Re: Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act; Market Stabilization [CMS-9929-P]

Similar documents
Marketplace Stabilization Rule Webinar

March 7, Re: Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act; Market Stabilization

Reinsurance and Cost-Sharing Reductions Estimates

HEALTH INSURANCE MARKETPLACES 2016 OPEN ENROLLMENT PERIOD: JANUARY ENROLLMENT REPORT For the period: November 1 December 26, January 7, 2016

Analysis of Affordable Care Act (ACA) Market Stabilization Final Rule 1. April 19, 2017

Frequently Asked Questions Regarding Verification of Special Enrollment Periods

Reports and Research Table of Contents May 18, 2017 Board Meeting

ACA and AHCA Part 1: The Big Picture in the Individual Market, 50,000 Arizonans 50+ Face Huge Cost Increase by 2020 under GOP Proposal

H.R American Health Care Act of 2017

Association Health Plans: Projecting the Impact of the Proposed Rule

Exchange Market: 2015 National Snapshot

Health and Economy Baseline Estimates

Proposals for Insurance Options That Don t Comply with ACA Rules: Trade-offs In Cost and Regulation

Health Care Rule Changes Will Harm Consumers

HEALTH INSURANCE EXCHANGES: WHO IN TENNESSEE HAS ENROLLED? A critical component of the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act (ACA) was

Quantifying Tax Credits for People Now Buying Insurance on Their Own

AMA vision for health system reform

REPORT 2 OF THE COUNCIL ON MEDICAL SERVICE (A-18) Improving Affordability in the Health Insurance Exchanges (Reference Committee A) EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

Affordable Care Act Repeal and Replacement Legislation

December 13, 2018 Internal Revenue Service Room 5205 Ben Franklin Station Washington, DC 20044

RE: CMS-9929-P, Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act; Market Stabilization

Executive Summary. September 22, The Honorable Chuck Schumer Democratic Leader, U.S. Senate S-221 Capitol Building Washington, DC 20510

November 27, Re: Affordable Care Act: Proposed HHS Notice of Benefit and Payment Parameters for 2019 CMS P

Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act Market Stabilization. Summary of Final Rule with Operational and Strategic Impacts.

Individual Insurance Markets: Enrollment Changes in 2018 and Potential Policies That Could Lower Premiums and Stabilize the Markets in 2019

Factors Influencing 2019 Premiums in the Individual Market ISSUE BRIEF KEY TAKEAWAYS FEBRUARY 2018

Insurance (Coverage) Reform

The Affordable Care Act: Seven Years Later

Restricting Special Enrollment Periods Could Hurt Young Adults and the Health Insurance Marketplaces

STATES SHOULD STRUCTURE INSURANCE EXCHANGES TO MINIMIZE ADVERSE SELECTION by Sarah Lueck

Covered California s Review of CMS s Analysis of the 2018 Open-Enrollment Period

Understanding the Affordable Care Act s State Innovation ( 1332 ) Waivers

February 19, Dear Secretary Azar,

Obamacare Tax Subsidies: Bigger Deficit, Fewer Taxpayers, Damaged Economy

Health Insurance Premium Tax Credits and Cost-Sharing Subsidies

Health and Economy Baseline Estimates

STATE OF WASHINGTON. Re: Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act; Exchange Program Integrity [CMS P]

Health Care: Obama Officials Look Back at the ACA and the Path Forward

H.R Better Care Reconciliation Act of 2017

Re: [CMS-9930-P]-Comments on Notice of Benefit and Payment Parameters for 2019 Proposed Rule

Health Care Spending Under Reform: Less Uncompensated Care and Lower Costs to Small Employers

IMPACT ON MEMBERS AND PREMIUMS OF COVERING THE COST OF THE UNFUNDED COST SHARING REDUCTION PROGRAM

Estimating the Impact of Repealing the Affordable Care Act on Hospitals

American Health Care Act (House-Passed Bill)

A Promising Strategy for an Affordable Medicaid Buy-In Option in Colorado

Affordable Care Act: Impact on the Indiana Market

Date: February 6, From: Center for Consumer Information and Insurance Oversight, Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services

Committee on Ways and Means U.S. House of Representatives. Hearing on Expanding Coverage of Prescription Drugs in Medicare.

Marketing Matters: How Marketing and Outreach Builds Stable Marketplaces and Pays Off for the Federal Government

The New Responsibility to Secure Coverage: Frequently Asked Questions

The Honorable Sylvia Matthews Burwell, Secretary United States Department of Health and Human Services 200 Independence Ave., SW Washington, DC 20201

Delaying the Individual Mandate Would Disrupt Overall Implementation of the Affordable Care Act

Overview of Health Insurance Exchanges

Key Medicaid, CHIP, and Low-Income Provisions in the Senate Bill Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act (Released November 18, 2009)

Comparison of ACA and STLD Coverage Requirements and Implications for the ACA Markets

WHITE PAPER. Impact of CSR De-funding on Market Stability. Executive Summary

1825 Eye Street, NW, Suite 401 Washington, DC p: f:

Update on the Section 1332 State Innovation Waivers May Update on the Section 1332 Innovation Waivers

Helping Consumers Understand and Use Health Insurance in 2014

RE: CMS-9926-P; Medicaid Program; Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act; HHS Notice of Benefit and Payment Parameters for 2020

ACA Regulations: Insurance Exchanges and EHBs

The Healthy America Program

Office of the President Haywood L. Brown, MD, FACOG

DRAFT Premium Adjustment Percentage

RE: Comment on CMS-9937-P ( Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act; HHS Notice of Benefit and Payment Parameters for 2017: Proposed Rule )

Summary Cost Data for Health Plans Available in Georgia s Exchange, 2014: Fact Sheet

AGENCY: Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services (CMS), HHS.

The Trump Administration Marketplace Rule and How States Can Respond

Health Reform in the 21 st Century: Proposals to Reform the Health System. Committee on Ways and Means U.S. House of Representatives June 24, 2009

Obamacare in Pictures

Bringing Health Care Coverage Within Reach

Submitted to the Senate Finance Committee. The Graham-Cassidy-Heller-Johnson (GCHJ) Proposal

Covered California Continues to Attract Sufficient Enrollment and a Good Risk Mix Necessary for Marketplace Sustainability

Did the Massachusetts Individual Mandate Mitigate Adverse Selection?

Medicare Policy RAISING THE AGE OF MEDICARE ELIGIBILITY. A Fresh Look Following Implementation of Health Reform JULY 2011

CHAPTER 1. Trends in the Overall Health Care Market

STUDY OF THE IMPACT OF THE ACA IMPLEMENTATION IN KENTUCKY

OVERVIEW OF THE AFFORDABLE CARE ACT. September 23, 2013

Healthcare.gov Auto-Renewal Process for 2018

The Effects of Terminating Payments for Cost-Sharing Reductions

State of Maryland. Individual Market Stabilization Reinsurance Analysis. Prepared by: March 15, Wakely Consulting Group

Considering New Options: Navigating the 2014 Health Insurance Marketplace

Federal Subsidies for Health Insurance Coverage for People Under Age 65: Tables from CBO s September 2017 Projections

Impact of Individual Mandate Penalty Elimination and Other Market Factors on Coverage Nationally and in California

Issues for Employers as Health Care Legislation Moves to the Senate

COVEREDCA.COM. January 18, 2018

Health Insurance Premium Tax Credits and Cost-Sharing Subsidies: In Brief

11/14/2013. Overview. Employer Mandate Exchanges Medicaid Expansion Funding. Medicare Taxes & Fees. Discussion

The Affordable Care Act (ACA) Health Insurance Exchanges

H.R. 849 Protecting Seniors Access to Medicare Act

If Senate Republican Health Bill Weakens Essential Health Benefits Standards, It Would Harm People with Pre-Existing Conditions

HOUSE LEGISLATION WOULD CAUSE 350,000 PEOPLE TO FORGO HEALTH COVERAGE AND COULD JEOPARDIZE HEALTH REFORM By Judith Solomon and Robert Greenstein

Mid-Atlantic Permanente Medical Group, P.C. Kaiser Foundation Health Plan of the Mid-Atlantic States, Inc

2015 Utah Enrollment Update

1332 State Innovation Waivers Under the Trump Administration. Manatt Health April 12, 2017

September 22, The Honorable Orrin Hatch Chairman Committee on Finance U.S. Senate Washington, DC Dear Chairman Hatch:

January 6, Honorable John Boehner Speaker of the House U.S. House of Representatives Washington, DC Dear Mr. Speaker:

What Is Next For the Affordable Care Act s Cost-Sharing Reductions?

The Individual Mandate: Theory & Practice

Update on the Affordable Care Act. Kevin Shah, MD MBA. Review major elements of the affordable care act

Transcription:

1775 Massachusetts Avenue, NW Washington, DC 20036 telephone 202.797.6000 fax 202.797.6004 web brookings.edu Economic Studies Center for Health Policy March 7, 2017 Patrick Conway Acting Administrator Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services Department of Health and Human Services Attention: CMS 9929 P P.O. Box 8016 Baltimore, MD 21244 8016 Re: Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act; Market Stabilization [CMS-9929-P] Dear Acting Administrator Conway: I welcome the opportunity to comment on the Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services (CMS) Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act; Market Stabilization notice of proposed rulemaking. This letter discusses two proposals contained in the proposed rule: (1) modifying the actuarial value de minimis range; and (2) implementing pre-enrollment eligibility verification for special enrollment period enrollees. Contrary to CMS stated objectives, both proposals are likely to reduce the number of people with insurance coverage and to harm, rather than improve, the individual market risk pool. The remainder of this letter discusses each proposal in turn. Please note that the views expressed in this letter are my own and do not necessarily reflect the views of other staff members, officers, or trustees of the Brookings Institution. Modification of Actuarial Value De Minimis Range Under current regulations, in order to fall in a given metal tier, a plan s actuarial value (AV) may be no more than 2 percentage points below the AV level that defines that metal tier. The proposed rule would expand this so-called de minimis range to 4 percentage points. For example, this change would allow silver plans to have an AV as low as 66 percent, rather than the 68 percent currently allowed. As discussed below, changing the de minimis range for silver plans would likely have the effect of reducing the value of the premium tax credit for many families, thereby reducing individual market enrollment and worsening the individual market risk pool. In greater detail, competitive pressures drive insurers to offer plan designs at a wide range of costsharing levels. As a result, it is likely that many insurers will elect to offer silver plans with AVs at or near the bottom of the new de minimis range. This means that the lowest-cost silver plans

available in any particular area will generally have a lower AV and a correspondingly lower premium than they would have under existing regulations. Because the premium tax credit is calculated based on the premium of the second-lowest-cost silver plan offered in an individual s area, the value of the premium tax credit will fall accordingly. The reduction in the value of the tax credit will directly increase health care cost burdens for families who receive the premium tax credit but do not also receive cost-sharing reductions (CSRs). This will be the case no matter how the family changes its choices in response to the reduction in the tax credit. If a family continues to purchase coverage with the same AV as it did before, it will be required to pay a higher net premium in order to do so. Alternatively, the family could decide to hold premium costs constant by purchasing a plan with a lower AV, but this would increase the family s average out-of-pocket costs. 1 Either way, the family s total health care cost burden will have increased. (Families that do receive CSRs will be largely protected against higher costs if they are able to switch to a lower AV plan. This is because switching to a lower AV plan would keep their premium costs from increasing, and the CSRs they receive would automatically increase to cover the additional out-of-pocket costs.) The regulatory impact analysis of the proposed rule solicited comments on how to quantify the overall impact of reductions in the value of the premium tax credit. The Department has estimated that the weighted average second-lowest cost silver plan premium would be $5,586 per year in 2017 in states using the HealthCare.gov enrollment platform. 2 Reducing the AV of the benchmark plan by 2 percentage points from 68 percent to 66 percent would reduce the average benchmark premium by $131 per year, assuming that claims costs account for 80 percent of the total premium. 3 CMS data indicate that, as of June 2016, there were 2.9 million individuals receiving advance premium tax credits who did not also receive CSRs (and thus will bear the full burden of the reduction in the value of the premium tax credit). At this enrollment level, the $131 reduction in the benchmark premium estimated above would reduce the aggregate financial assistance the Federal government provides to consumers by $381 million per year. 4 The aggregate premium and out-of-pocket costs borne by consumers would increase by approximately the same amount as the reduction in financial assistance. In practice, the reduction in financial assistance could be smaller or larger than this estimate. The reduction in financial assistance could be smaller if the AV of the benchmark plan does not fall by a full 2 percentage points in all markets; indeed, there is reason to believe that less competitive 1 An analysis by the Center on Budget and Policy Priorities provides a concrete example of the choices faced by a particular sample family. See Aron-Dine, A. and Park, E. (February 15, 2017). Trump Administration s New Health Rule Would Reduce Tax Credits, Raise Costs, For Millions of Moderate-Income Families. Center on Budget and Policy Priorities. Retrieved March 6, 2017 from http://www.cbpp.org/research/health/trump-administrations-newhealth-rule-would-reduce-tax-credits-raise-costs-for. 2 Office of the Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation (ASPE). (October 24, 2016). Health Plan Choice and Premiums in the 201 Health Insurance Marketplace. Retrieved March 6, 2017 from https://aspe.hhs.gov/system/files/pdf/212721/2017marketplacelandscapebrief.pdf. 3 In detail, the $131 change in the value of the tax credit can be calculated as $5,586*0.8*(0.66 0.68)/0.68. 4 Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services (CMS). (October 19, 2016). First Half of 2016 Effectuated Enrollment Snapshot [Press Release]. Retrieved March 6, 2017 from https://www.cms.gov/newsroom/mediareleasedatabase/fact-sheets/2016-fact-sheets-items/2016-10-19.html.

markets will see smaller reductions. 5 On the other hand, the reduction in financial assistance could be larger if some families who are eligible for CSRs do not switch to lower AV plans, for example because a lower AV plan that includes their preferred providers is not available. Unlike families receiving CSRs who are able to switch to lower AV plans, the reduction in premium tax credits for these families would not be offset by larger CSRs. Lower financial assistance is also likely to reduce individual market enrollment, which would further reduce financial assistance spending. The reduction in individual market enrollment spurred by lower financial assistance is worrisome in its own right. However, this reduction in enrollment is also likely to have negative consequences for the individual market risk pool. Both economic theory and empirical evidence imply that the individuals most likely to drop coverage in response to reduced financial assistance will be healthier than the individuals who remain enrolled. 6 Thus, expanding the de minimis range is likely to worsen the individual market risk pool, not improve it as CMS intends. In the proposed rule, CMS suggests that increased enrollment spurred by the greater variety of plan designs allowed by the expanded de minimis range will offset any negative effects from reduced financial assistance. This is very unlikely to be the case. With respect to bronze plans, the expanded de minimis range will have literally no effect. This is because insurers must continue to comply with the out-of-pocket maximum requirements created by the Affordable Care Act (ACA). According to the 2018 AV Calculator, the minimum AV that a bronze plan can achieve while still complying with the out-of-pocket maximum requirements is 58.54 percent. 7 This falls within the existing de minimis range for bronze plans, so expanding the de minimis range will not increase plan variety in the bronze coverage tier and thus cannot spur additional enrollment. The expanded de minimis range will permit insurers to offer a broader range of plan designs in the silver, gold, and platinum metal tiers. However, the availability of additional plan designs in these coverage tiers is unlikely to spur meaningful additional enrollment. The newly available plan designs in these coverage tiers will all be more generous than plans in the bronze coverage tier that were already available. Most economic models of consumer behavior imply that individuals who prefer these new plan options to being uninsured would also have preferred the existing bronze plan options to being uninsured. This implies that the availability of new options in the silver, gold, and platinum tiers is likely to spur little if any new enrollment. Recommendation: For the reasons outlined above, I recommend that CMS not finalize its proposed expansion of the AV de minimis ranges. If CMS nevertheless wishes to make some 5 In less competitive markets, some insurers may decline to take full advantage of the expanded de minimis range because they realize that doing so would reduce the value of the premium tax credit. In more competitive markets, however, insurers are largely to make significant use of the expanded de minimis range since most of the negative consequences of reducing the value of the premium tax credit would be borne by the insurer s competitors, while the full benefits of offering a plan at the bottom of the expanded range would be received by the insurer itself. 6 For two leading examples, see: Einav, L and Finkelstein, A. (2011). Selection in Insurance Markets: Theory and Empirics in Pictures. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 25(1), 115-138. http://economics.mit.edu/files/5810; and Hackmann, M.B., Kolstad, J.T., and Kowalski A. E. (2015). Adverse Selection and an Individual Mandate: When Theory Meets Practice. American Economic Review, 105(3), 1030-1066. https://www.aeaweb.org/articles?id=10.1257/aer.20130758. 7 While relaxing the ACA s out-of-pocket maximum requirements would expand the range of bronze plans that insurers are permitted to offer, doing so would be unwise, as it would jeopardize financial security for enrollees and exacerbate adverse selection concerns.

modifications in this area, CMS should finalize an expanded de minimis range only for bronze, gold, and platinum plans and leave the de minimis range for silver plans unchanged. This alternative policy would avoid reducing the value of the premium tax credit and thereby avoid the proposed policy s negative effects on individual market enrollment and the individual market risk pool, while still providing insurers with additional plan design flexibility. Expansion of Special Enrollment Period Pre-Enrollment Verification Pilot Last fall, CMS announced a pilot of a process under which individuals seeking to enroll in Marketplace coverage through a special enrollment period (SEP) would be required to have documentation proving their eligibility for the SEP verified before coverage could begin. At that time, CMS indicated that this process would be implemented for a randomly selected 50 percent of SEP applicants starting in June 2017. The proposed rule proposes to expand this process to all enrollees without waiting for the pilot s results. CMS s new proposed approach would be unwise, as there is a significant risk that pre-enrollment verification will reduce the number of people with health insurance coverage and worsen, rather than improve, the individual market risk pool. Inevitably, some eligible individuals will fail to provide suitable documentation when they initially apply for their SEP, whether due to confusion about what documentation is required or other factors, and will then be required to submit additional documentation before their coverage can begin. Research in behavioral economics finds that even small hassle costs to enrolling in a program can substantially reduce take-up, implying that attrition at this stage of the process could be significant. 8 At a minimum, many individuals required to submit additional documentation will face delays in accessing coverage. These reductions and delays in coverage will directly impair access to care and financial security for the affected individuals. However, they may also damage the individual market risk pool. The SEP population includes people with a range of health care needs. Both economic theory and empirical evidence imply that the sickest individuals will be the most motivated to invest the effort to navigate the pre-enrollment verification process, while healthier individuals will be most likely to be deterred. 9 It therefore seems likely that the SEP enrollees discouraged from enrolling by preenrollment verification will be healthier than the average individual market enrollee. CMS experience with its existing SEP eligibility verification process supports the view that preenrollment verification will drive significant reductions in SEP enrollment, particularly among the healthy. CMS previously reported that 45 percent of SEP enrollees ages 18-24 who were selected for a post-enrollment review under the existing process failed to submit satisfactory documentation after an initial round of outreach. 10 By contrast, the failure rate was much lower among individuals 8 Baicker, K., Congdon, W. J., and Mullainathan, S. (2012). Health Insurance Coverage and Take-Up: Lessons from Behavioral Economics. The Milbank Quarterly, 90(1), 107-134. http://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/j.1468-0009.2011.00656.x/full. 9 Einav, L and Finkelstein, A. Selection in Insurance Markets: Theory and Empirics in Pictures; and Hackmann, M.B., Kolstad, J.T., and Kowalski A. E. Adverse Selection and an Individual Mandate: When Theory Meets Practice. 10 Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services (CMS). (December 12, 2016). Pre-Enrollment Verification for Special Enrollment Periods. Retrieved March 6, 2017 from https://www.cms.gov/cciio/resources/fact-sheets-andfaqs/downloads/pre-enrollment-sep-fact-sheet-final.pdf.

ages 55-64: just 27 percent. While age is only a crude proxy for health status, these data strongly suggest that the discouraged SEP enrollees would be comparatively healthy. These data also suggest that the total number of lost enrollees could be substantial. Data on HealthCare.gov enrollment show that 1.4 million people enrolled through a SEP during 2015. 11 If pre-enrollment verification had been in place in 2015 and even one-quarter of those individuals had failed to submit need documentation on their first try, a conservative assumption in light of the data cited above, then around 345,000 people would have faced delays in obtaining coverage or lost their coverage entirely. The costs of implementing pre-enrollment verification that are outlined above could, in principle, be justified if there were clear evidence that SEP abuse was widespread and that pre-enrollment verification will keep high-cost SEP-ineligible individuals from obtaining coverage. However, the proposed rule does not provide evidence establishing that significant numbers of ineligible individuals are currently accessing SEPs or that inappropriate use of SEPs is having a substantial adverse effect on the risk pool. Moreover, the evidence of SEP abuse that has been cited by insurers and others has serious shortcomings. 12 In the absence of compelling evidence of SEP abuse, there is a substantial risk that the costs of pre-enrollment verification for SEP enrollees will exceed its benefits, which implies that CMS should take a cautious approach. Recommendation: For the reasons outlined above, I recommend that CMS not finalize its proposal to expand pre-enrollment verification to all SEP enrollees. Rather, in light of the considerable uncertainty about the effects of implementing pre-enrollment verification, I believe that CMS initial decision to test these procedures through a rigorously designed pilot was appropriate. The pilot s randomized design will allow it to provide compelling evidence on how pre-enrollment verification affects individual market enrollment and the risk pool. This evidence will allow CMS to reach an evidence-based decision about whether to expand pre-enrollment verification when the results become available in the spring of 2018. In the proposed rule, CMS sought comment on an alternative approach under which it would still expand pre-enrollment verification but would retain a small control group to evaluate the effects of these procedures. In light of the potential unintended consequences of pre-enrollment verification discussed above, it would be preferable to continue the pilot in its current form, rather than increasing the share of SEP applicants at risk of these negative consequences. Nevertheless, this alternative would be better than discontinuing the pilot entirely. If CMS pursued this alternative, it would be important to ensure that the share of enrollees left outside the preverification process was large enough to facilitate a rigorous evaluation of the effects of the policy. 11 Apostle, K. (June 28, 2016). Key Findings from the Health Insurance Marketplaces: Marketplace Activity in 2015 and 2016. Presentation. Retrieved March 6, 2017 from https://academyhealth.confex.com/academyhealth/2016arm/meetingapp.cgi/session/4923. 12 Fiedler, M. (February 17, 2017). Trump Administration s Proposed Change to ACA Special Enrollment Periods Could Backfire. Up Front Blog, Brookings Institution. Retrieved March 6, 2017 from https://www.brookings.edu/blog/up-front/2017/02/17/trump-administrations-proposed-change-to-aca-specialenrollment-periods-could-backfire/.

Alternative Approaches to Improving the Individual Health Insurance Market While the two CMS proposals discussed in this letter are unlikely to improve the functioning of the individual health insurance market, improving the individual market is a worthy goal. There are at least two important areas where CMS and the Administration could take action to clarify how the individual market will operate in 2018 and thereby foster better market outcomes. The benefits of appropriate action in these areas would likely be considerably larger than the benefits of the policy changes included in the proposed rule. First, the Administration should clearly state that it intends to retain and enforce the ACA s individual responsibility requirement. The Congressional Budget Office (CBO) has estimated that repealing this provision of the ACA would cause large reductions in individual market enrollment and that the lost enrollees would be disproportionately healthy, thereby necessitating increases in individual market premiums of around 20 percent. 13 Not only would retaining this requirement foster better outcomes in the individual market over the long term, but it would also eliminate an important source of near-term uncertainty about how the individual market will operate in 2018. This uncertainty may cause some insurers to curtail their individual market offerings for 2018 and will likely cause insurers who do participate to charge higher premiums than they otherwise would. Second, the Administration should clearly state that it intends to continue making payments to compensate insurers for the cost of providing cost-sharing reductions. CBO estimates that costsharing reduction payments will total $10 billion in fiscal year 2018. 14 This is a substantial fraction of total individual market premium revenue, so withdrawing these payments would cause serious disruption in the individual market. Furthermore, as with repealing the individual responsibility requirement, insurer uncertainty about whether these payments will be made during the 2018 plan year could cause some insurers to curtail their individual market offerings for 2018 and will likely cause insurers who do participate to charge higher premiums than they otherwise would. Thank you for the opportunity to comment on CMS proposed rule. I hope this information is helpful. If I can provide any additional information, I would be happy to do so. Sincerely, Matthew Fiedler Fellow, Center for Health Policy, Economic Studies Brookings Institution Email: mfiedler@brookings.edu Phone: (202) 238-3515 13 Congressional Budget Office (CBO). (December 8, 2016). Options for Reducing the Deficit: 2017 to 2026: Repeal the Individual Health Insurance Mandate. Retrieved March 6, 2017 from https://www.cbo.gov/budgetoptions/2016/52232. 14 Congressional Budget Office (CBO). (January 24, 2017). Federal Subsidies Under the Affordable Care Act for Health Insurance Coverage Related to the Expansion of Medicaid and Nongroup Health Insurance: Tables from CBO's January 2017 Baseline. Retrieved March 6, 2017 from https://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/recurringdata/51298-2017-01-healthinsurance.pdf.