 5.54 5.23 5.13 5.10 5.03 5.01 5.03 5.04 5.00 5.19 Difference 0.01 0.00 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.01 Household Formation (Millions of Households) Forecast 124.46 126.10 127.70 129.17 130.44 131.71 132.96 134.20 135.44 136.69 130.89 Baseline 124.46 126.09 127.70 129.17 130.44 131.71 132.95 134.19 135.43 136.68 130.88 Difference 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 Personal Income (Billions of Inflation-Adjusted 2009 Dollars) Forecast 13,973.3 14,515.5 15,115.3 15,592.3 16,049.7 16,490.4 16,900.6 17,325.7 17,772.6 18,230.0 16,196.5 Baseline 13,973.1 14,515.5 15,114.6 15,591.0 16,047.6 16,488.1 16,898.2 17,323.4 17,770.4 18,227.7 16,194.9 Difference 0.3 0.1 0.8 1.3 2.1 2.4 2.4 2.3 2.2 2.2 1.6 Consumer Spending (Billions of Inflation-Adjusted 2009 Dollars) Forecast 11,230.0 11,599.1 11,995.2 12,336.3 12,651.3 12,936.5 13,223.8 13,515.4 13,815.4 14,133.5 12,743.7 Baseline 11,228.6 11,597.9 11,993.3 12,333.4 12,647.0 12,931.5 13,218.5 13,509.9 13,810.0 14,128.1 12,739.8 Difference 1.4 1.2 1.9 3.0 4.3 5.0 5.3 5.5 5.4 5.4 3.8 Household Net Worth (Billions of Inflation-Adjusted 2009 Dollars) Forecast 79,138.8 80,532.5 82,291.7 83,927.2 85,482.3 86,944.6 88,500.0 90,185.1 91,990.2 93,846.5 86,283.9 Baseline 78,907.7 80,271.8 82,002.3 83,621.8 85,163.9 86,619.3 88,171.9 89,853.3 91,654.9 93,508.1 85,977.5 Difference 231.1 260.7 289.4 305.4 318.4 325.4 328.0 331.8 335.3 338.5 306.4 BG 2956 heritage.org 7

AppeNDIX table 1 The Economic and Fiscal Effects of Eliminating the Federal Estate and Gift Tax (page 2 of 3) 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 Average, 2015 2024 Effective Real Capital Stock (Billions of Inflation-Adjusted 2009 Dollars) Forecast 18,025.8 18,723.1 19,504.9 20,381.4 21,285.8 22,183.0 23,100.0 24,039.4 24,996.9 25,994.6 21,823.5 Baseline 18,023.1 18,718.3 19,497.7 20,371.3 21,272.9 22,167.6 23,082.3 24,019.6 24,975.2 25,971.1 21,809.9 Difference 2.7 4.8 7.2 10.0 12.8 15.5 17.8 19.8 21.7 23.5 13.6 Gross Private Domestic Investment (Billions of Inflation-Adjusted 2009 Dollars) Forecast 2,867.0 3,078.5 3,244.2 3,330.7 3,416.1 3,516.5 3,598.7 3,683.3 3,772.9 3,867.6 3,437.5 Baseline 2,866.3 3,077.2 3,241.8 3,328.0 3,412.8 3,513.2 3,595.4 3,680.0 3,769.6 3,864.2 3,434.9 Difference 0.7 1.3 2.4 2.7 3.2 3.3 3.3 3.3 3.3 3.4 2.7 Private Fixed Nonresidential Investment (Billions of Inflation-Adjusted 2009 Dollars) Forecast 2219.596 2346.247 2493.6 2604.251 2686.013 2772.285 2861.1 2947.969 3033.662 3129.828 2,709.46 Baseline 2218.519 2344.881 2491.458 2601.701 2683.094 2769.164 2857.923 2944.714 3030.316 3126.365 2,706.81 Difference 1.07675 1.36625 2.14175 2.55 2.919 3.12175 3.17675 3.2555 3.346 3.46275 2.64 Private Fixed Residential Investment in Equipment and Structures (Billions of Inflation-Adjusted 2009 Dollars) Forecast 578.3 666.8 684.9 673.3 678.9 690.3 686.6 682.4 685.4 689.7 671.7 Baseline 578.6 666.9 684.9 673.2 678.8 690.1 686.4 682.3 685.4 689.7 671.6 Difference 0.4 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.0 0.0 Net Exports of Goods and Services (Billions of Inflation-Adjusted 2009 Dollars) Forecast 448.8 511.4 551.9 554.8 515.4 453.9 383.3 321.0 262.3 207.7 421.1 Baseline 448.4 511.0 550.8 553.2 513.2 451.3 380.6 318.2 259.5 204.8 419.1 Difference 0.4 0.4 1.1 1.6 2.2 2.6 2.7 2.8 2.9 2.9 2.0 Consumer Price Index, All-Urban (Percent) Forecast 2.41 2.45 2.49 2.55 2.60 2.65 2.71 2.77 2.83 2.90 2.64 Baseline 2.41 2.45 2.49 2.55 2.60 2.65 2.71 2.77 2.83 2.90 2.64 Difference 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Yield on 10 Year Treasury Notes (Percent) Forecast 3.23 3.73 4.20 4.21 4.21 4.21 4.21 4.21 4.21 4.21 4.06 Baseline 3.23 3.73 4.20 4.21 4.21 4.21 4.21 4.21 4.21 4.21 4.06 Difference 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Discount Rate on 3 Month Treasury Bills (Percent) Forecast 0.35 1.99 3.41 3.51 3.51 3.51 3.51 3.51 3.51 3.51 3.03 Baseline 0.35 1.99 3.41 3.51 3.51 3.51 3.51 3.51 3.51 3.51 3.03 Difference 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 BG 2956 heritage.org 8

AppeNDIX table 1 The Economic and Fiscal Effects of Eliminating the Federal Estate and Gift Tax (page 3 of 3) FEDERAL BUDGET INDICATORS 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 Total, 2015 2024 Federal Debt held by the Public (Billions of Dollars) Forecast 13,494.7 14,013.6 14,563.0 15,156.3 15,782.5 16,373.3 16,950.1 17,563.2 18,210.2 18,862.8 18,862.8 Baseline 13,490.4 14,009.0 14,558.4 15,151.4 15,776.8 16,366.9 16,942.6 17,554.4 18,199.7 18,850.7 18,850.7 Difference 4.3 4.7 4.6 4.9 5.7 6.4 7.5 8.9 10.4 12.1 12.1 Federal Tax Receipts, Unified Budget Basis (Billions of Dollars) Forecast 3,404.6 3,575.6 3,709.5 3,852.6 4,019.5 4,267.4 4,523.4 4,770.0 5,025.9 5,333.9 42,482.4 Baseline 3,401.3 3,571.7 3,705.2 3,849.0 4,016.4 4,264.2 4,520.5 4,767.3 5,023.0 5,330.9 42,449.4 Difference 3.3 4.0 4.3 3.7 3.2 3.2 2.9 2.7 2.8 3.0 33.0 Static Revenue 21.5 22.9 23.7 24.5 25.6 26.7 27.7 28.7 29.6 30.5 261.4 Loss* Net Change 18.2 18.9 19.4 20.8 22.4 23.5 24.8 26.0 26.8 27.5 228.4 in Revenue** Federal Unified Budget Outlays (Billions of Dollars) Forecast 3,850.8 4,000.8 4,165.1 4,352.1 4,551.9 4,764.4 5,006.4 5,289.3 5,578.9 5,892.7 47,452.3 Baseline 3,846.2 3,996.4 4,160.8 4,348.1 4,548.0 4,760.5 5,002.4 5,285.2 5,574.5 5,888.0 47,410.1 Difference 4.5 4.4 4.2 4.0 3.9 3.9 3.9 4.1 4.4 4.7 42.1 Federal FY Unified Budget Balance (Billions of Dollars) Forecast 462.4 411.0 443.2 492.6 531.6 506.0 482.1 505.3 551.3 561.1 4,946.5 Baseline 460.8 410.4 443.2 492.5 530.8 505.4 481.1 503.9 549.7 559.5 4,937.3 Difference 1.6 0.6 0.0 0.1 0.8 0.7 0.9 1.3 1.5 1.7 9.2 * Static revenue loss is the assumed loss of the revenue stream for the federal estate and gift taxes over the 10 year period (2015 2024) as projected by the Congressional Budget Office (CBO). ** This net change in revenue is the summation of the dynamic (in difference) revenue stream and the static revenue stream as projected by the CBO. Source: Heritage Foundation calculations using data from the IHS Global Insight 2014 September Short-Term Quarterly U.S. Macroeconomic Model. BG 2956 heritage.org 9