All about interest rates

Similar documents
Interest Rate Liberalization and the International Role of the RMB. Nicholas Lardy. Senior Fellow Peterson Institute for International Economics

China: The Long and Short of Economic Reform

The Effect of Chinese Monetary Policy on Banking During the Global Financial Crisis

Outlook 2013: China. Growth expected to accelerate again

Progress Evaluation of the Transformation of China's Economic Growth Pattern 1 (Preliminary Draft Please do not quote)

Summary. Editor: Tristan Zhuo Senior Economist Phone:

Sinology KEY QUESTIONS FOR CHINA INVESTORS IN 2015 PART II. by Andy Rothman. Why Do I Keep Saying China Won t Ease this Year?

THE U.S. ECONOMY IN 1986

Is China the New France?

South African Reserve Bank STATEMENT OF THE MONETARY POLICY COMMITTEE. Issued by Lesetja Kganyago, Governor of the South African Reserve Bank

Key Insights. China Macro Pulse

Money and Banking. Lecture XII: Financial Risks in the Chinese Economy. Guoxiong ZHANG, Ph.D. December 5th, Shanghai Jiao Tong University, Antai

an eye on east asia and pacific

Has the China Collapse Finally Arrived?

Summary. The RMB will be added to the IMF s SDR basket of currencies starting October 1 st, which will be

COMMENTARY NUMBER 462 June Trade Balance, Consumer Credit. August 9, Bernanke Bemoans GDP Not Reflecting Common Experience

ECONOMY REPORT - CHINESE TAIPEI

International Monetary and Financial Committee

Monetary policy assessment of 12 March 2009 Swiss National Bank takes decisive action to forcefully relax monetary conditions

WTO ACCESSION AND FINANCIAL REFORM IN CHINA Justin Yifu Lin

Arthur Kroeber Managing Director Dragonomics Research & Advisory. 21 January 2010

Economic ProjEctions for


Credit Conditions for Young and Beginning Farmers. by Nathan S. Kauffman 1

MONETARY AND FINANCIAL TRENDS IN THE FIRST NINE MONTHS OF 2013

Observation. January 18, credit availability, credit

Exploring the Economy s Progress and Outlook

China: Double, Double Toil and Trouble/Fire Burn, and Cauldron Bubble?

Summary. The RMB continues to depreciate against the dollar. While there are a number of factors

CLSA Investors Forum September Mrs Margaret Leung Vice-Chairman and Chief Executive Hang Seng Bank

Monetary Policy Report, June 2017

The U.S. Economy and Monetary Policy. Esther L. George President and Chief Executive Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City

SPECIAL REPORT. TD Economics ASSESSING CHINA S QUEST FOR ECONOMIC REBALANCING

Reforming the Transmission Mechanism of Monetary Policy in China

Asian Insights Third quarter 2016 Asia s commitment in policies and reforms

Developing futures to mitigates risks as China's economy shifts gear

In the past 20 years, China has added

CHINA S DIRECTION IN What is the Risk of a Debt Crisis?

The reasons why inflation has moved away from the target and the outlook for inflation.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES U.S. GROWTH IN THE DECADE AHEAD. Martin S. Feldstein. Working Paper

MCCI ECONOMIC OUTLOOK. Novembre 2017

Neoliberalism, Investment and Growth in Latin America

Global Economic Outlook

Ric Battellino: Recent financial developments

HAS THE CHINA COLLAPSE FINALLY ARRIVED?

Implications of Fiscal Austerity for U.S. Monetary Policy

The Economic Recovery and Monetary Policy: Taking the First Step Towards the Long Run

The Impact of China on the UK and European Economies January Cork Gully on. The impact of China on the UK and European Economies

China s Economic Growth Model Medium and Long Term Challenges

CHINA S ECONOMY AT A GLANCE

Jean-Pierre Roth: Recent economic and financial developments in Switzerland

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

Speech by Mr. Amando M. Tetangco, Jr. Governor, Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas

International Monetary and Financial Committee

Haruhiko Kuroda: Japan s economy and monetary policy

Remarks on the Housing Market and Subprime Lending. Remarks. Ben S. Bernanke. Chairman. (via satellite) to the International Monetary Conference

REFER TO DISCLOSURE SECTION AT THE END OF THE NOTES

ASSESSING THE RISK OF A DOUBLE-DIP RECESSION: KEY INDICATORS TO MONITOR

Farmers have significantly increased their debt levels

Out of the Shadows: Projected Levels for Future REO Inventory

Flash Comment China takes more steps to fight financial risks

International Monetary and Financial Committee

Jan F Qvigstad: Outlook for the Norwegian economy

Joseph S Tracy: A strategy for the 2011 economic recovery

Global Economic Outlook

THE NEW ECONOMY RECESSION: ECONOMIC SCORECARD 2001

China s Growth Miracle: Past, Present, and Future

CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES CONGRESSIONAL BUDGET OFFICE CBO. The Budget and Economic Outlook: Fiscal Years 2013 to 2023

POST-CRISIS GLOBAL REBALANCING CONFERENCE ON GLOBALIZATION AND THE LAW OF THE SEA WASHINGTON DC, DEC 1-3, Barry Bosworth

Monthly Outlook. June Summary

1 Implications of rising trade tensions for the global economy. Prepared by Lucia Quaglietti

Masaaki Shirakawa: The transition from high growth to stable growth Japan s experience and implications for emerging economies

Economic Interaction

BOFIT Forecast for Russia

HONDURAS. 1. General trends

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2009 and 2010 estimates)

Agencia Tributaria TAX REVENUE ANNUAL REPORT

Summary. Chinese equities remained mired in a bear market, with the Shanghai composite losing nearly

Q Capital Markets Review

CRS Report for Congress

Business cycles in South Africa during the period 1999 to 2007

Outlook for Economic Activity and Prices (July 2018)

International Monetary and Financial Committee

Sixtieth session of the Trade and Development Board September Items 4 and 8: Interdependence and Development Strategies

EMBA June 2016 ON CHINA

International Journal of Business and Economic Development Vol. 4 Number 1 March 2016

Themes in bond investing June 2009

Escaping from a Liquidity Trap and Deflation (Svensson, JEP, 2003)

Gauging Current Conditions: The Economic Outlook and Its Impact on Workers Compensation

KEYNOTE SPEECH Deputy Governor of Bank Indonesia, Bp. Perry Warjiyo Ph.D at BNP Paribas Economic Outlook 2016 Jakarta, 23 March 2016

The ECB Survey of Professional Forecasters. First quarter of 2017

1 World Economy. Value of Finnish Forest Industry Exports Fell by Almost a Quarter in 2009

The UK economic and fiscal outlook

Monetary and financial trends in the fourth quarter of 2014

Mizuho Economic Commentary-China

Brian P Sack: Managing the Federal Reserve s balance sheet

Finland falling further behind euro area growth

ENGINEERING CHINA S FINANCIAL REFORM

PART 1. recent trends and developments

Real Gross Domestic Product (GDP) of Hong Kong increased 0.9 percent in the first half

Transcription:

Financial reform All about interest rates by Nicholas R. Lardy Financial reform is the most important economic challenge that China s new leadership faces as it seeks to sustain reasonably rapid economic growth over the next 10 years. For some time there has been a consensus that the growth model of the Hu Jintao-Wen Jiabao era is broken. Hu and Wen presided over an economy in which the investment share of GDP rose by more than 10 percentage points, reaching the astonishing peak of 48% in 2011-12. But economic growth based on a super-elevated level of investment and systematic suppression of private consumption is not a viable long-run growth model. Consumption expenditure must become a much more important source of demand. Let em rise Reform of the financial sector is the single most important prerequisite for sustained economic rebalancing in favor of consumption. The key element of financial reform is not the introduction of complex financial instruments or further opening the domestic market to foreign financial institutions. It is rather eliminating the remaining government controls on interest rates on both deposits and loans, commonly referred to as market-oriented interest-rate liberalization. The People s Bank of China has long set ceilings on deposit rates and floors on lending rates. In sharp contrast with the Jiang Zemin-Zhu Rongji era, when the central bank set these rates so that households earned an average real interest rate of 3% on one-year deposits, average real returns in the Hu-Wen era were negative. Interest-rate liberalization began under Jiang and Zhu, but was largely suspended in 2004 when the central bank allowed financial institutions to adjust their lending rates upward without limit from the benchmark rates. The ceiling on deposit rates remained unchanged until June 2012, when the central bank allowed banks to pay interest rates up to 10% above newly established, slightly lower benchmark rates on deposits. Although this small relaxation only had a marginal impact, competition for depositors compelled banks to push their deposit rates to the top of the new permitted range, suggesting strongly that market-determined deposit rates lie higher. This view is shared by leading Chinese bankers such as Xiao Gang, chairman of the Bank of China, China s fourth largest commercial bank. He has strongly supported market-oriented interest-rate liberalization, even though he anticipates it will cut net interest margins of banks by up to half. Market-oriented interest-rate liberalization could be expected to contribute to China s economic rebalancing through three distinct channels. First, higher deposit rates would increase household income and thus, Financial reform is the most important economic challenge facing China s new leadership Interest-rate liberalization lies at the heart of the changes that need to be made Nicholas Lardy is Anthony M. Solomon Senior Fellow at the Peterson Institute for International Economics and author of Sustaining China s Economic Growth After the Global Financial Crisis (Peterson Institute, 2012). MARCH 2013 21

The shape of financial repression Composition of GDP, % of total (1992-2011) 40 30 Household consumption Investment Source: CEIC, GK Dragonomics estimates 2010 Earning less, saving more Household diposable income compared to household savings, % of GDP (1992-2011) 70 60 40 30 20 Income Savings Source: CEIC, GK Dragonomics estimates 2010 for any given household savings rate, boost private consumption expenditure. Second, higher deposit rates would likely lower the household saving rate also boosting private consumption expenditure. Finally, higher deposit rates will feed through in part to higher lending rates which, in turn, can be expected to increase the wage share of GDP, a key prerequisite for raising the consumption share of GDP. Since each of these channels is independent, the effects of interest-rate liberalization would be the sum of the three. Happy shoppers Financial repression, in the form of lower deposit rates faced by households after 2003, contributed importantly to a reduction in household income as a share of GDP. Between 2003 and 2009 (the last year for which the detailed flow of funds accounts are available), interest earned by households on their savings deposits as a share of GDP declined by half. This occurred despite the fact that household bank deposits as a share of GDP over this period increased by more than half. In short, the stock of household saving as a share of GDP rose sharply, while the interest income generated by these deposits as a share of GDP plummeted. Market-oriented interest-rate liberalization would eliminate the financial repression that imposes a high implicit tax on Chinese savers, leading directly to higher levels of household income and household consumption expenditure. The second channel through which interest-rate liberalization could be expected to raise household consumption is its effect on household savings behavior. The aggregate data on household savings from the flow of funds show that in the latter years of the Jiang-Zhu era (1997-2003), when the real one-year deposit rate was positive, household savings averaged 32% of disposable income. In the Hu-Wen era, when the average real rate of return on one-year deposits was negative, household savings jumped to an average of 38% of disposable income. Three separate IMF studies provide microeconomic evidence for the same inverse relationship between the real interest rate and the saving rate of Chinese households. Data in China s flow of funds accounts allow us to estimate with some confidence that, if interest rates were liberalized, the combined effects of the first two channels would be to raise household consumption by 6 percentage points of GDP. This single policy change would reverse about two-thirds of the decline in consumption as a share of GDP seen under Hu and Wen. gloomy factories The third channel through which interest-rate liberalization would contribute to rebalancing is more complex but potentially important. In the Hu-Wen era, real lending rates fell by almost 0 basis points compared to the Jiang-Zhu era. This may seem surprising but was perfectly predictable. Low ceiling rates on deposits set by the central bank after 2003 gave commercial banks a very cheap source of funding. Competition among banks meant that a large portion of this reduced cost of funds was passed along to borrowers. This constituted an implicit subsidy for 22 GK DRAGONOMICS MARCH 2013

the capital-intensive manufacturing sector at the expense of the more labor-intensive services sector, thus elevating profits in manufacturing and depressing profits in services. This tilted more investment into manufacturing at the expense of services. The effect on the pattern of economic growth was remarkable. Between the very early 1980s and 2002, the services share of GDP increased by 1 percentage point per year, reaching 42%. But in the next decade it rose cumulatively by only a single percentage point. Since services are much more labor-intensive than manufacturing, the pattern of growth after 2002 generated many fewer jobs than would have been the case if financial repression had not lowered the cost of borrowing after 2003. The adverse effect of this on household income was compounded because service-sector jobs in China pay higher wages than those in manufacturing. Interest-rate liberalization would reverse this process. Higher deposit rates would be passed on at least in part to borrowers, making fewer investment projects profitable. That would contribute importantly to reducing the super-elevated share of investment in GDP to a more sustainable level. Moreover, the implicit subsidy to manufacturing would erode and more service-sector jobs would be created. This would have a double-barreled positive effect on household wages, feeding through to higher consumption. The flip side is that the profit share of GDP, which soared during the Hu-Wen era, would erode. Thus an ancillary benefit of interest-rate liberalization would be to contribute to improving the Time for workers to fight back Wage share of GDP (1992-2009), % 55 54 53 52 51 49 48 47 Source: CEIC WMPs: as dangerous as they sound Both Moody s and Fitch Ratings argue that the emergence of wealth management products (WMPs), which typically offer savers higher nominal interest rates than bank deposits, constitutes a back door de facto liberalization of interest rates. Is this another dual-track approach to economic reform, with market-determined rates via WMPs set to wrest market share from fixedceiling bank deposit rates? And if so, should we not view WMPS positively, as a precursor to broader interest-rate reforms and growing household consumption? There are several reasons to be skeptical. First, WMPs appear to be purchased disproportionately by highincome households. Banks are required to accept even very small savings deposits, but WMPs require a high minimum investment, rarely less than Rmb,000 two years worth of wages for workers in private enterprises. Higher yielding products often have minimum investment levels of Rmb200,000-0,000 or even more, so the higher interest earnings from WMPs accrue disproportionately to wealthier households that save an unusually high share of their incomes. They are much less likely to spend the additional income compared to less affluent households. Second, WMPs involve potentially large risks. Almost all WMPs are relatively short term, typically 90 days, but frequently the funds raised are invested in projects with long payback periods. So when WMPs mature, trust companies and banks repay depositors with funds raised from the sale of new WMPs, rather than from the returns generated by the projects in which the funds were invested. Xiao Gang, chairman of the Bank of China, says that WMPs share certain characteristics with Ponzi schemes. From the investor side there are other dangers. Many investors in WMPs look only at the nominal interest rate and are unaware of or unable to evaluate the risk of the products that are offered. The December 2012 default on Rmb140m of third-party wealth products marketed by Huaxia Bank underscores these risks. Regulators responded by tightening up on the issuance of WMPs. In short, liberalization of interest rates via WMPs is a poor substitute for across-the-board, market-oriented interestrate liberalization. The positive influence of higher earnings of WMPs on private consumption expenditure is likely to be muted, while WMPs entail substantial risks to the financial system. MARCH 2013 23

Too cheap by half Real interest rate on one-year loans, % 20 15 10 5 0-5 -10 1997 Jiang-Zhu era (1997-2003) 2002 Source: CEIC, author estimates Hu-Wen era (2004-11) 2007 2012 Vested interests especially property developers and other owners of capital will resist interest-rate liberalization distribution of income, since it would reduce the outsized gains that have accrued to capital owners over the past decade a major source of increased income inequality in China. Interest-rate liberalization is sometimes opposed for fear that higher rates could imperil both China s non-financial corporate sector, which currently has bank debt in excess of 100% of GDP, and China s commercial banks, which would face a much higher cost of funds. Even gradual interest-rate liberalization is likely to push some firms to the wall. Yet this should be regarded as an inevitable consequence of a decade of super-low lending rates. If banks cannot expect their borrowers to pay market-determined loan rates they will not be able to offer their depositors market-determined deposit rates. Banks could easily absorb a reduction in their net interest margins if, as expected, they struggle to pass the higher costs of funds to their borrowers. Currently Chinese banks are highly profitable, topping international leagues for return on assets, the best measure of bank profitability. But to minimize the possibility that banks would respond to potentially reduced margins by pursuing excessively risky lending, interest-rate liberalization should be accompanied by strengthened bank regulation. The real obstacle to interest-rate liberalization is the opposition of the vested interests that have gained so much from China s imbalanced growth strategy of the past decade. That strategy benefited property developers and other owners of capital (including the state) at the expense of wage earners; the manufacturing sector at the expense of services; and China s coastal regions at the expense of interior provinces. The coastal regions benefited from imbalanced growth in part because most of China s manufacturing is concentrated in coastal regions. But this benefit was compounded by two other distortions that were important in much of the Hu-Wen era subsidized energy and an undervalued exchange rate. Since two-thirds of China s energy production is used in manufacturing, cheap power further increased the pro-manufacturing bias of the past decade. And the low exchange rate compounded the same bias by pushing up profits on exports of manufactured goods. Following in Deng s footsteps? Powerful vested interests may oppose financial-sector reform, but early evidence suggests the Xi-Li leadership team will push ahead anyway. Xi s trip to Shenzhen, Zhuhai, Foshan and Guangzhou immediately after the 18th Party Congress in late 2012 and precisely 20 years after Deng Xiaoping s famous Southern Tour was a clear signal that China s incoming president intends to resume the economic reforms that were all but suspended under Hu and Wen. China s new leaders know that reform is needed, for two reasons. First, the slower pace of growth in 2011-12 revealed structural weaknesses in the underlying growth model. There is now a widespread recognition that much of the growth of the past decade was made possible by fundamental reforms undertaken in the Jiang-Zhu era, notably the downsizing of the 24 GK DRAGONOMICS MARCH 2013

state sector in the mid-1990s and the measures to become a member of the World Trade Organization in 2001. But as the economic momentum gained by these reforms wanes, Xi and Li understand that new far-reaching reforms are needed to ensure that China s growth does not fall below the 7-8% pace now regarded as the new normal. Second, even the vested interests understand that the legitimacy of the party and its continued rule depend on delivering reasonably rapid economic growth. Ultimately they are likely to cede some of the outsized benefits they have gained from the current growth model, rather than block reform and risk losing all. What would a new growth path under Xi and Li look like? To sustain 7.5% growth over the decade while scaling back investment by 10 percentage points of GDP (as recommended in a recent IMF paper) would require consumption growth to run about 2 percentage points ahead of GDP growth and investment growth to decelerate very substantially. Assorted China bears argue that quicker consumption growth is unlikely, while any significant investment slowdown could drive down GDP growth to an average of about 3% for an extended period. Yet Taiwan s experience suggests rebalancing while sustaining growth is achievable. After three decades of imbalanced growth that led to a 30 percentage point reduction in the consumption share of GDP, Taiwan in the mid-1980s began a program of concerted financial reform that included capital-market, interest-rate and exchange-rate liberalization. These reforms led to a surge in private consumption expenditure that helped to sustain relatively rapid economic growth, even as net exports shrank by 10 percentage points of GDP between 1987 and 1996. There is no reason why China should not follow the same path. All good things start here In addition to supporting growth, liberalizing interest rates would have many other benefits. It would reduce the risk of creating asset bubbles that can accompany extended periods of negative real deposit rates. It is a prerequisite for increasing competition in the banking system, which could lead to a more efficient allocation of capital. It would facilitate the deepening of China s capital markets, paving the way for further liberalization of the capital account. And it would improve the monetary policy transmission mechanism, increasing the ability of the monetary authority to reduce macroeconomic fluctuations. If Xi Jinping and Li Keqiang make the financial reforms needed to create a healthier model of economic growth, there is a good prospect that China s economy will grow at 7-8% for the next decade. By the end of 2022, when Xi and Li are expected to step down, China s GDP will have doubled in size surpassing that of the US today. More importantly, personal income and consumption gains will be much larger, enabling China s citizens to share more fully in the benefits of rapid economic growth than they did in the Hu-Wen era. Liberalizing interest rates should not be viewed, therefore, as a mere tool of greater economic efficiency. It is also a path toward greater social justice. Hu s raw deal Real interest rate on one-year deposits, % 8 7 6 5 4 3 2-1 01-2 -3-4 -5 1997 Source: PBC, NBS Jiang-Zhu era (1997-2003) 2002 Hu-Wen era (2004-11) 2007 Successful financial reform would help underpin annual economic growth of 7-8% for the next decade 2012 MARCH 2013 25